Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Innovation Dynamics and Industry Structure Under Different Technological Spaces

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Italian Economic Journal Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper presents an Agent-Based model to analyze the reciprocal influence between industry structure and industry innovation patterns. This topic was originally investigated through the seminal models of Schumpeterian competition developed by Nelson and Winter (Am Econ Rev 67:271–276, 1977, An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 1982), Winter (J Econ Behav Organ 5:287–320, 1984), and Nelson (National innovation systems. A comparative analysis. Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1993). However, the knowledge accumulation process depicted in these models was extremely simplified. In particular, they did not provide any insight about the direction of firms’ technological advancement, within the range of possible alternative technological paths. This aspect is instead of topical importance for the generation of sectoral spillovers affecting the diffusion of innovations and the evolution of the industry structure. Our model aims at filling this gap by amending the framework proposed in Nelson and Winter (An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 1982) so to to account for different characterizations of the ‘technology structure’ of the industry, and their possible influence on the process of Schumpeterian selection. More precisely, technology is represented as a directed network where each node constitutes a batch of technological skills to be learned by firms. The model shows that firms’ ability to imitate competitors generates spillover effects whose relevance depends upon the topological structure of Technology Network and firms’ specialization trajectories. In turn, by influencing the process of Schumpeterian competition, these spillovers exert a fundamental impact on both the industry innovative performance and the evolution of the industry structure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In particular, they considered a science-based regime, where the average of the distribution of the ‘latent productivity’ grew at an exogenous rate, determined by the progresses of science, and a ‘cumulative’ regime, where the distribution was centered on the on the ’prevailing’ productivity of firms.

  2. For an extended literature review on this stream of research see also Cohen (2010).

  3. Notice that, since the rate of profit depends on \(r_{im}\) and \(r_{in}\), R&D outlays reduce the funds available to finance investment

  4. A similar algorithm can be found in Morone and Taylor (2010).

  5. As a final step, we ‘clean’ the network by eliminating from the Parents List of each node, parents who are already the ancestors of another parent, so to avoid redundancies.

  6. If more than one, they chose the deeper one (i.e. the one with the longer genealogy). Hence they prefer more specialized skills (in-depth search).

  7. For simplicity reasons we assume that firms chose as sub-target the node with the lowest index among those required to implement the target. This trivial rule, while not affecting at all the dynamics of the model, is sufficient to assure that firms will always choose as sub-target nodes that they are actually able to learn directly, given their current SP.

  8. When a firm exhausts all the possibilities of a trajectory, she is allowed to start exploring another one. The choice of the new target is based on the same procedure explained above.

  9. The increased productivity, in turn, can increases future R&D outlays via profit, investment, and capital accumulation.

  10. In case \(N^{im}_{it}\), the maximum number of competitors a firm can look at when imitating (see Sect. 2), is greater than the number of competitors with ‘priority’, the remaining ones are randomly sampled. In the opposite case the firm extracts randomly the \(N^{im}_{it}\) competitors to imitate among those with priority.

  11. In this way we rule out any disturbing factor possibly arising from an asymmetric distribution of gains across different branches of the Technology Network. Therefore, the dimension of the spillovers along each possible trajectory does not depend on a pre-determined and arbitrary distribution of productivity gains across nodes. Instead, it depends on the topology of the network representing the industry technological space—which shapes the interdependencies between different technological skills—and on firms’ choices about the direction of their search process.

  12. This implies that the initial stock of capital is lower the higher the initial number of firms is.

  13. This value seems to be fairly realistic even today. Some examples: in the previous decade the R&D expenditure as a percentage of sale was about 13.5% for the software and Internet industry, 13,5% for the healthcare industry, 7% for the computer and electronics industry, 5% for the aerospace and defense industry, while it was signifcantly lower for the chemicals and energy industry, about 1%.

  14. On the contrary, as we will show in Sect. 4.1, imitation plays a central role when the network is poorly branched and its nodes are more interrelated.

  15. In Nelson and Winter (1982) this was the only reason explaining the drop in average productivity levels in less concentrated scenarios whereas the best practice productivity was not affected at all by the industry initial structure under the investigated science-based technological regime which exogenously determined the growth of ‘latent productivity’. The impact of different initial market structures under a cumulative regime, instead, was not investigated at all.

  16. The Herfindahl Numbers Equivalent is formally defined as the inverse of the Herfindahl–Hirschman Index: \(HHI=\sum _{i}s^{2}_{i}\).

  17. Note that at the beginning of the simulation total output is equally distributed among firms. Hence the Herfindahl Numbers Equivalent in the first period of each run simply equals the number of firms initially in business.

  18. The plot for imitators’ capital shares, which fundamentally resembles that for market shares, is omitted for space reasons.

  19. For an extended review of this literature see Nelson (1993), and more recently Malerba (2004) and Hall and Rosenberg (2010).

References

  • Andersen E (1996) The nelson and winter models revisited: prototypes for computer-based reconstruction of schumpeterian competition. DRUID Working Paper, pp 96-102

  • Antonelli C (2009) The economics of nnovation: from the classical legacies to the economics of complexity. Econ Innov New Technol 18–7:611–646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arthur B (1988a) Self-reinforcing mechanisms in economics. In: Anderson P, Arrow K, Pines D (eds) The economy as an evolving complex system. Addison-Wesley, Reading

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur B (1988b) Competing technologies: an overview. In: Dosi G, Freeman C, Nelson R, Silverberg G, Soete L (eds) Technical change and economic theory. Pinter, London, pp 591–607

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur B (1989) Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock in by historical events. Econ J 99:116–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bottazzi G, Dosi G, Rocchetti G (2001) Modes of knowledge accumulation, entry regimes and patterns of industrial evolution. Ind Corp Change 10–3:609–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breschi S, Malerba F, Orsenigo L (2000) Technological regimes and schumpeterian patterns of innovation. Econ J 463:388–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantner U, Malerba F (2007) Innovation, lndustrial dynamics and structural transformation. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cantono S, Silverberg G (2008) A percolation model of eco-innovation diffusion: the relationship between diffusion, learning economies and subsidies. Technol Forecast Soc Change 76–4:487–496

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassiers M, Forey D (2002) Public knowledge, private property and the economics of high-tech consortia. Econ Innovat New Technol 11–2:123–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen W (2010) Fifty years of empirical studies of innovative activity and performance. In: Bronwyn H, Rosenberg N (eds) Handbook of economics of innovation. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 129–213

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Dawid H (2006) Agent-based models of innovation and technological change. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd K (eds) Handbook of computational economics, vol 2. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G (1982) Technological paradigms and technological trajectories : a suggested interpretation of the determinants and directions of technical change. Res Policy 11(3):147–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Egidi M (1991) Substantive and procedural uncertainty. an exploration of economic behaviours in changing environments. J Evolut Econ 1–2:145–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esptein J (2006) Remarks on the foundations of agent-based generative social science. In: Tesfatsion L, Judd K (eds) Handbook of computational economics, vol 2. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 1585–1602

    Google Scholar 

  • Fontana R, Nuvolari A, Verspagen B (2009) Mapping technological trajectories as patent citation networks: an application to data communication standards’. Econ Innov New Technol 18–4:311–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garavaglia C (2010) Modelling industrial dynamics with history-friendly simulations. Struct Change Econ Dyn 21–4:258–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall B, Jaffe A, Trajtenberg M (2001) The nber patent citation data file: Lessons, insights and methodological tools. NBER Working Papers, p 8498

  • Hall B, Rosenberg N (2010) Handbook of the economics of innovation, vol 1. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Hohnisch M, Pittnauer S, Stauffer D (2006) A percolation-based model explaining delayed take-off in new-product diffusion’. Bonn Econ Discussion Papers, p 9

  • Jaffe A, Trajtenberg M, Henderson R (1993) Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. Quart J Econ 108–3:577–598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krafft J, Quatraro F, Saviotti P (2011) The knowledge-base evolution in biotechnology: a social network analysis. Econ Innov New Technol 20–5:445–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F (1992) Learning by firms and incremental technical change. Econ J 102–413:845–859

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F (2004) Sectoral systems of innovation. Concepts, issues, and analysis of six. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F (2005) Sectoral systems of innovation: a framework for linking innovation to the knowledge base, structure and dynamics of sectors. Econ Innov New Technol 14(1–2):63–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Nelson R, Orsenigo L (2008) Vertical integration and disintegration of computer firms: a history-friendly model of the coevolution of the computer and semiconductor industries. Ind Corp Change 17–2:197–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Nelson R, Orsenigo L, Winter S (1999) ’History-friendly’ models of industry evolution: the computer industry. Ind Corp Change 8–1:3–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malerba F, Orsenigo L (2002) Innovation and market structure in the dynamics of the pharmaceutical industry and biotechnology: towards a history friendly model. Ind Corp Change 11–4:667–703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morone P, Taylor R (2010) Knowledge diffusion and innovation. Modelling complex. Edward Elgar, Northampton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R (1993) National Innovation systems. A comparative analysis. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R, Winter S (1977) Simulation of schumpeterian competition. Am Econ Rev 67–1:271–276

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Nomaler O, Verspagen B (2007) Knowledge flows, patent citations and the impact of science on technology. Unu-Merit Working Paper Series, p 22

  • Perez C (2009) The double bubble at the turn of the century: technological roots and structural implications. Camb J Econ 33–4(4):779–805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schettino F (2007) Us patent citations data and industrial knowledge spillovers. Econ Innov New Technol 16–8:595–633

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1950) Capitalism, socialism, and democracy, 3rd edn. Harper, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg G, Dosi G, Orsenigo L (1988) Innovation, diversity and diffusion: a self-organization model. Econ J 98–393:1032–1054

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silverberg G, Verspagen B (2005) A percolation model of innovation in complex technology spaces. J Econ Dyn Control 29:225–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon H (1947) Administrative behavior: a study of decision-making processes in administrative organizations, 4th edn. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Verspagen B (2007) Mapping technological trajectories as patent citation network: a study on the history of fuell cell research. Adv Complex Syst 10–1:93–115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG (1984) Schumpeterian comptetion in alternative technological regimes. J Econ Behav Organ 5:287–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to Roberto Fontana, Stefano Lucarelli, Margherita Balconi, Andrea Fumagalli, Pietro Terna, and Mauro Gallegati for their support and their helpful advice. I am also thankful to Domenico Delli Gatti and Cristiano Antonelli for their useful remarks and suggestions. Usual caveat applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alessandro Caiani.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Investment

As explained in the text the function defining desired investment reflects the idea that firms are afraid of ‘spoiling’ their own market if they increase too much the scale of production, thereby reducing the market price and possibly their own profit margin. Assuming that the demand curve has a constant elasticity \(\eta \) and firm’s market share is equal to s, the elasticity of the residual demand facing the firm, under the firm’s conjecture that other producers will maintain constant their output, is given by: \(\frac{\eta }{s}\) Given that \(\pi =(P(Q)-\frac{c}{A})sQ\), the firm maximizes her profit when it chooses a level of output such that:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \pi }{\partial Q}=\left( \left( \frac{\partial P}{\partial Q}\frac{Q}{P}P+P\right) -\frac{c}{A}\right) s=0 \Rightarrow \left( -\frac{1}{\eta /s}+1\right) P=\frac{c}{A}\Rightarrow \nonumber \\&\quad \Rightarrow \frac{\eta }{\eta -s}=\frac{PA}{c}=\rho \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

If instead firm’s conjecture is that the rest of the industry consists of price-takers that respond along a supply curve with constant elasticity \(\psi \) we obtain a more general results. The profit maximizing price-to-marginal-costs ratio is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \rho =\frac{\eta +(1-s)\psi }{\eta +(1-s)\psi -s} \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

Notice that, when \(\psi =0\), we obtain the previous equilibrium condition. The right-hand side of the above equation can be interpreted as the target mark-up \(\rho ^{T}(s)\) of the firm, expressed as a function of the firm’s market share.

Hence, desired investment can be expressed as:

$$\begin{aligned} I_{D}=\delta +1-\rho ^{T} \frac{c}{P_{t} A_{it}} \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

When the realized mark-up \(P_{t} A_{it}/c\) is exactly equal to the target mark-up \(\rho ^{T}(s)\) the firm considers herself to be in a profit maximizing equilibrium at the current level of production and her desired investment is simply equal to the amount required to replace depreciated capital. Instead, when the realized mark-up is greater (smaller) than the target one, the desired net investment will be positive (negative). Equation (2.8) in Sect. 2 was obtained by setting \(\eta =1\) and \(\psi =1\).

1.2 A.2 Tables of Results

Table 2 Results of the simulations-5 networks generated with \(P_{Split} = 25\%\) & Initial parents number = 10
Table 3 Results of the simulations-5 networks generated with \(P_{Split} = 10\%\) & Initial parents number = 10
Table 4 Results of the simulations-5 networks generated with \(P_{Split}=40\%\) & Initial parents number = 10

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Caiani, A. Innovation Dynamics and Industry Structure Under Different Technological Spaces. Ital Econ J 3, 307–341 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-017-0049-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40797-017-0049-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation