Skip to main content
Log in

International Fisheries Agreements with a Shifting Stock

  • Published:
Dynamic Games and Applications Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

When a fish stock shifts from one nation to another nation, e.g., due to climate change, the nation that loses the resource has incentives to deplete it, while the other nation, receiving the resource, has incentives to conserve it. We propose an analytical model to study under which circumstances self-enforcing agreements can align incentives. Our setup allows to distinguish between a fast and a slow shift and between a smooth or a sudden shift in ownership. We show that the shorter the expected duration of the transition, the higher the total equilibrium exploitation rate. Similarly, a sudden shift implies—by and large—more aggressive non-cooperative exploitation than a gradual shift. However, a self-enforcing agreement without side-payments is more likely for a sudden than for a smooth shift. Further, the scope for cooperation increases with the expected duration of the transition, and it decreases with the renewability of the resource and the discount rate. Most importantly, we show that concentrating on in-kind transfers can be very detrimental for shifting renewable resources: In some cases, there is no efficient bargaining solution without side-payments, even when there are only two players.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Note that at this level of abstraction, we do not differentiate between producer surplus and consumer surplus, or any positive externalities such as cultural or touristic values derived from, for example, a picturesque fishing industry. The decrease in marginal utility could thus capture increasing harvesting costs, a supply side effect on the landings price, or other more general effects. However, we require that no utility can be derived from the resource when it is not harvested (i.e., there are no existence values). We further discuss this latter aspect in Sect. 6.

  2. In the coming pages, we will introduce a number of short-hand variables to simplify the notation. For the reader’s convenience, an overview of the fundamental and derived variables that we use is given in the Appendix in Table 2.

  3. Let \(i_\mathrm{min}\) be the lowest extraction rate of player i and let \(d_\mathrm{max}\) be the largest equilibrium total extraction rate. Then a condition that guarantees nonnegative objective function values is \(i_\mathrm{min}M\left( (1-d_\mathrm{max})M\right) ^{\frac{\alpha }{1-\alpha }} \ge 1\) for \(i = A,B\).

  4. We refer to a standard mathematic textbook for economists, e.g., [35, p.391]. To see the solution more clearly, it is useful to change variables so that we start counting from the terminal stage T. That is, we introduce a new variable \(n = 0,1,2,\ldots \) so that \(n = 0 \equiv \tau = T\). This means that Eq. (6) is written as: \(k_{n+1}^{i} = l + m k_{n}^{i}\) which can be solved to get \(k_n^i=m^n k_0 + l(\sum (m^n))\). As we have a geometric series in the brackets, the solution of the equation can be rewritten as: \(k_n^i=\frac{l(1-m^n)}{1-m}+mk_0 \Leftrightarrow k_n^i=m^n[k_0 - \frac{ l}{1-m}] + \frac{ l}{1-m}\), where \(\frac{l}{1-m} = \frac{1}{1-\alpha \beta q} \frac{1}{1-\frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}} = \frac{1}{1-\alpha \beta q} \frac{1}{\frac{(1-\alpha \beta q) - \alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}} = \frac{1}{1-\alpha \beta q - \alpha \beta + \alpha \beta q} = \frac{1}{1- \alpha \beta }\).

  5. The legal principle that treaties must be honored (pacta sunt servanda) is understood to be contingent on the current state of affairs when the treaty was made (rebus sic stantibus).

  6. We provide the source codes (using [33]) to replicate all figures of this paper as an online appendix. These scripts also allow the interested reader to explore the state space further than the examples that we provide here.

  7. In a sense, the lower Z, the stronger is the effect of an increase in T on q. For example if \(Z = 3\), T can only take the values 1, 2 and 3. If \(T=1\), \(q=\frac{2}{3}\) and \(d_\mathrm{max} = 0.49\). When \(T = 2\), \(q=\frac{1}{3}\) and \(d_{\max } = 0.62\), and when \(T = 3\), \(q= 0\) and \(d_{\max } = 0.62\). Now when \(Z = 50\), \(q = 0.3\) when \(T = 35\) and \(q= 0.28\) when \(T=36\). The associated change in \(d_{\max }\) will be much smaller.

  8. Interestingly, a pessimistic shift in one player’s prior may exacerbate the problem of the commons due to the strategic interactions.

References

  1. Acemoglu D (2003) Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. J Comp Econ 31(4):620–652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Antoniadou E, Koulovatianos C, Mirman LJ (2013) Strategic exploitation of a common-property resource under uncertainty. J Environ Econ Manag 65(1):28–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Barrett S (1994) Self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Oxf Econ Pap 46:878–894

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Blenckner T, Llope M, Möllmann C, Voss R, Quaas MF, Casini M, Lindegren M, Folke C, Chr. Stenseth, N (2015) Climate and fishing steer ecosystem regeneration to uncertain economic futures. In: Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences, vol. 282, p 1803

  5. Brander K (2008) Tackling the old familiar problems of pollution, habitat alteration and overfishing will help with adapting to climate change. Mar Pollut Bull 56(12):1957–1958

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Breton M, Keoula MY (2012) Farsightedness in a coalitional great fish war. Environ Resour Econ 51(2):297–315

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Breton M, Keoula MY (2014) A great fish war model with asymmetric players. Ecol Econ 97:209–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Casini M, Blenckner T, Möllmann C, Gårdmark A, Lindegren M, Llope M, Kornilovs G, Plikshs M, Stenseth NC (2012) Predator transitory spillover induces trophic cascades in ecological sinks. Proc Natl Acad Sci 109(21):8185–8189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Cheung WW, Lam VW, Sarmiento JL, Kearney K, Watson R, Pauly D (2009) Projecting global marine biodiversity impacts under climate change scenarios. Fish Fish 10(3):235–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Cheung WW, Lam VW, Sarmiento JL, Kearney K, Watson REG, Zeller D, Pauly D (2010) Largescale redistribution of maximum fisheries catch potential in the global ocean under climate change. Glob Change Biol 16(1):24–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Costello C, Kaffine D (2011) Unitization of spatially connected renewable resources. BE J Econ Anal Policy 11(1):1–29

    Google Scholar 

  12. Dixit A, Grossman G, Gul F (2000) The dynamics of political compromise. J Polit Econ 108(3):531–568

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Ellefsen H (2013) The stability of fishing agreements with entry: the northeast atlantic mackerel. Strateg Behav Environ 3(1–2):67–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Fesselmeyer E, Santugini M (2013) Strategic exploitation of a common resource under environmental risk. J Econ Dyn Control 37(1):125–136

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  15. Hannesson R (2007) Global warming and fish migration. Nat Res Model 20(2):301–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Hannesson R (2013) Sharing a migrating fish stock. Mar Resour Econ 28(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Harstad B (2013) The market for conservation and other hostages. CESifo working paper series 4296, CESifo Group Munich

  18. Ishimura G, Herrick S, Sumaila UR (2013a) Fishing games under climate variability: transboundary management of Pacific sardine in the California current system. Environ Econ policy Stud 15(2):189–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Ishimura G, Herrick S, Sumaila UR (2013b) Stability of cooperative management of the Pacific sardine fishery under climate variability. Mar Policy 39:333–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Jensen F, Kronbak LG (2009) Random penalties and renewable resources: a mechanism to reach optimal landings in fisheries. Nat Res Model 22(3):393–414

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  21. Koulovatianos C (2015) Strategic exploitation of a common-property resource under rational learning about its reproduction. Dyn Games Appl 5(1):94–119

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  22. Kwon OS (2006) Partial international coordination in the great fish war. Environ Resour Econ 33(4):463–483

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Laukkanen M (2003) Cooperative and non-cooperative harvesting in a stochastic sequential fishery. J Environ Econ Manag 45(2, Supplement):454–473

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  24. Levhari D, Mirman LJ (1980) The great fish war: an example using a dynamic cournot-nash solution. Bell J Econ 11(1):322–334

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  25. Liu X, Heino M (2013) Comparing proactive and reactive management: managing a transboundary fish stock under changing environment. Nat Res Model 26(4):480–504

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  26. Liu X, Lindroos M, Sandal L (2014) Sharing a fish stock when distribution and harvest costs are density dependent. Environ Resour Econ 63(3):665–686

  27. Long NV (1975) Resource extraction under the uncertainty about possible nationalization. J Econ Theory 10(1):42–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Long NV (2010) A survey of dynamic games in economics. World Scientific, Singapore

  29. McKelvey R, Miller K, Golubtsov P (2003) Fish wars revisited: a stochastic incomplete-information harvesting game. In: Wesseler J, Weikard H-P, Weaver RD (eds) Risk and uncertainty in environmental and natural resource economics. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 93–112

    Google Scholar 

  30. Miller KA, Munro GR, Sumaila UR, Cheung WWL (2013) Governing marine fisheries in a changing climate: a game-theoretic perspective. Can J Agric Econ 61(2):309–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Miller S, Nkuiya B (2014) Coalition formation in fisheries with potential regime shift. Unpublished working paper, University of California, Santa Barbara

  32. Munro GR (1979) The optimal management of transboundary renewable resources. Can J Econ/Revue canadienne d’Economique 12(3):355–376

  33. R 3.1.1 (2014) R: a language and environment for statistical computing. R Foundation for Statistical Computing, Vienna. http://www.R-project.org

  34. Ryszka K (2013) Resource extraction in a political economy framework. Discussion paper TI 13-094/VIII, Tinbergen Institute

  35. Sydsæter K, Hammond P, Seierstad A, Strøm A (2005) Further mathematics for economic analysis. Prentice Hall, Harlow

    Google Scholar 

  36. Tarui N, Mason CF, Polasky S, Ellis G (2008) Cooperation in the commons with unobservable actions. J Environ Econ Manag 55(1):37–51

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  37. Vislie J (1987) On the optimal management of transboundary renewable resources: a comment on Munro’s paper. Can J Econ/Revue canadienne d’Economique 20(4):870–875

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Chris Costello, Rögnvaldur Hannesson, Marko Lindroos, Bruno Nkuiya and seminar participants at UCSB, the 2014 IIFET conference in Brisbane, the 2014 NorMER meeting in Copenhagen and the 2015 EAERE conference in Helsinki for their constructive comments and feedback. All remaining errors are, of course, our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Florian K. Diekert.

Additional information

This research is funded by NorMER, a Nordic Centre of Excellence for Research on Marine Ecosystems and Resources under Climate Change.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 65 KB)

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Parameter Overview

See Table 2.

Table 2 Overview of the used parameters

1.2 Proofs

1.2.1 Proof of Proposition 1

The existence of the first phase follows from the assumption that \(s_0 = 1\) so that player A is the sole owner in the first stage of the game and player B cannot extract anything. The existence of the last phase follows from the assumption that \(s_T = 0\) and player A cannot extract anything. The second phase may not exist (e.g., when \(T = 1\)).

Consider the first phase (Eq. 10). Player B’s extraction rate is constrained by the share \(1-s_{\tau }\) accessible to him. This share is increasing as \(s_{\tau }\) decreases. The extraction rate of player A is given by \(a_{\tau } = s_{\tau } \gamma ^A_{\tau }\). This may in principle increase or decrease. Clearly, \(s_{\tau }\) is declining with \(\tau \), but \(\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\) increases with \(\tau \):

$$\begin{aligned} \gamma ^A_{\tau +1} - \gamma _{\tau }^{A}> 0&\Leftrightarrow \frac{1}{1+\alpha \beta \varphi _{\tau +1}^A} - \frac{1}{1+\alpha \beta \varphi _{\tau }^A} > 0 \quad \Leftrightarrow \quad \varphi _{\tau }^A > \varphi _{\tau +1}^A \\&\Leftrightarrow q k^{A}_{\tau }+(1-q)k^{A}_{\tau +1} > q k^{A}_{\tau +1}+(1-q)k^{A}_{\tau +2} \end{aligned}$$

The last line is true because \(k^{A}_{\tau } > k^{A}_{\tau +1}\), as we have discussed in relation to Eq. (7) on page 9. In spite of this indeterminacy, it is possible to show that the total extraction rate in the first phase, which we denote \(d^I_{\tau }\) for clarity, increases with \(\tau \):

$$\begin{aligned} d^{I}_{\tau +1} > d^{I}_{\tau }&\Leftrightarrow s_{\tau +1} \gamma ^A_{\tau +1} + 1 - s_{\tau +1} > s_{\tau } \gamma ^A_{\tau } + 1 - s_{\tau } \\&\Leftrightarrow s_{\tau +1} (\gamma ^A_{\tau +1} - 1) > s_{\tau } (\gamma ^A_{\tau } - 1) \quad \Leftrightarrow \quad \frac{s_{\tau +1}}{s_{\tau } } < \frac{\gamma ^A_{\tau }-1}{\gamma ^A_{\tau +1}-1} \end{aligned}$$

The change in sign in the last line occurs because \(\gamma _{\tau }^{A}< 1\) for all \(\tau \). The left-hand side of the last inequality is smaller than one as \(s_{\tau +1} < s_{\tau }\) by construction. The right-hand side, however, is larger than one: \(\frac{\gamma ^A_{\tau }-1}{\gamma ^A_{\tau +1}-1} > 1 \Leftrightarrow \gamma ^A_{\tau }-1 < \gamma ^A_{\tau +1}-1 \Leftrightarrow \gamma ^A_{\tau +1} > \gamma _{\tau }^{A}\). The first phase ends when \(1-s_{\tau } \ge \frac{\gamma ^B (1-\gamma _{\tau }^A)}{1-\gamma _{\tau }^A\gamma ^B} \Leftrightarrow s_{\tau } \le \frac{\alpha \beta }{1-(1-\alpha \beta )\gamma _{\tau }^A} \).

Consider the second phase. Equating the two non-binding best replies \(a_{\tau } = \gamma ^A_{\tau } (1-b_{\tau })\) and \(b_{\tau } = \gamma ^B (1-a_{\tau })\) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} a_{\tau }&= (1\!- \!\gamma ^B(1-a_{\tau }) )\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\Leftrightarrow a_{\tau } = \gamma ^A_{\tau }- \gamma ^A_{\tau } \gamma ^B + a_{\tau } \gamma ^A_{\tau } \gamma ^B \quad \Leftrightarrow \quad a_{\tau } = \frac{ \gamma _{\tau }^{A}(1-\gamma ^B)}{1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B} \end{aligned}$$

The case for player B is symmetric. The total extraction rate is \(d^{II}_{\tau } = a_{\tau } + b_{\tau } = \frac{ \gamma _{\tau }^{A}(1-\gamma ^B) + \gamma ^B(1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A})}{1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B}\). It is increasing with \(\tau \) when the following holds:

$$\begin{aligned} d^{II}_{\tau +1} \!- \!d^{II}_{\tau } =&\frac{(\gamma ^A_{\tau +1} \!-\! 2 \gamma ^A_{\tau \!+\!1} \gamma ^B \!+\! \gamma ^B)(1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B)-(\gamma _{\tau }^{A}- 2 \gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B \!+\!\gamma ^B)(1\!-\!\gamma ^A_{\tau +1}\gamma ^B)}{(1\!-\!\gamma ^A_{\tau +1}\gamma ^B)(1\!-\!\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B)} \!>\! 0 \end{aligned}$$

Because the denominator is positive (\(\gamma _{\tau }^{A}< 1\) and \(\gamma ^B <1\)), this is equivalent to:

$$\begin{aligned}&(\gamma ^A_{\tau +1}-\gamma ^A_{\tau })(1+(\gamma ^B)^2-2\gamma ^B) > 0. \end{aligned}$$

This inequality holds because the first bracket is positive, and since \(\gamma ^B=1-\alpha \beta \), the second bracket reduces to \((\alpha \beta )^2\), which is also positive.

Total extraction in the third phase is \(d^{III}_{\tau } = s_{\tau } + (1-s_{\tau }) \gamma ^B = 1-\alpha \beta +\alpha \beta s_{\tau }\). This is declining as \(\tau \rightarrow T\) simply due to the fact that \(s_{\tau } > s_{\tau +1}\).

1.2.2 Proof of Proposition 2

In the following, it will be useful to define the following auxiliary parameters:

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi ^A_{\tau } \equiv qk_{\tau }^A + (1-q)k_{\tau +1}^A \qquad {\text {and}} \qquad \varphi ^B \equiv \frac{1}{1-\alpha \beta } \end{aligned}$$

We start by conjecturing that \(V_{\tau }^{\mathrm{coop}, i}\) and \(V_{\tau }^{\mathrm{nc}, i}\) are of the usual log-linear form and that the coefficients \(k_{\tau }^A\) and \(k_{\tau }^B\) take the form as described by Eq. (7). Taking the perspective of player A, her relevant value functions are:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{\tau }^{\mathrm{coop}, A}(\lambda , x_t) =&\ln \lambda (1-\alpha \beta ) + \ln x_t + \\&\ldots \beta \left( q\left[ k_{\tau }^A \ln x_{t+1} + K_{\tau }^{\mathrm{coop}, A} \right] + (1-q)\left[ k_{\tau +1}^A \ln x_{t+1} + K_{\tau +1}^{A} \right] \right) \\ V_{\tau }^{\mathrm{nc}, A}(\lambda , x_t) =&\ln a_{\tau } + \ln x_t +\\&\ldots \beta \left( q\left[ k_{\tau }^A \ln x_{t+1} + K_{\tau }^{\mathrm{nc}, A} \right] + (1-q)\left[ k_{\tau +1}^A \ln x_{t+1} + K_{\tau +1}^{A} \right] \right) \end{aligned}$$

Note that \(x_{t+1} = M\left( \alpha \beta x_t\right) ^{\alpha }\) under cooperation but \(x_{t+1} = M\left( (1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }) x_t\right) ^{\alpha }\) under non-cooperation. Equating coefficients therefore shows that indeed \(k_{\tau }^A = 1 + \alpha \beta \varphi ^A_{\tau }\) as in the non-cooperative case:

$$\begin{aligned} k_{\tau }^A \ln x_{t} + K_{\tau }^{\mathrm{coop}, A} =&\ln \lambda (1-\alpha \beta ) + \ln x_t +\\&\ldots \beta \left( q\left[ k_{\tau }^A (\ln M + \alpha \ln \alpha \beta + \alpha \ln x_t) + K_{\tau }^{\mathrm{coop}, A} \right] + \right. \\&\ldots \left. (1-q)\left[ k_{\tau +1}^A (\ln M + \alpha \ln \alpha \beta + \alpha \ln x_t) + K_{\tau +1}^{A} \right] \right) \end{aligned}$$

We have also:

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\beta q)K_{\tau }^{\mathrm{coop}, A}&= \ln \lambda (1-\alpha \beta ) + \beta \left( (1-q)K^A_{\tau +1} + \varphi ^A_{\tau }(\ln M + \alpha \ln \alpha \beta )\right) \end{aligned}$$
(20)

For the non-cooperative case, equating coefficients yields:

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\beta q)K_{\tau }^{\mathrm{nc}, A}&= \ln a_{\tau } + \beta \left( (1-q)K^A_{\tau +1} + \varphi ^A_{\tau }(\ln M + \alpha \ln (1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau })\right) \end{aligned}$$
(21)

Player A’s participation constraint is satisfied when:

$$\begin{aligned} V_{\tau }^{\mathrm{coop}, A}(\lambda , x_t) - V_{\tau }^{\mathrm{nc}, A}(x_t)&= k_{\tau }^A \ln x_{t} + K_{\tau }^{\mathrm{coop}, A} - \left( k_{\tau }^A \ln x_{t} + K_{\tau }^{\mathrm{nc}, A} \right) \ge 0 \end{aligned}$$

Clearly, the term \(k_{\tau }^A \ln x_{t}\) cancels. Similarly, inspecting (20) and (21), we see that the term \(K_{\tau +1}^A\), capturing the further development of the game, enters in the same manner in those two equations. Thus, it cancels as well. Therefore, we can define player A’s gain from cooperation by \(g^A\):

$$\begin{aligned} g^A(\lambda )&= \frac{1}{1-\beta q} \left( \ln \lambda + \ln \left( \frac{1-\alpha \beta }{a_{\tau }}\right) + \alpha \beta \varphi ^A_{\tau }\ln \left( \frac{\alpha \beta }{1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }}\right) \right) \end{aligned}$$
(22)

Whether this \(g^A(\lambda ) > 0\) is in fact independent of the current stock level and the future development of the game.

1.2.3 There is Not Always Scope for Cooperation

To see that there cannot always be scope for cooperation, note that \(g^A(\lambda )\) is increasing in \(\lambda \) and reaches its maximum at \(\lambda = 1\). We now show that \(g^A(1) < 0\) as \(\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1\) or \(q \rightarrow 0\), so that player A would not join an agreement, even if she were offered the entire harvest.

To show that \(g^A(1) < 0\) as \(q \rightarrow 0\), consider A’s gain from cooperation at stage \(T-1\). At this stage we have \(\lim _{q \rightarrow 0} \varphi _{T-1}^A = 0\) and consequently \(a_{T-1} = s_{T-1}\) (Player A will harvest all she can before she loses the resource for sure). We have \(g^A(1) < 0 \Leftrightarrow \ln \left( \frac{1-\alpha \beta }{a_{\tau }}\right) < 0 \Leftrightarrow 1-\alpha \beta < a_{T-1}\). When \(s_{T-1} < 1-\alpha \beta \), we need to consider the game at stage \(\tau < T-1\). But from backward induction, it follows that \(a_{\tau } = s_{\tau }\) for all \(\tau \) and consequently \(b_{\tau } = (1-s_{\tau })(1-\alpha \beta )\). Now there will be some \(\tau \) at which \(s_{\tau } > 1-\alpha \beta \) and since \(\varphi ^A_{\tau }\) is bounded above by \(\frac{1}{1-\alpha \beta }\) we know that at some stage (as \(s_{\tau } \rightarrow 1\)) we have \(\ln (1-\alpha \beta ) - (1+\alpha \beta \varphi ^A_{\tau })\ln s_{\tau } < 0\) and thus \(g^A(1) < 0\) .

Consider now the case when \(\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1\). We have that \(g^A(1) < 0\) whenever:

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \ln \left( \frac{1-\alpha \beta }{a_{\tau }}\right) + \alpha \beta \varphi ^A_{\tau }\ln \left( \frac{\alpha \beta }{1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }}\right)&< 0 \end{aligned}$$

To evaluate this limit, we need a few building stones. Consider first \(k^{A}_{\tau }, \varphi ^A_{\tau }\) and \(\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\), where we use L’Hôpital’s rule to show that these terms converge to some constant \(\kappa \):

$$\begin{aligned} \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} k^{A}_{\tau }&= \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \left[ \frac{1}{1-\alpha \beta }\left( 1-\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau }\right) \right] \\&= \frac{ \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \left[ -(T-\tau )\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1- q)}{1- \alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau -1}\left( \frac{1-q}{(1-\alpha \beta q)^2}\right) \right] }{ \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} - 1} \\&= (T\!-\!\tau ) \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \left[ \left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1\!-\! q)}{1\!-\! \alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau -1} \right] \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \left[ \frac{1\!-\!q}{(1\!-\!\alpha \beta q)^2} \right] \!=\! \frac{ T-\tau }{1-q} = \kappa _1 > 0 \\ \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \varphi ^A_{\tau }&= \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} q k^{A}_{\tau }+(1-q)k^{A}_{\tau +1} = q\frac{(T-\tau )}{(1-q)} + T - \tau -1 = \kappa _2 > 0 \\ \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \gamma _{\tau }^{A}&= \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \frac{1}{1+\alpha \beta \varphi ^A} = \kappa _3 > 0 \\ \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \gamma ^B&= \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} (1-\alpha \beta ) = 0 \end{aligned}$$

And therefore:

$$\begin{aligned}&\lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} a_{\tau } = \left\{ \begin{array}{lll} \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} s_{\tau }\gamma _{\tau }^{A}&{} = s_{\tau }\kappa _3 &{} \quad {\text {Phase I}}\\ \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \frac{\gamma _{\tau }^{A}(1-\gamma ^B)}{1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B} &{} = \kappa _3 &{} \quad {\text {Phase II}} \\ \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} s_{\tau } &{} = s_{\tau } &{} \quad {\text {Phase III}} \end{array} \right. \quad \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} b_{\tau } = \left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} 1-s_{\tau } &{} = 1-s_{\tau } \\ \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \frac{\gamma ^B(1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A})}{1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B} &{} = 0 \\ \lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} (1-s_{\tau })\gamma ^B &{} = 0 \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$

Hence, \(\lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \ln \left( \frac{1-\alpha \beta }{a_{\tau }}\right) = -\infty \), but \(\lim _{\alpha \beta \rightarrow 1} \alpha \beta \varphi ^A_{\tau }\ln \left( \frac{\alpha \beta }{1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }}\right) = \kappa _2 \ln \left( \frac{1}{1-s_{\tau }\kappa _3}\right) \) in Phase I, \(= \kappa _2 \ln \left( \frac{1}{1-\kappa _3}\right) \) in Phase II, and \(= \kappa _2 \ln \left( \frac{1}{1-s_{\tau }}\right) \) in Phase III. In any case, it is bounded above so that the entire term \(\left[ \ln \left( \frac{1-\alpha \beta }{a_{\tau }}\right) + \alpha \beta \varphi ^A_{\tau }\ln \left( \frac{\alpha \beta }{1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }}\right) \right] \) must be smaller than zero as claimed.

1.2.4 Derivation of \(\lambda _\mathrm{min}^A\) and \(\lambda _\mathrm{max}^B\)

Now consider the situation where \(\alpha \beta \) take values such that \(g^A(\lambda _\mathrm{min}^A) = 0\) exists. By rewriting Eq. (22) and taking exponents on both sides, we get:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _\mathrm{min}^A&= \frac{a_{\tau }}{1-\alpha \beta } \left( \frac{1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }}{\alpha \beta } \right) ^{\alpha \beta \varphi ^A_{\tau }} \end{aligned}$$
(23)

By parallel reasoning, player B’s participation constraint is satisfied when \(V_{\tau }^{\mathrm{coop}, B} - V_{\tau }^{\mathrm{nc}, B} \ge 0\) and \(\lambda _\mathrm{max}^B\), the maximum share that player B would be willing to give to player A and still harvest cooperatively is—if it exists —defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _\mathrm{max}^B&= 1 - \frac{b_{\tau }}{1-\alpha \beta } \left( \frac{1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }}{\alpha \beta } \right) ^{\alpha \beta \varphi ^B} \end{aligned}$$
(24)

1.2.5 Cooperation Possibilities are not Constrained by the Available Harvest Shares

At any stage \(\tau \), player A needs to harvest at least \((1-\alpha \beta )\lambda _\mathrm{min}^A\) to join the agreement. This is less than he would harvest under non-cooperation:

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha \beta )\lambda _\mathrm{min}^A&< a_{\tau } \quad \Leftrightarrow \quad a_{\tau }\left( \frac{1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }}{\alpha \beta } \right) ^{\alpha \beta \varphi ^A_{\tau }} < a_{\tau } \quad \Leftrightarrow \quad \left( \frac{1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }}{\alpha \beta } \right) ^{\alpha \beta \varphi ^A_{\tau }} < 1 \end{aligned}$$

The last statement is true because \(1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau } = 1-d^{\mathrm{nc}} < 1-d^* = \alpha \beta \) and \(\alpha \beta \varphi > 0\) and a function \(x^y < 1\) when \(x<1\) and \(y>0\). For player B, the argumentation is parallel:

$$\begin{aligned} (1\!-\!\alpha \beta )\left( 1\!-\!\lambda _\mathrm{max}^B\right)&< \!b_{\tau } \!\quad \Leftrightarrow \quad \! b_{\tau }\left( \frac{1-a_{\tau }-b_{\tau }}{\alpha \beta } \right) ^{\alpha \beta \varphi ^B} \!<\! b_{\tau } \!\quad \Leftrightarrow \quad \! \left( \frac{1\!-\!a_{\tau }\!-\!b_{\tau }}{\alpha \beta } \right) ^{\alpha \beta \varphi ^B} \!<\! 1 \end{aligned}$$

As \(a_{\tau } \le s_{\tau }\) and \(b_{\tau } \le 1-s_{\tau }\) by construction, it follows immediately that cooperation possibilities are not constrained by the accessible harvest shares.

This completes the proof of Proposition 2.

1.2.6 Proof of Proposition 3

To show how the extraction pattern changes with, we need to derive \(\frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial q} \)(\(k^B\) and thus \(\gamma ^B\) do not depend on q). In this derivation, we will again employ the following auxiliary parameters to make the derivations more concise.

$$\begin{aligned} \varphi ^A_{\tau } \equiv qk_{\tau }^A + (1-q)k_{\tau +1}^A \qquad {\text {and}} \qquad \varphi ^B \equiv \frac{1}{1-\alpha \beta } \end{aligned}$$

To start, consider \(\frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial q}\) :

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial q}&= \frac{-(T-\tau )\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau -1}\left( \frac{-\alpha \beta (1-\alpha \beta q)-\alpha \beta (1-q)(-\alpha \beta )}{(1-\alpha \beta q)^2}\right) }{1-\alpha \beta } \nonumber \\&= -(T-\tau )\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau -1}\left( \frac{ - \alpha \beta }{(1-\alpha \beta q)^2 }\right) > 0 \end{aligned}$$
(25)

The above follows from \(T>\tau \) and because the term \(\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) > 0\) as \(\alpha , \beta \) and \(q \in (0,1)\). As a consequence:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \varphi _{\tau }^A}{\partial q}&= k_{\tau }^A + q\frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial q} - k_{\tau +1}^A + (1-q) \frac{\partial k_{\tau +1}^A}{\partial q} \nonumber \\&= k_{\tau }^A - k_{\tau +1}^A + q \left( \frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial q} -\frac{\partial k_{\tau +1}^A}{\partial q} \right) + \frac{\partial k_{\tau +1}^A}{\partial q} > 0 \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Here, we have to show that \(\frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial q} > \frac{\partial k_{\tau +1}^A}{\partial q}\) for all \(k_{\tau }^A > k_{\tau +1}^A\) and \(q>0\) and \(\frac{\partial k_{\tau +1}^A}{\partial q} > 0\). From (25) we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial q} \!- \!\frac{\partial k_{\tau +1}^A}{\partial q} \!>\! 0&\Leftrightarrow \! (T-\tau -1)\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1\!-\!\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau -2}-(T-\tau )\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1\!-\!\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau -1} \!>\! 0 \\&\Leftrightarrow (T-\tau -1)\left( \frac{1-\alpha \beta q}{\alpha \beta (1-q)}\right) > T-\tau \\&\Leftrightarrow T-\tau -1 > \alpha \beta (T-\tau - q) \end{aligned}$$

This is true because \(\alpha , \beta \) and \(q \in (0,1)\). This implies:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial q}&= \frac{-\alpha \beta \frac{\partial \varphi _{\tau }^A}{\partial q}}{(1+\alpha \beta \varphi ^A)^{2}} < 0 \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Furthermore, we need to derive \( \frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial T} \) (\(k^B\) and thus \(\varphi ^B\) and \(\gamma ^B\) do not depend on T). Again, consider first \(\frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial T}\) :

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial T}&= \frac{-1}{1-\alpha \beta }\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau }\ln \left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q} \right) > 0 \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Since \(\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q} \right) < 1\), the logarithm yields a negative number, so that the entire term is positive. Consequently:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \varphi _{\tau }^A}{\partial T} = q \frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial T} + (1-q) \frac{\partial k_{\tau +1}^A}{\partial T} > 0 \end{aligned}$$
(29)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad \frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial T} = \frac{-\alpha \beta \frac{\partial \varphi _{\tau }^A}{\partial T}}{(1+\alpha \beta \varphi ^A)^{2}} < 0 \end{aligned}$$
(30)

In the first phase, player B is harvesting the entire share available to him (\(b^{I}_{\tau } = 1-s_{\tau }\)). Hence his extraction rate does not depend on q. It does depend on T, however, since \(s_{\tau } = \frac{T- \tau }{T}\). \(s_{\tau }\) increases with T so that \(b^{I}_{\tau }\) decreases. From (27), it follows that player A’s and thus the total extraction rate is decreasing in q. Regarding an increase in T, we see from (30) that \(\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\) decreases, but \(s_{\tau }\) increases. The total effect is still negative:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial d_{\tau }^{I} }{\partial T} =&\frac{\partial s_{\tau }}{\partial T} \gamma _{\tau }^{A}+ s_{\tau } \frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^{A}}{\partial T} - \frac{\partial s_{\tau }}{\partial T} < 0 \\&\Leftrightarrow \frac{\partial s_{\tau }}{\partial T} \gamma _{\tau }^{A}+ s_{\tau } \frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^{A}}{\partial T} - \frac{\partial s_{\tau }}{\partial T} <0 \\&\Leftrightarrow s_{\tau } \frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^{A}}{\partial T} < (1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A})\frac{\partial s_{\tau }}{\partial T} \end{aligned}$$

This is true because \(\frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^{A}}{\partial T} <0\) and all other terms are positive (and \(\gamma _{\tau }^{A}<1\)).

In the second phase, we have \(d^{II} =\frac{\gamma _{\tau }^{A}+\gamma ^B-2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B}{1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B}\). Consequently:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial d_{\tau }^{II} }{\partial q}&= \frac{\left( \frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial q}-\frac{ \partial 2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B}{\partial q}\right) \left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) - \frac{ \partial (1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B)}{\partial q}\left( \gamma _{\tau }^{A}+\gamma ^B-2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) }{\left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) ^2} \\&= \frac{\left( \frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial q}-2\gamma ^B\frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial q} \right) \left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B \right) + \gamma ^B\frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial q}\left( \gamma _{\tau }^{A}+\gamma ^B-2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) }{(1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B)^2} \\&= \frac{(1-\gamma ^B)^2\frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^{A}}{\partial q}}{\left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) ^2} =\frac{(\alpha \beta )^2\frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial q}}{\left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) ^2} \end{aligned}$$

As we know, \((\alpha \beta )^2>0\) and \(\frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial q}<0\) (confer (27)), which implies a negative nominator and a positive denominator. Consequently, the total extraction is decreasing in q.

Similarly:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial d_{\tau }^{II} }{\partial T}&= \frac{\left( \frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial T}-\frac{\partial 2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B}{\partial T} \right) \left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) - \frac{\partial (1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B)}{\partial T} \left( \gamma _{\tau }^{A}+\gamma ^B-2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) }{\left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) ^2} \\&=\frac{(\alpha \beta )^2\frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial T}}{\left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) ^2} \end{aligned}$$

Again, \((\alpha \beta )^2>0\) and \(\frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial T}<0\) (following from (30)) , which implies a negative nominator and a positive denominator. Consequently, the total extraction is decreasing in T in the second phase.

In the third phase, neither player’s extraction rate reacts to changes in q. Instead, both player’s extraction rates depend on T as \(a^{III}_{\tau }=s_{\tau }\) and \(b^{III}_{\tau }=(1-s_{\tau })\gamma ^B\). As an increase in T means a larger \(s_{\tau }\), the extraction rate of player A increases in T, and consequently player B’s extraction rate decreases. The total effect is increasing, as player B’s declining effect is smaller than the effect of player A (\(1-\alpha \beta <1\)).

1.2.7 Proof of Proposition 4

To see that an increase in \(\alpha \) or \(\beta \) (and hence \(\alpha \beta \)) leads to a lower total extraction rate in all phases, we first need to establish \(\frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta } < 0\) and \(\frac{\partial \gamma ^B}{\partial \alpha \beta } < 0\). As \(\gamma ^B = 1-\alpha \beta \), the sign of the latter derivative is obvious. For \( \gamma _{\tau }^A = (1+\alpha \beta (qk_{\tau }^A + (1-q)k_{\tau +1}^A))^{-1}\), it is more involved. We first need to show that \( \frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta } > 0\):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta }&= \frac{\left( 1-\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau }\right) -(T-\tau )\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau -1}\left( \frac{(1-q)(1-\alpha \beta q) + \alpha \beta q(1-q)}{(1-\alpha \beta q)^2}\right) (1-\alpha \beta ) }{(1-\alpha \beta )^2} > 0 \\&\Leftrightarrow \left( 1-\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau }\right) > (T-\tau )\left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau -1}\left( \frac{(1-q)(1-\alpha \beta )}{(1-\alpha \beta q)^2}\right) \\&\Leftrightarrow \left( \frac{\alpha \beta (1-q)}{1-\alpha \beta q}\right) ^{\tau -T} - 1 > (T-\tau )\left( \frac{1-\alpha \beta q}{\alpha \beta (1-q)}\right) \frac{(1-q)(1-\alpha \beta )}{(1-\alpha \beta q)^2} \\&\Leftrightarrow \left( \frac{1-\alpha \beta q}{\alpha \beta - \alpha \beta q}\right) ^{T-\tau }\!- \!1\! >\! (T\!-\!\tau ) \frac{1-\alpha \beta }{\alpha \beta (1\!-\!\alpha \beta q)} \end{aligned}$$

We know that this holds because at \(\tau = T-1\) (the largest value that \(\tau \) can take at which \(k_{\tau }^A\) is still strictly positive), the last line reads: \(\frac{1-\alpha \beta q}{\alpha \beta - \alpha \beta q}- 1 > \frac{1-\alpha \beta }{\alpha \beta (1-\alpha \beta q)}\). This can be transformed to \(q(1-\alpha \beta )^2>0\) which is true because \(q < 1\) and \(\alpha \beta < 1\). For \(\tau > T-1\) the left-hand side (LHS) of the above inequality is growing exponentially, while the right-hand side (RHS) is growing linearly.

The subsequent comparative static results follow immediately from \(\frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta } > 0 \):

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \left[ qk_{\tau }^A + (1-q)k_{\tau +1}^A\right] }{\partial \alpha \beta } = q \frac{\partial k_{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta } + (1-q) \frac{\partial k_{\tau +1}^A}{\partial \alpha \beta } > 0 \nonumber \\&\quad \frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta } = \frac{-\left[ qk_{\tau }^A + (1-q)k_{\tau +1}^A\right] - \alpha \beta \frac{\partial \left[ qk_{\tau }^A + (1-q)k_{\tau +1}^A\right] }{\partial \alpha \beta } }{\left( 1+\alpha \beta [qk_{\tau }^A + (1-q)k_{\tau +1}^A]\right) ^2} < 0 \end{aligned}$$
(31)

In the first phase, Player B’s extraction rate is given by \(b_{\tau }^I = 1-s_{\tau }\) and does not depend on \(\alpha \beta \). Player A’s extraction rate in the first phase is given by \(a_{\tau }^I = s_{\tau } \gamma _{\tau }^{A}\) and \(\frac{\partial a_{\tau }^I }{\partial \alpha \beta } = s_{\tau }\frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta } < 0\), which follows from (31).

In Phase II, total extraction is \(d^{II}_\tau =a^{II}_{\tau }+b_{\tau }^{II} =\frac{\gamma _\tau ^A(1-\gamma ^B)}{1-\gamma _\tau ^A\gamma ^B} +\frac{\gamma ^B(1-\gamma _\tau ^A)}{1-\gamma _\tau ^A\gamma ^B}=\frac{\gamma _{\tau }^{A}+\gamma ^B-2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B}{1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B}\). Consequently:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial d_{\tau }^{II} }{\partial \alpha \beta }&= \frac{\left( \frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta }+\frac{ \partial \gamma ^B}{\partial \alpha \beta }-\frac{ \partial 2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B}{\partial \alpha \beta } \right) \left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) - \frac{ \partial (1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B)}{\partial \alpha \beta }\left( \gamma _{\tau }^{A}+\gamma ^B-2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) }{\left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) ^2} \\&= \frac{\left( \frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta }\!-\!1\!+\!2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\!-\!2\gamma ^B\frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta }\right) \left( 1\!-\!\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) \!-\! \left( \gamma _{\tau }^{A}-\gamma ^B\frac{ \partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta }\right) \left( \gamma _{\tau }^{A}+\gamma ^B-2\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) }{\left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) ^2} \\&= \frac{(\alpha \beta )^2\frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta }-\left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\right) ^2}{\left( 1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B\right) ^2} \end{aligned}$$

As \((\alpha \beta )^2>0\), \(\frac{\partial \gamma _{\tau }^A}{\partial \alpha \beta }<0\) and \((1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A})^2>0\), the nominator is negative. Additionally, the denominator is \((1-\gamma _{\tau }^{A}\gamma ^B)^2>0\), and consequently the total extraction is decreasing in \(\alpha \beta \) in the second phase.

In the third phase, player A’s extraction rate is independent of \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \), and thus changes in those do not affect her extraction rate. However, player B’s extraction is linearly dependent on both \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \) as \(b_\tau =(1-s_{\tau })1-\alpha \beta \), and an increase in those parameters results in a decrease in player B’s and consequently in the total extraction rate.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Diekert, F.K., Nieminen, E. International Fisheries Agreements with a Shifting Stock. Dyn Games Appl 7, 185–211 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-016-0184-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-016-0184-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation