Skip to main content
Log in

Sexual Orientation and Wage Discrimination in France: The Hidden Side of the Rainbow

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article is the first study to present an econometric evaluation of wage discrimination based on sexual orientation in the French labor market. Having identified same-sex couples using the French Employment Survey, we estimate the wage gap related to sexual orientation in the private and public sectors, in order to analyze whether or not lesbians and gays suffer a wage penalty. The results obtained show the existence of a wage penalty for homosexual male workers, as compared with their heterosexual counterparts, in both the private and public sectors; the magnitude of this discrimination varies from about −6.5 % in the private sector, to −5.5 % in the public sector. In the private sector, the wage penalty suffered by gay employees is higher for skilled workers than for the unskilled, and—in both sectors—the wage penalty is higher for older workers than for younger ones. As with many other countries, we do not find any evidence of the existence of a wage discrimination against lesbians.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Badgett (2006) for a survey of this literature.

  2. If a significant proportion of heterosexual employees is homophobic, hiring homosexual workers can lead to a decrease in individual productivity of both homosexuals (harassment, depression, lack of motivation, etc.) and heterosexuals (lack of concentration, lost time, etc.).

  3. Oaxaca (1973), in his seminal study on gender wage discrimination, shows that the share of the gender wage gap due to discrimination, decreases from 77 % to 58 % when controlling for industry and occupation.

  4. If the probability of accessing executive positions is lower for homosexuals than for heterosexuals with identical characteristics, but once gays and lesbians become executives they are paid the same, (i) the proportion of gay or lesbian employees among executives will be low (gay glass ceiling) and thus the average wage will be lower for homosexual employees than for heterosexual ones, but (ii) a wage discrimination based on sexual orientation will appear, only if the variable “Executive position vs. non-executive position” is not used as a control variable in the wage equation.

  5. This point is also emphasized by Carpenter (2004)

  6. In a discrimination and signaling framework, it can be profitable for heterosexual workers, in order to obtain higher wages, to use marriage as a signal of heterosexuality (Carpenter 2005b, 2007b; Frank 2006).

  7. This measurement error can however be reduced by filtering populations of cohabitants on the basis of various criteria: age (to eliminate juvenile cohabitation), family links, income (economic cohabitation), nationality (to exclude migrant workers), etc. Several articles show, that identifying homosexual populations via a cohabitation criterion is precise and efficient (see Black et al. 2000; Carpenter 2004) and that the bias associated with this method is less than 0.4 %.

  8. See Arabsheibani et al. (2004, 2005, 2007), Black et al. (2003), Elmslie and tebaldi (2007), Ahmed and Hammarstedt (2009), Carpenter (2004, 2007a, 2008b) and, for France, Digoix et al. (2004), Toulemon et al. (2005). On average, in these various studies, about 27 % of heterosexual men and women have college education, as compared with 43 % of gays and over 48 % of lesbians

  9. Same references as the previous footnote

  10. On average, in the various studies, about 40 % of heterosexual men and women have children as compared with 4.5 % of gays and 18 % of lesbians (same references that supra; see also Frank 2006)

  11. Especially the correction, or not, of the selection bias by estimating first a probit model of participation (Heckman two-step estimation).

  12. Articles 225-1, 225-2, 132-77, 222-18-1. English translation of the Code available at: http://www.legifrance.gouv.fr/content/download/1957/13715/version/4/file/Code_33.pdf

  13. For a complete investigation of the various types of discrimination faced by gays and lesbians in the workplace, one can usefully refer to Badgett et al. (2007) for the United States, or Irwin (1999) for Australia.

  14. IPSOS survey conducted in 2004 for the newspaper Têtu, on a national sample of 1,002 persons, representative of the French population over 15 years of age.

  15. European Commission (2008), Discrimination in the European Union: 2008, Eurobarometer Special survey n°296.

  16. 2009 Report on Homophobia, Association SOS Homophobia ed.

  17. CSA Institute, poll n° 0900383: Perception of discriminations in the workplace: viewpoints of private sector employees and of public servants, conducted in March 2009 on national representative samples of private and public sector employees.

  18. The threshold value of 1,000€ has been indexed in accordance with the evolution of the average wage. A lump-sum income of 300 €/month, corresponding to a reservation income, has been attributed to inactive members of the couples. Similarly, a lump-sum income of 1,000€/month has been attributed to independent workers. This value, equal to the first quartile of the distribution of independent workers (Rouault 2001), was selected to be sure that all potential economic cohabitation has been eliminated.

  19. Throughout this article, we use the terms “male homosexuals” or gays—and “female homosexuals” or lesbians—to denote the members of our samples of same-sex couples.

  20. Survey on Sexual Behavior in France (ACSF), conducted in 1992 (cf. Les comportements sexuels en France, Spira A., Bajos N. and the ACSF team, La Documentation Française, Paris, 1993).

  21. In an imperfect information framework such a difference could be explained by a strategic behavior of gay employees, to prevent their employers from accumulating over time a sufficient amount of information, leading to the revelation of their sexual orientation.

  22. See for example Antecol and Steinberger (2009), for an econometric study of the central role played by sexual orientation on labor supply in the US.

  23. The wage w i is a net monthly salary including all monetary compensation.

  24. Note that the cause of the selection bias is not the consequence of having a non-random sample, but arises merely because individuals whose observable characteristics are unfavorable have a large error term in the selection equation

  25. Heckman (1976, 1979).

  26. The residual variance of the earning equation also depends on the Mills ratio and, therefore, on individual characteristics.

  27. The addition of these new variables can be viewed as the introduction of specific constraints necessary for identification.

  28. Sexual orientation is not introduced in the selection equation. Nevertheless, to be cautious, we decided to re-estimate the model with a selection equation including sexual orientation as an explanatory variable. All the estimated parameters of the wage equation and, in particular, the estimates of the wage discrimination remained the same. The results are available upon request.

  29. The definition of the private sector used here includes the large national public companies.

  30. As we use pool data on the period 1996–2007, we include in all regressions time dummies variables to control for structural breaks other the estimation period.

  31. With the semi-logarithmic specification we used, the net impact on wage of the sexual orientation is given by eβi−1 where β i is the estimated coefficient associated with the explanatory variable Gay or Lesbian.

  32. As in the US, the higher level of wages earned by lesbians, compared to heterosexual females, is mainly due to a higher level of investment in human capital, particularly in education (see for example Antecol et al. (2007)).

  33. A lower, but not negligible, wage discrimination in the public sector compared to the private sector, is a result that has already been obtained in several articles: Zweimuller and Winter-Ebmer (1993), Hoffnar and Greene (1996), Berson (2009).

  34. For example, for high-skill jobs, the explanatory variable “Number of children” is statistically significant and plays negatively, while the variable “Number of children × Public sector” is statistically significant and plays positively. This means that the return associated to the number of children in the private sector is equal to e −0.004−1 = −0.4 % while it is equal to e −0.004+0.015−1 = +1.11 % in the public sector.

  35. We focus in this article on wage discrimination only but of course discrimination in low wage jobs can take many other forms than wage differences: barriers to entry for gay men, characteristics that discourage gay men from applying etc.

  36. This explains the lower job stability of gay employees as compared to their heterosexual counterparts (see Table 1).

  37. Cf. Oaxaca (1973), Blinder (1973), Oaxaca and Ransom (1994).

References

  • Ahmed AM, Hammarstedt M (2009) Sexual orientation and earnings: a register data based approach to identify homosexuals. J Popul Econ, July

  • Allegretto SA, Arthur M (2001) An empirical analysis of homosexual/heterosexual male earnings differentials: unmarried and unequal? Ind Labor Relat Rev 54(3), April

  • Antecol H, Steinberger M (2009) Female labor supply differences by sexual orientation: a semi-parametric decomposition approach. IZA Discussion Paper n°4029, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), February

  • Antecol H, Jong A, Steinberger M (2007) The sexual orientation wage gap: the role of occupational sorting, human capital, and discrimination. IZA Discussion Paper n°2945, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), July

  • Arabsheibani GR, Marin A, Wadsworth J (2007) Variations in gay pay in the USA and the UK. In: Badgett L, Frank J (eds) Sexual orientation discrimination: an international perspective. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Arabsheibani GR, Marin A, Wadsworth J (2002) Gays’ pay in the UK, n°8, Royal Economic Society Annual Conference 2002 from Royal Economic Society

  • Arabsheibani GR, Marin A, Wadsworth J (2004) In the pink: homosexual/heterosexual wage differentials in the UK. Int J Manpow 25(3–4):343–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arabsheibani GR, Marin A, Wadsworth J (2005) Gays’ pay in the UK. Economica 72:333–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K (1973) The theory of discrimination. In: Ashenfelter O, Rees A (eds) Discrimination in labor markets. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Badgett L (1995) The wage effects of sexual orientation discrimination. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 48(4):726–739

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Badgett L (2001) Money, myths, and change: the economic live of lesbians and gay men. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Badgett L (2006) Discrimination based on sexual orientation: a review of the literature in economics and beyond. In: Rodgers WM III (ed) Handbook on the economics of discrimination. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Badgett L, Lau H, Sears B, Ho D (2007) Bias in the workplace: consistent evidence of sexual orientation and gender identity discrimination. University of California Los Angeles, UCLA, The Williams Institute, June

  • Becker GS (1957) The economics of discrimination. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1965) A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal 75(299):493–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1981) A treatise on the family. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Berg N, Lien D (2002) Measuring the effect of sexual orientation on Income: evidence of discrimination? Contemporary Economic Policy 20(4):394–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berill KT (1992) Anti-gay violence and victimization in the United States: an overview. In: Herek GM, Berill KT (eds) Hate crimes: confronting violence against lesbians and gay men. Sage, Newbury Park

    Google Scholar 

  • Berson C (2009) Private vs. public sector: discrimination against second-generation immigrants in France, Working Paper of the Sorbonne Center for Economics, n°2009-59, University Paris 1 Pantheon-Sorbonne, September

  • Black D, Makar H, Sanders S, Taylor L (2003) The earnings effects of sexual orientation. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 56(3):449–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black D, Gates G, Sanders S, Taylor L (2000) Demographics of the gay and lesbian population in the United States: evidence from available systematic data sources. Demography 37(2):139–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blandford JM (1999) Sexual orientation’s role in the determination of earnings and occupational outcomes: theory and econometric evidence, Dissertation

  • Blandford JM (2000) Evidence on the role of sexual orientation in the determination of earnings outcomes. Working Paper Harris Graduate School of Public Policies Studies, University of Chicago

  • Blandford JM (2003) The nexus of sexual orientation and gender in the determination of earnings. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 56(4):622–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder AS (1973) Wage discrimination: reduced form and structural estimates. The Journal of Human Resources 8:436–455

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calandrino M (1999) Sexual orientation discrimination on the UK labor market. Working Paper St. Antony’s College, University of Oxford

  • Carpenter CS (2004) New evidence on gay and lesbian household incomes. Contemporary Economic Policy 22(1):78–94

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter CS (2005a) Self-reported sexual orientation and earnings: evidence from California. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 58(2):258–273

    Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter CS (2005b) Heterosexual signalling and the marriage premium. Unpublished paper

  • Carpenter CS (2007a) Revisiting the income penalty for behaviorally gay men: evidence from NHANES III. Labour Economics 14:25–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter CS (2007b) Do straight men “come out” at work too? The heterosexual male marriage premium and discrimination against gay men. In: Badgett L, Frank J (eds) Sexual orientation discrimination: an international perspective. Routledge, New York, pp 76–92

    Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter CS (2008a) Sexual orientation, work, and income in Canada. Canadian Journal of Economics 41(4):1239–1261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter CS (2008a) Sexual orientation, income, and non-pecuniary economic outcomes: new evidence from young lesbians in Australia. Review of Economics of the Household, Springer Netherlands ed., Vol. 6, n°4, December, pp 391–408

  • Clain HS, Leppel K (2001) An investigation into sexual orientation discrimination as an explanation for wage differences. Appl Econ 33(1):37–47

    Google Scholar 

  • Digoix M, Festy P, Garnier B (2004) What if same-sex couples exist in France after all? In: Digoix M, Festy P (eds) “Same-sex couples, same-sex partnerships & homosexual marriages: a focus on cross-national differentials”., Ined, Working Paper n°124

  • Elmslie B, Tebaldi E (2007) Sexual orientation and labor market discrimination. Journal of Labor Research 28(3):436–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank J (2006) Gay glass ceilings. Economica 73:485–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank J (2007) Is the male marriage premium evidence of discrimination against gay men? In: Badgett L, Frank J (eds) Sexual orientation discrimination: an international perspective. Routledge Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (1976) The common structure of statistical models of truncation, sample selection and limited dependent variables and a simple estimator of such models. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 5:475–492

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47(1):153–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heineck G (2009) Sexual orientation and earnings: evidence from the ISSP. Applied Economics Letters 16(13):1351–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffnar E, Greene M (1996) Gender discrimination in the public and private sectors: a sample selectivity approach. J Socio-Econ, Elsevier 25(1):105–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irwin J (1999) The pink ceiling is too low: workplace experiences of lesbians, gay men and transgender people. Australian Centre for Lesbian and Gay Research, New South Wales: Gay and Lesbian Rights Lobby

  • Kite ME, Whitley BE (1996) Sex differences in attitudes toward homosexual persons, behaviors, and civil rights: a meta-analysis. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 22:336–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klawitter M (1997) The effects of sexual orientation on the determinants of earnings for women. Working Paper, University of Washington

  • Klawitter M (1998) The determinants of earnings for women in same-sex and different-sex couples. Working Paper, University of Washington

  • Klawitter M, Flatt V (1998) The effects of state and local antidiscrimination policies on earnings for gays and lesbians. J Policy Anal Manag 17(4):658–686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meurs D, Ponthieux S (2000) Une mesure de la discrimination dans l’écart de salaire entre hommes et femmes. Economie et Statistiques, n° 337–338

  • Meurs D, Ponthieux S (2006) L’écart des salaires entre les femmes et les hommes peut-il encore baisser? Economie et Statistiques, n° 398–399

  • Oaxaca RL (1973) Male–female wage differentials in urban labour markets. Int Econ Rev 14:693–709

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oaxaca RL, Ransom MR (1994) On discrimination and the decomposition of wage differentials. Journal of Econometrics 61:5–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pew Research Center for the People and the Press (PRCPP) (2002) What the World Thinks in 2002. Topline Results

  • Phelps ES (1972) The statistical theory of racism and sexism. American Economic Review 62:659–661

    Google Scholar 

  • Plug E, Berkhout P (2004) Effects of sexual preferences on earnings in the Netherlands. Journal of Population Economics 17:117–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plug E, Berkhout P (2008) Sexual orientation, disclosure and earnings,. IZA Discussion Paper, n°3290

  • Rouault D (2001) Les revenus des indépendants et dirigeants: la valorisation du bagage personnel. Economie et Prévision 348:35–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Toulemon L, Vitrac J, Cassan F (2005) Le difficile comptage des couples homosexuels d’après l’enquête EHF. In «Histoires de familles, histoires familiales », sous la direction de Cécile Lefèvre et Alexandra Filhon, Ined, les Cahiers de l’Ined, n° 156, partie IX.32, pp 589–602

  • Zweimuller J, Winter-Ebmer R (1993) Gender wage differentials in private and public sector jobs. J Popul Econ, Springer 7(3):271–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thierry Laurent.

Annex: Variables Used in the Selection and Wage Equations

Annex: Variables Used in the Selection and Wage Equations

Table 11 List of variables used

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Laurent, T., Mihoubi, F. Sexual Orientation and Wage Discrimination in France: The Hidden Side of the Rainbow. J Labor Res 33, 487–527 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-012-9145-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-012-9145-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation