1 Introduction

Total real gross fixed investment in Italy fell by around 30 per cent between the outbreak of the global financial crisis, in 2007, and 2014, returning to levels comparable to those of the mid-Nineties. A striking feature of this downturn was its unusual severity and duration, also in an international comparison. The plunge involved all types of expenditure, including construction investment here not discussed.

This paper delves into the causes of Italy’s exceptional decline in non-construction expenditure during the double recession occurred between 2007 and 2014, using both statistical and econometric analyses. The economic literature, which we briefly review, has singled out a number of determinants of investment expenditure, including demand conditions, the user cost of capital, uncertainty, credit availability, labour market regulation. We first analyze the most recent survey data on Italy to determine the main obstacles to investment growth as perceived by Italian firms. We next move on to use standard econometric techniques to measure the contribution of each economic factor to the observed investment trends in Italy over the past years.

Our main findings are the following. Among the sectors, the main culprit of Italy’s recent investment downturn is the private non-financial service sector, although the allocation of value added away from industry also played a role in the decline. Looking at the economic determinants, according to survey data, demand, financial and uncertainty conditions all contributed to the slump in gross fixed capital formation in Italy. An aggregate econometric model of investment indicates that even during the recent double recession the most important driver of capital accumulation was demand conditions. Moreover, the user cost of capital had a substantial negative impact in the acute phases of the sovereign debt crisis, but since 2013 its contribution has turned positive thanks to the expansionary monetary policy measures enacted. Tight credit supply conditions dampened investment expenditure in particular in 2009 and 2012. Firms’ uncertainty provided a sizeable drag on capital accumulation not only during the global financial crisis but also in 2013-14 and it appears as one of the main factors behind the delayed recovery of the Italian economy from the sovereign debt crisis. These macroeconomic results are confirmed by a specific econometric analysis of capital accumulation expenditure in Italy’s manufacturing branches.

The structure of the paper is as follows. Section 2 briefly recalls the literature on the determinants of investment decisions. Section 3 provides some descriptive analysis on both the sectorial and economic drivers of the recent developments in non-construction investment in Italy. In particular, it first measures the contribution of each economic sector in explaining the drop in Italy’s gross tangible non-construction investment rate. Next, it discusses the findings of the European Commission’s Investment Survey for the four largest euro-area countries and exploits the Bank of Italy’s most recent business surveys to single out the key factors underlying investment developments in Italy. In Sect. 4 we quantify the role of each economic determinant in explaining the observed downturn in Italy, in particular exploring alternative measures of uncertainty. We first estimate an aggregate investment model for the private sector at a quarterly frequency, that includes uncertainty and credit supply conditions. Given its relevance for non-construction investment in Italy, we next analyze a yearly 1986–2012 panel dataset of 13 manufacturing branches, which broadly confirms the results obtained at an aggregate level. Section 5 draws some conclusions. The Appendix provides some further information on non-construction investment developments in an international comparison.

2 Related Literature on the Determinants of Investment

The theoretical and empirical literature has singled out several main economic determinants underlying the process of capital accumulation, which we here briefly discuss. First, the “accelerator model” suggests that output and demand fluctuations have a key role in explaining investment behaviour (see e.g. Chirinko 1993). The cost and availability of financial resources, as well as the structure of corporate balance sheets, are also of great relevance in a context in which internal and external funds are not perfect substitutes (see Fazzari et al. 1988 amongst others).Footnote 1 Next, uncertainty has been long recognized as a major factor in investment decisions, in that it may lead to a postponement of investment plans or an increase in the case of more desirable risk-return prospects. Economic theory provides contrasting explanations regarding the sign and relevance of the investment-uncertainty relationship (Leahy and Whited 1996), since it depends on the technological features of firms’ production processes and on the structure of the product market. In particular it depends on the degree of reversibility of investment expenses (the more reversible they are, the less relevant is uncertainty; Bernanke 1983), firms’ risk aversion and market power (for a risk-neutral competitive firm with constant returns to scale and no irreversibility greater uncertainty increases investment; Abel 1993), the interplay between irreversibility and monopolistic power (in a context of irreversibility, imperfect competition or decreasing returns to scale can lead to a negative effect of uncertainty on investment; Caballero 1991), the degree of flexibility of labour (which can compensate for the irreversibility of investment; Eberly and Van Mieghem 1997). The empirical literature largely converges in pinning down negative effects of uncertainty on capital accumulation.Footnote 2 In particular, on a cross-section of Italian manufacturing firms, Guiso and Parigi (1999) find that firm-specific uncertainty weakens investment, the more when capital expenses are less reversible and the greater the firm’s market power.Footnote 3 Bloom et al. (2007), in an influential paper first released in the aftermath of the huge rise in uncertainty following the September 11 events, show that the responsiveness of investment to demand shocks decreases in periods of high uncertainty in a sample of U.K. manufacturing companies.

Among the more recent studies, aimed at analyzing the sharp fall of investment occurred during the Great Recession and the European sovereign debt crisis, Gilchrist et al. (2014) explore the connection between uncertainty and credit shocks and “point to financial distortions as the main mechanism through which fluctuations on uncertainty affects macroeconomic outcomes” (2014, p. 1). Bachmann et al. (2014) employ German IFO Survey microdata and U.S. data from the Philadelphia FED Business Outlook Survey to build survey-based uncertainty indexes and show that the negative impact on investment expenses of rises in uncertainty are stronger in Germany but more persistent in the U.S. (which could reflect stronger capital irreversibility in the former case, a larger impact of financial frictions in the latter). Banerjee et al. (2015) find that uncertainty lowers investment in a quarterly panel of G7 countries while Barkbu et al. (2015) point to a large effect of demand expectations, which is compounded by financial and uncertainty factors in the euro area.

Finally, a strand of the empirical literature focused on the structural features and recent changes in the Italian economy has also suggested the existence of a strong link between labour market regulation and capital accumulation. In particular, according to Saltari and Travaglini (2009) and Ciccarone and Saltari (2015), increased labour market flexibility since the mid-Nineties favoured the adoption of labour-intensive production techniques to the detriment of investment, therefore especially weakening the accumulation of the more innovative capital components.

Ultimately at the empirical level it appears important to assess the relevance and the relative weight of all mentioned factors in driving investment expenditure. This paper attempts to provide an answer to this question for the Italian economy, focusing on the double recessionary period 2007–2014.

3 Some Descriptive Statistical Analyses of Italy’s Investment Downturn: Sector-Specific Developments and Evidence from Surveys

A comparison with past crises proves that the recent double recession in Italy has been exceptionally long and intense, both for gross domestic product (GDP), which cumulatively fell by nearly 10 per cent, and for gross fixed capital formation (GFCF; Table 1).Footnote 4 While GDP declined more strongly in 2008–2009 than in 2011–2014, the downturn in investment was more severe in the latter recession. The drop in GFCF in 2007–2014 was broad-based across investment goods, with all types of expenditure at present below their pre-crisis level. Moreover, it was particularly severe relative to the declines observed in the other four largest euro-area countries.Footnote 5

Table 1 The decline in GDP and in investment during Italy’s recent recessions
Fig. 1
figure 1

Gross fixed non-construction investment rates in the four largest euro-area countries (percentage shares in GDP at market prices, computed on chain-linked volumes)

Focusing on the share of GFCF in GDP, between the inception of the European Monetary Union and the outbreak of the global financial crisis in 2007 Italy’s non-construction investment rate was not at all dismal in an international perspective: it was indeed comparable to Germany and France’s ratios (nearly 10 per cent) and in turn about one percentage point higher than Spain’s investment rates (Fig. 1; Table 2). However, in Italy the decline thereafter was the most long-lasting and pronounced across the four countries, leading to the lowest investment rate in 2014, at 8.3 per cent. In 2015 Italy was the only large euro-area country recording an “investment gap” relative to its 2000–2007 average, although in all four countries, with the exception of France, the investment rate was lower than the 2007–2008 peak.

Table 2 The current non-construction “investment gap” in the four largest euro-area countries (percentage shares, when otherwise not indicated, computed on chain-linked volumes)

3.1 Sectorial Drivers of Italy’s Investment Downturn

A sectorial analysis helps shed light on the drivers of Italy’s sharp investment decline in recent years. Changes in the total-economy investment rate stem from changes in investment intensity in each industry (“within effect”) and varying shares of each sector in total output (“between effect”). Via shift-share analysis, it is therefore possible to ascertain to what extent aggregate investment rates reflect the investment behaviour in individual sectors and the changing sectorial composition of the economy. By defining \(X\equiv \frac{I}{Y}\), where I is nominal GFC and Y is nominal value added, the investment rate can be expressed as

$$\begin{aligned} X=\mathop \sum \limits _{s=1}^n X_{s} \frac{Y_s }{Y} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where s is one of the n sectors of the economy.

Taking time differentials (where  \(\hat{}\)  indicates differentials),

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{X} =\sum \limits _{s=1}^n {\widehat{X}_s } \frac{Y_s}{Y} + \sum \limits _{s=1}^n {X_s} \frac{\widehat{Y}_s }{Y} , \end{aligned}$$
(2)

and dividing both terms by X, with simple algebraic manipulations we obtain the following decomposition:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\hat{X}}{X} = \sum \limits _{s=1}^n \frac{\widehat{X}_s}{X_s}\frac{I_s}{I}+\sum \limits _{i=1}^n \frac{I_s}{I}\left( \frac{\hat{Y}_s}{Y_s}-\frac{\hat{Y}}{Y}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(3)

The first term on the right-hand side of the equation is the “within effect” and the second term is the “between effect”.

We break the total economy down into six sectors: (i) agriculture, forestry and fishing; (ii) industry (except utilities); (iii) private regulated sector (utilities; transport and communication); (iv) finance, insurance and real estate (FIRE); (v) private unregulated services; (vi) public sector (public administration, health and education). We here consider only tangible non-construction investment, owing to its much less favourable dynamics than those reported for intangible GFCF.Footnote 6

Since the mid-Nineties the sectorial breakdown of gross fixed tangible non-construction capital formation has been stable in Italy (Table 3, figures in brackets). Industry is the key sector in tangible non-construction investment, undertaking on average around 39 per cent of total expenditure, which is also a large share in an international comparison (Busetti et al. 2015). Conversely, the weight of private (regulated and unregulated) services is relatively low, as is public investment spending, owing to fiscal consolidation that began in the mid-Nineties.

Figure 2 presents the shift-share decomposition of the change in aggregate tangible non-construction investment rates in Italy for three sub-periods (1996–1999; 2000–2007; 2008–2012), also reported in the last column of Table 3.Footnote 7 The sum of the contributions of each sector is the total “within effect”.Footnote 8

Fig. 2
figure 2

The decomposition of changes in tangible non-construction investment rates in Italy (current prices; annual average changes)

In 1995–2012 private services were the main driver of the total economy tangible non-construction investment rate dynamics in Italy, with a larger contribution coming from the unregulated vis-à-vis the regulated sector as of the 2000s. Industry too was an important positive contributor until 2007, explaining on its own nearly one third of the total “within effect”. Whereas in the years prior to the global financial crisis the aggregate “within effect” was positive (in particular, reflecting positive investment rate changes in all sectors before the inception of the European Monetary Union), in the recent recessionary period until 2012 sectorial investment rates declined across the board. Non-financial private services were the main driver of the recent aggregate downturn: in particular, this sector explains about two-thirds (i.e. over 2 percentage points) of the total-economy investment rate decline, against a negative contribution of industry of less than 0.5 percentage points, notwithstanding its roughly equivalent weight. The “between effect”—which reflects the tendency to a reallocation of value added away from industry, a high-investment intensity sector, to the less capital intensive private services sector—also contributed negatively to overall investment rate developments in the most recent years, as in the previous sub-periods.Footnote 9

Table 3 Changes in sectorial tangible non-construction investment rate in Italy (average annual changes by sub-period; shares in total tangible non-construction investment in brackets; investment rates and shares computed on series at current prices)

This analysis suggests that for the coming years the inversion of the declining trend in the total economy tangible non-construction investment rate is crucially related to the materialization of a significant recovery in private non-financial service expenditure.

3.2 Economic Drivers of Italy’s Investment Decline According to Survey Data

The European Commission (EC) Investment Survey, taken bi-annually in spring and autumn, allows us to analyze firms’ perceptions on the economic determinants of the recent decline in Italy’s manufacturing investment and to set them in an international perspective.Footnote 10 According to this survey, insufficient demand prospects and a low capacity utilization rate were significant factors constraining investment in manufacturing in Italy during the double recession, in addition to policy uncertainty (included in ‘other factors’; Fig. 3). The drag on investment spending stemming from financial constraints was particularly severe in 2009 and in 2012 but subsequently waned, similarly to all other obstacles to investment. Technological factors have actually returned to boosting GFCF in Italy since 2010.

Fig. 3
figure 3

The drivers of manufacturing firms’ investment according to the EC Investment Survey (1) (balances; percentage points)

The EC Investment Survey does not explicitly include economic uncertainty among the determinants of investment. Limited to Italy, the Bank of Italy’s survey Invind, taken in spring, allows gauging the effects of a measure of this type of uncertainty on investment expenses at firm level.Footnote 11 We classify the firms for which the uncertainty (on expected turnover growth) is above the 75 percentile as “high uncertainty” units, those for which it is below the 25 percentile as “low uncertainty”, and the remaining units as “average uncertainty”. The left panel of Fig. 4 shows the difference, according to these three groups of firms, between the share of firms that expect higher investment at year T for year T\(+\)1 and those that expect less investment; the black line indicates the change in investment recorded by national accounts, shifted backward by one year in the left panel. For most years in the period under study the plans previously formulated by high-uncertainty firms were especially pessimistic in comparison to the other groups. In the right panel of Fig. 4 the percentages of firms increasing or decreasing realized investment in year T are separated into groups defined by ex ante uncertainty (measured in year T\(-\)1). Again for much of the 2007–2013 period the most uncertain firms tend to confirm even ex post their lower investment.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Expected and realized investment for low and high uncertainty Italian firms (difference in percent between the quota of firms that plan to increase investment in the following year and those that plan a decrease—left panel- and same difference for realized investment—right panel)

4 Econometric Analyses of Non-Construction Investment Dynamics in Italy

We now move on to substantiate the described survey evidence for Italy by means of econometric analyses. Special emphasis will be placed on evaluating the impact of uncertainty, which could potentially strongly and negatively affect firms’ investment decisions during bad economic times. First, we provide aggregate evidence for private sector non-construction investment using an econometric relationship that follows the modeling approach in the Bank of Italy Quarterly Model (BIQM), augmented to take into account uncertainty and credit supply conditions. Using these estimates we present a decomposition of the fall in investment occurred during the double recessionary period 2007–2014 in terms of the contributions of various determinants. Next we provide panel estimates of the effects of uncertainty and liquidity conditions for 13 manufacturing branches. This evidence broadly confirms and corroborates the previous results based on aggregate data. Focusing on manufacturing is indeed particularly relevant for Italy, given the high non-construction investment rate of this sector in an international perspective, as seen in Sect. 3.1. In both the aggregate and disaggregate approaches, uncertainty is proxied with survey measures of the dispersion of agents’ expectations on their own demand conditions and/or on the general economic environment.

4.1 Aggregate Estimates for Private Sector Non-Construction Investment (Quarterly Data)

We first assess the impact of the various determinants of the private sector non-construction investment using an econometric relationship that follows the modeling approach of the BIQM. In particular, the investment equation is obtained within a standard neoclassical model where firms derive investment and labour demand by a cost minimization problem, given factor prices and the desired level of additional production capacity. Assuming a Cobb-Douglas production function and the non-malleability of capital, it is known that desired investment as a share of expected demand is equal to the optimal capital/output ratio K*, which in turn is a function of factor prices.Footnote 12

The empirical counterpart is a dynamic model of investment with long-run homogeneity restrictions between investment and the capital/output ratio and investment and output; expectations and adjustment costs are taken into account by including several lags of the private sector value added and the capital/output ratio. The estimated model is thus specified as:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta i_t= & {} \beta _0 +\beta _1 ( {i_{t-1} -( {k_{t-1}^*(uc_{t-1} )+y_{t-1} })})+\sum \limits _{j=1}^p {\beta _{2,j} \Delta y_{t-j} }\nonumber \\&+\sum \limits _{j=1}^q {\beta _{3,j} \Delta k_{t-j}^*(uc_{t-j} )\,+} \,\gamma 'z_t , \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(i_t ,\,\,y_t ,\,\,k_t^*(uc_t )\) are (the logarithm of) the investment expenditure, the private sector value added and the optimal capital/output ratio, respectively, the latter being a known function of the user cost of capital \(uc_t \); \(\Delta \) is the first difference operator.Footnote 13

Compared with the standard neoclassical model, the equation includes three additional determinants:

$$\begin{aligned} z_t =( {confid_t ,\,\,\,uncert_t ,\,\,credit_t })\,', \end{aligned}$$

that are aimed at capturing the effects of: (i) entrepreneurs’ level of confidence on the general and own economic outlook, (ii) firms’ uncertainty proxied by a measure of dispersion of their ‘sentiments’ (second moments), (iii) credit conditions.

In more detail, the level of confidence is measured by the average sentiment indicator for manufacturing firms published by Istat.Footnote 14 For uncertainty several proxies are considered. From the Istat survey we derive a dispersion measure of replies regarding expectations for (1) orders, (2) production, and (3) general economic situation. These measures of uncertainty, defined as in Fuss and Vermeulen (2008) and Bachmann et al. (2014),Footnote 15 are forward-looking and time-varying.Footnote 16 In addition we look at (4) the dispersion (in terms of standard deviation) among the forecasts of Italian GDP provided by the analysts surveyed by Consensus Economics. These four different measures are shown in Fig. 5 for the period 1986Q1–2014Q4, together with (5) an ‘average measure’ obtained by taking the first principal component (PC) of (1), (2), (3) and (4). Finally, credit frictions are captured by the synthetic indicator of credit supply conditions obtained from the Italian Bank Lending Survey.Footnote 17

Fig. 5
figure 5

Alternative measures of uncertainty (1)

Table 4 Estimation results for the aggregate model of investment (dependent variable: first difference of the logarithm of non-construction investment)

The model has been estimated by OLS with quarterly data over the period 1986–2013. Table 4 reports the regression results in terms of coefficients (with t-statistics provided in brackets) and main diagnostics.Footnote 18 The columns differ according to the proxy used for uncertainty displayed in Fig. 5; the principal component is in the last column. The short-run coefficients for output and capital/output ratios reported are the sum of the parameters of the respective distributed lags in the estimated equation. Using one-sided Gaussian critical values, nearly all coefficients are statistically significant at least at the 10 per cent level. Clearly, there is some degree of collinearity among the confidence, uncertainty and credit restrictions indicators, which turn out to inflate somewhat the coefficients’ standard errors. The regression results and the properties of the model happen to be very similar for all measures of uncertainty considered.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Dynamic multipliers of the investment equation with respect to shocks to uncertainty, confidence, credit supply conditions, output, user cost of capital

The properties of the estimated model are better summarized in Fig. 6, which reports the response of investment (with respect to a baseline level) to shocks to its determinants after 1,2, ...,40 quarters, the so-called “dynamic multipliers”. Specifically, we consider: (1) a temporary (2 years) shock to uncertainty, calibrated with what was observed at the time of the Great Recession (we apply for 8 quarters the difference between the average values in the uncertainty indicator between 2008–2009 and 2006–2007); (2) a temporary (2 years) shock to confidence, similarly calibrated; (3) a temporary (2 years) shock to credit supply conditions, similarly calibrated; (4) a permanent increase by 1 per cent in output; (5) a permanent increase of 100 basis points in the real user cost of capital.

The effects of uncertainty shocks to investment are provided in the top left panel. A worsening of uncertainty of a similar magnitude as that observed during the 2008–2009 recession curbs investment sizably, cumulatively by about 5 per cent after two years according to the first principal component of the four elementary indicators.

Following a temporary shock to the level of firms’ confidence, calibrated looking at the average deterioration recorded during the Great Recession, the maximum impact on investment falls between 3 and 4 per cent, but vanishes rapidly as the shock disappears.Footnote 19

Credit restrictions of a magnitude similar to what was on average observed in 2008–2009 exert a sizable negative impact on investment, ranging between 6 and 8 per cent after two years. This result appears broadly in line with the estimates reported in Panetta and Signoretti (2010) and Caivano et al. (2010), where several different ways of identifying the effects of the credit supply restrictions of 2008–2009 were considered.Footnote 20

As regards the effects of shocks in output, the ‘accelerator’ is found to reach a peak in the second year when the elasticity of investment to output is between 1.5 and 1.8; the elasticity then gradually returns to 1 following the long term constraint imposed, and tested, in the model.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Factors driving the dynamics of the private sector’s non-construction investment since the Great Recession (percentage values)

Finally, a permanent rise of 100 basis points in the real user cost of capital has a gradual and prolonged negative impact on investment, peaking at about \(-\)5 per cent after 10 years (\(-\)4 after 5 years). It is noteworthy that the multipliers with respect to output and the cost of capital are similar (albeit somewhat smaller) to those that were estimated using data before the crisis, as reported in Busetti et al. (2005).

The estimated model of investment can shed light on the factors behind the large decline in capital accumulation observed during the double recession. Figure 7 shows the contributions of each of the determinants included in the model to the year-on-year growth rate of the private-sector non-residential investment.Footnote 21 In most periods the main driver is the demand component (sum of the output and confidence contributions). The real user cost of capital provided a large negative impact during the most acute phases of the sovereign debt crises, but contributed positively since 2013 (overall by nearly 4 percentage points), mainly reflecting the effects of the expansionary monetary policy measures adopted by the European Central Bank. The constraints to capital accumulation imposed by tight credit supply conditions accounted about one third of the fall in investment occurred during the periods 2008–2009 and 2012–2013. Finally, uncertainty provided a sizeable negative impact not only during the Great Recession but also since mid-2013, and stands out as one of the factors explaining the delayed recovery of the Italian economy.

The econometric decomposition in Fig. 7 is consistent with the qualitative results coming from the surveys and described in Sect. 3.2. An analysis by the IMF also provides a broadly similar assessment (International Monetary Fund 2015). The results presented here are also consistent with the counterfactual exercise of Busetti and Cova (2013) where simulations of the BIQM were used to identify the contributions of the main factors related to the sovereign debt crisis.

4.2 Annual Panel Estimates on Manufacturing Non-Construction Investment

Moving to the disaggregated analysis, the empirical investment model applied to annual 13-branches of manufacturing data for 1986–2012 has the following baseline specification:Footnote 22

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta i_{i,t}= & {} \alpha _{0} +\alpha _{1i} +\alpha _{2i} \Delta i_{i,t-1} +\alpha _{3i} \Delta va_{i,t} + \alpha _{4i} \Delta interest_{i,t-1}\nonumber \\&+\,\alpha _{5i} liquidity_{i,t-1} + \alpha _{6i} uncertainty_{i,t-1} +\alpha _{7i} cycle_{i,t-1} +\varepsilon _{i,t} \end{aligned}$$
(5)

All variables, except the interest rate and the dummy cycle variable, are expressed in logarithms, with \(\Delta \) denoting first differences; coefficients may therefore be interpreted as elasticities. Branch-specific non-construction investment and value added are taken from Istat national accounts. Investment data were winsorised to eliminate possible outliers and to clean the dataset from idiosyncratic data points.Footnote 23 The interest rate is the average bank lending rate to firms, the only series for which a sectorial breakdown is unavailable. Sectorial corporate liquidity conditions are proxied by the annual average of the percentage balances computed on the liquidity expectations of the manufacturing firms surveyed monthly by Istat. Demand uncertainty is proxied by a (branch-specific) dispersion measure of replies from the same survey regarding total order expectations, as defined in the Sect. 4.1. The cycle variable is a dummy variable taking value 1 in expansionary years, capturing the general state of the Italian economy.Footnote 24

The equation is estimated with the Arellano and Bond (1991) Generalized Method of moments (GMM) estimator for linear dynamic panel data. This estimator is validated since in all specifications the null hypothesis of no autocorrelation in first-differenced errors is not rejected at orders higher than one and the Sargan test on overidentifying restrictions is passed (i.e. the null that the restrictions are valid is not rejected). Given the relative long panel we deal with, we implement limits on the number of instruments in order not to weaken the latter test.Footnote 25

Our results for the manufacturing sector are presented in Table 5, which offers three alternative specifications (with column b as our baseline and preferred specification). Changes in lagged non-construction investment are negatively correlated with current changes in the same variable, suggesting irreversible investment decisions. Contemporary changes in output, which capture sector-specific demand conditions, positively affect non-construction investment expenditure, as expected.Footnote 26 An increasing cost of lending dampens investment, as does decreasing corporate liquidity. Uncertainty is found to have a large significant negative impact on capital accumulation. Finally, favourable phases in the general economic cycle exert a positive, yet small, lagged, and weakly significant effect on sectorial capital spending.

An attempt was made also to test the effect, if any, of labour market regulation on investment dynamics in manufacturing branches, as suggested for example by Ciccarone and Saltari (2015). A measure of employment protection legislation (EPL) at the branch level is not available for Italy, so various proxies were attempted, although none were found to be statistically significant at the 10 per cent level, thereby leading to their exclusion from the baseline results reported in Table 5.Footnote 27 We believe that either a more disaggregated analysis considering solely the intangible and innovative components of capital accumulation or a more comprehensive focus including also private service sectors are warranted in order to fully test the hypothesis put forth by Ciccarone and Saltari (2015) amongst others. This analysis however goes beyond the scope of this paper and we deem it to be an interesting avenue for future research.

Table 5 Sectorial estimation results (dependent variable: non-construction investment change (t))

Finally, limiting our estimation period to 1986–2007 leads to broadly similar results to those reported in Table 5, suggesting no significant break in the factors influencing the sectorial spending patterns during the recent recessionary years.Footnote 28 Moreover, there appears no statistically significant difference in the correlations between export-oriented and domestic market-oriented branches.Footnote 29

5 Conclusions

The decline in Italy’s non-construction investment since 2007 has been of unprecedented severity, in both a historical and an international perspective. All investment goods were affected. In 2014 a large non-construction “investment gap” was registered in Italy, both relative to its pre-crisis peak and to its 2000–2007 average.

While sectorial investment rates fell across the board in 2008–2012, private non-financial services stand out as the main “culprit” of Italy’s downturn, explaining two thirds of the decline in the aggregate propensity to invest. This negative contribution was compounded by that originating from the reallocation of value added from high investment intensity sectors (industry) to low investment intensity sectors (private non-financial services). Assuming this “between effect” will continue to be negative over the next years, significant positive investment growth should be undertaken in particular by private services in order to guarantee a sustained recovery and a closure of the afore-mentioned “investment gap”.

Amongst the factors behind the recent non-construction investment slump, various results may be drawn out from our econometric analyses, broadly confirming indications arising from survey data. In addition to traditional determinants (demand conditions and the user cost of capital), uncertainty and credit supply conditions are found to have statistically and economically significant effects on firms’ capital spending. According to our estimates, demand conditions were the main driver of the investment slump in the recent double recession. The user cost of capital provided a large negative impact during the most acute phases of the sovereign debt crises but since 2013 its contribution has reversed, owing to the expansionary monetary policy measures enacted. The constraints imposed by tight credit supply conditions were particularly large during 2009 and 2012. Uncertainty also provided a sizeable negative impact during the double recession; it appears as one of the main factors explaining the delay in the recovery of the Italian economy. The significance of these determinants and their impact on non-construction investment growth is confirmed by a specific panel analysis on the manufacturing branches, which cumulatively explain over a third of total non-construction investment. Again, uncertainty is found to have a significant negative impact on capital accumulation.