Skip to main content
Log in

Power in Networks: The Medici

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Homo Oeconomicus Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We use the Public Good (Power) Index and the Public Value to rank the marriages of business relations of 15 elite families in fifteenth century Florence—with a focus on the networks of the Medici and the taking of power by Cosimo de’ Medici. Theoretical analysis supports the outstanding position of the Medici family and explains much of its historical success.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: software package netrankr with file florentine_m (see. https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=netrankr). The Pucci family is not considered in the network scheme because this family had no marriage links to any other family. Table 1a in the appendix contains an alternative representation of the network in Fig. 1.)

Fig. 2
Fig. 3

(Source: software package netrankr with file florentine_m (see. https://CRAN.R-project.org/package=netrankr). The Acciaiuolli, the Albizzi, the Ridolfi, the Strozzi, and the Pucci family are not considered in the network scheme because these families had no business links to any other family. Table 2a in the appendix contains an alternative representation of the network in Fig. 3.)

Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Machiavelli (1882[1532]: 197). characterizes Cosimo as “a man of rare prudence, of grace but agreeable presence, and most liberal and humane. He never attempted anything against the party opposed to him, or against the state, but endeavored to do good to all.” We will refer to Cosimo’s mode of decision making—labelled “robust action” by Padgett and Ansell (1993)—in the final section of this paper.

  2. See Max Weber’s definition of power discussed below.

  3. Machiavelli (1882 [1532]: 210) commented: “Thus did Florence, by this and similar proceedings, deprive herself not only of many good and worthy citizens, but of much wealth and industry.”

  4. Holler and Widgrén (1999) argue that the value of a coalition is power. More generally, v(.) is the characteristic function à la von Neumann-Morgenstern which assigns, in a cooperative game, values to coalitions.

  5. See Holler (1982a) for a discussion of this property. Because of the public good assumption, there is “no splitting up of a cake” and no bargaining over shares. Myerson (1977) presents a bargaining model for networks that connects the (fair) bargaining outcome and the corresponding Shapley value.

  6. The swing players define the power for the indices of Shapley-Shubik, Penrose-Banzhaf-Coleman, Johnston and Deegan-Packel. See Holler (1982b) and Holler and Nurmi (2013) for an extensive discussion of these measures.

  7. For a recent discussion of the PGI, see Holler (2019). Note there are more than ten power indices, but there is only one measure that is serious about measuring the impact of a player in producing a public good, i.e., the PGI.

  8. In the Medici world, various majority rules applied. The beauty of a majority rule is that when it comes to fighting—and quite often the sword was used to implement decisions—then it is more likely that the majority beats the minority. Voting signaled where the majority is—and, due to this information, the minority often gave in.

  9. In 1468, Lorenzo (Il Magnifico), although in love with Lucrezia of the Donati family, had to marry Clarice of the mighty Roman Orsini family. She is commonly characterized as a dull and quarrelsome woman. It seems that Lorenzo was not very happy with her. Still, they had a son Giovanni (1475–1521) who became Pope Leo X in 1513. It seems that the link to the Orsini was very helpful to the Medici family as in this period, during and after Savonarola (1452–1498), their position at Florence was repeatedly challenged by republican governments.

  10. This concurs with Max Weber’s definition of power: “In general, we understand by’power’ the chance of a man or of a number of men to realize their own will in a communal action even against the resistance of others who are participating in the action” (Weber, 1948 [1924]: 180). It seems that, in Florence, there was always a resisting party during the period of our analysis.

  11. In the Pazzi conspiracy of 1478, the threatened Medici and their supporters used their power (and the assistance of the people of Florence) to physically eliminate the Pazzi family and most of their allies—including the archbishop of Pisa. Exclusion did not work.

  12. For effects of a priori union on the PGI, see Alonso-Meijide et al. (2010a, 2010b).

  13. See Nurmi (2005) and Nurmi and Meskanen (2000), and the pioneering article May (1954) which is a straightforward application of Kenneth Arrow’s “Impossibility Theorem” (Arrow 1963 [1951]).

  14. See Overcast and Tullock (1971) and Tullock (1985) for pioneer papers.

References

  • Alonso-Meijide, J. M., Casas-Mendez, B., Fiestras-Janeiro, G., & Holler, M. J. (2010b). Two variations of the Public Good Indices with a priori unions. Control and Cybernetics, 39, 839–855.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alonso-Meijide, J. M., Casas-Mendez, B., Fiestras-Janeiro, G., Holler, M. J., & Nohn, A. (2010a). Axiomatizations of public good indices with a priori unions. Social Choice and Welfare, 35, 517–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1963). [1951] Social choice and individual value (2nd ed.). Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breiger, R. L., & Pattison, P. E. (1986). Cumulated social roles: The duality of persons and their algebras. Social Networks, 8, 215–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emerson, R. M. (1962). Power-dependence relations. American Sociological Review, 27, 31–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J. (Ed.). (1982a). Power, voting, and voting power. Physica-Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J. (1982b). Forming coalitions and measuring voting power. Political Studies, 30, 262–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Nurmi, H. (Eds.). (2013). Power, voting, and voting power: 30 years after. Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J. (2019). The story of the poor public good index. In N. T. Nguyen, R. Kowalzyk, J. Mercik, & A. Motylska-Kruzma (Eds.), Transactions on computational collective intelligence 34 (pp. 171–179). Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Li, X. (1995). From public good index to public value: An axiomatic approach and generalization. Control and Cybernetics, 24, 257–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Packel, E. W. (1983). Power, luck, and the right index. Journal of Economics (Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie), 43, 21–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Rupp, F. (2019). Power in networks: a PGI analysis of Krackhardt’s Kite Network. In N. T. Nguyen, R. Kowalzyk, J. Mercik, & A. Motylska-Kruzma (Eds.), Transactions on computational collective intelligence 34 (pp. 21–34). Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M. J., & Rupp, F. (2020). Power in networks and the urban space. In E. Macrì, V. Morea, & M. Trimarchi (Eds.), Cultural commons and urban dynamics: A multidisciplinary perspective (pp. 37–52). Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Holler, M.J. and Widgrén, M. (1999). “The value of a coalition is power,” Homo Oeconomicus 15: 485–501; reprinted in Notizie di Politeia 59, 2000, 14–28.

  • Machiavelli, N. (1882[1532]). History of Florence. Political, and Diplomatic Writings, Volume 1. Translated from the Italian by Christian E. Detmold, Boston: James R. Osgood and Co.

  • May, K. O. (1954). Intransitivity, utility, and the aggregation of preference patterns. Econometrica, 22, 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1977). Graphs and cooperation in games. Mathematics of Operations Research, 2, 225–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, H. (2005). Aggregation problems in policy evaluation. European Journal of Political Economy, 21, 287–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nurmi, H., & Meskanen, T. (2000). Voting paradoxes and MCDM. Group Decision and Negotiation, 9, 297–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Overcast, H. E., & Tullock, G. (1971). A differential approach to the repeated prisoner’s dilemma. Theory and Decision, 1, 350–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padgett, J. F. (2010). Open Elite? Social mobility, marriage and family in Florence, 1282–1494. Renaissance Quarterly, 63, 357–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padgett, J. F., & Ansell, C. K. (1993). Robust action and the rise of the Medici, 1400–1434. American Journal of Sociology, 98, 1259–1319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1985). Adam Smith and the Prisoners’ Dilemma. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100(Supplement), 1073–1081.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1948). [1924], Class, status and party. In H. H. Gerth & C. Wright Mills (Eds.), Essays from Max Weber. Routledge and Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Florian Rupp.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

On behalf of all authors, the corresponding author states that there is no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The authors would like to thank Benoît Le Maux, Hartmut Kliemt, Barbara Klose-Ullmann, Raymond Russ, and two anonymous reviewers for very helpful comments.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 1a and 2a.

Table 1a Marriage relations of 15 families in fifteenth century Florence
Table 2a Business relations of 15 families in fifteenth century Florence

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Holler, M.J., Rupp, F. Power in Networks: The Medici. Homo Oecon 38, 59–75 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41412-021-00108-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41412-021-00108-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation