Skip to main content
Log in

Accumulation by Dispossession and Its Limits: The Southern Africa Paradigm Revisited

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The dispossession of agricultural producers from the land has long been considered a condition of successful capitalist development. The main contention of this paper is that such dispossession has in fact become the source of major developmental handicaps for at least some and possibly many countries of the global South. We develop our argument by focusing on the South(ern) African experience as a paradigmatic outlier case of accumulation by dispossession—that is, as one of its extreme instances capable of highlighting in almost ideo-typical fashion its nature and limits. After reconstructing interpretations of capitalist development in Southern Africa that in the early 1970s established the region as a paradigm of accumulation by dispossession, we discuss how useful these interpretations are for understanding the more recent developmental trajectory of South Africa. We then suggest ways in which these interpretations from the 1970s should be reformulated in light of subsequent developments. We conclude by briefly examining the theoretical and policy implications of the analysis.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Harvey himself argues that accumulation by dispossession can be seen as “the necessary cost of making a successful breakthrough to capitalist [and socialist] development”, but he also argues that in some instances (particularly post-1973) accumulation by dispossession, rather than opening up a new path of expanded reproduction, disrupted and destroyed paths that were already open (ibid 154–6).

  2. Seidman (1999: 420, 424–5) citing, among others, Arrighi (1970), Wolpe (1972), and Burawoy (1976).

  3. Amin (1976: 327–8).

  4. Freeman (2005).

  5. Chan (2003: 44–5).

  6. Alexander and Chan (2004: 614, 621; emphasis added)

  7. Hirsch (2005: 182).

  8. Hirsch (2005: 182–3).

  9. Hart (2002: 199–200).

  10. Hart (2002: 201).

  11. Barber (1961: 46, 93, 186–87, 208, 212–18).

  12. Arrighi (1970: 200–22).

  13. Arrighi (1970: 223).

  14. Arrighi (1970: 223–4).

  15. The different dynamics of the recessions of the early 1920s and of the late 1950s vividly illustrates the change. In the early 1920s, falling prices and wages induced businesses (especially in agriculture) to step up investments and absorb the increasingly “unlimited” supply of cheap Africa labor. In the late 1950s, in contrast, the recession led to an outflow of capital and a contraction in investment and the demand for labor. Arrighi (1970: 225–6).

  16. Arrighi (1970: 225–6).

  17. Arrighi (1970: 226).

  18. Legassick (1975: 249).

  19. Legassick (1975: 259–60).

  20. Legassick (1975: 253–5). On the weaker (and later) manifestation of an analogous convergence of interests in Rhodesia, see Arrighi (1967).

  21. Legassick (1975: 260–1).

  22. Legassick (1975: 262–3).

  23. Legassick (1975: 264–5).

  24. Wolpe (1972: 428, 433; second emphasis added). Although this article was published three years before Legassick’s, Wolpe referred to and quoted extensively the latter’s unpublished version.

  25. Wolpe (1972: 447).

  26. Wolpe (1972: 450, 452)

  27. Schneider (2000: 416).

  28. While state-owned monopolies continued to control electricity and water supply, railways and harbors, broadcasting, air transport, and much steel production, state-generated manufacturing capital increased from less than 10 per cent in the 1920s to 25% by the 1970s. Beinert (2001: 176).

  29. Lundahl (1992: 302).

  30. Schneider (2000: 417).

  31. Gelb (1991: 2).

  32. Terreblanche and Nattrass (1990: 9).

  33. Schneider (2000: 419).

  34. Marais (2001: 109). “There was a significant withdrawal of capital when slower growth in the late 1950s was followed by political crisis in 1960. But the government acted decisively to block the export of foreign exchange, increase interest rates, raise protectionist barriers, and crush opposition. Foreign investors responded by rewarding the reimposition of political authority rather than penalizing the intensification of repression” (Beinert 2001: 173). Evidently, as long as rates of profit were among the highest in the world, foreign capital had no qualms in placing its bets on apartheid.

  35. Lundahl (1992: 303).

  36. Thomas and Martin (1992: 172–175).

  37. Jones and Muller (1992: 296). For the comparative worsening of the South African performance, see Table 1.

  38. Deegan (2001: 44).

  39. Lundahl (1992: 293–4); Marais (2001: 32); Schneider (2000: 419).

  40. Lowenberg (1997: 64); Kaplinksy (1995: 189); Gelb (1991: 17); Schrire (1982: 132).

  41. Cf Gelb (1991: 20–1) and Marais (2001: 109). Gelb incorrectly contends that the collapse of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates in March 1973 was a cause of the South African economic crisis because it destabilized the price of gold. In reality, up to 1981 the de-stabilization resulted in a major increase in the price of gold, which lessened the impact of the crisis.

  42. Marais (2001: 45, 101)

  43. Lowenberg (1997: 67); Marais (2001: 101).

  44. Beinert (2001: 314–5); Black (1991: 171); Marais (2001: 103).

  45. Rogerson (1991: 355); Jones and Muller (1992: 302).

  46. Marais (2001: 109); Padayachee (1995: 169); Jones and Muller (1992: 299).

  47. Silver (2003: 54–64).

  48. Drucker (1968).

  49. Castells and Portes (1989: 29–30). See also Piore and Sabel (1984).

  50. Harrison (1994:8–12).

  51. Arrighi et al. (2003).

  52. Terreblanche (2002: 27).

  53. Carmody (2002: 258).

  54. Marais (2001: 136).

  55. Marais (2001: 115, 117, 136).

  56. Marais (2001: 112); Carmody (2002: 267).

  57. “By encouraging offshore investments, government hoped to create ‘space’ in the economy for foreign investors (and it must be added, black economic empowerment consortia), since firms shifting abroad are pressured into selling off non-core local operations in order to raise investment capital. Foreign investors took the opportunity (evident in the large share of FDI acquisitions), but without robust local demand to trigger further, new investments, the rush soon waned” (Marais 2001: 111, 174).

  58. Marais (2001: 117).

  59. Carmody (2002: 267) and Marais (2001: 113) citing a study of FDI flows to 54 developing countries by Schneider and Frey (1985: 167–75).

  60. Beinert (2001: 317).

  61. The low levels of formal education of many Africans, for example, made them ineligible for employment in the tertiary sector, which was one of the few sectors that did expand. As a result, in 2001 about 50% of African entrants to the job market could not find jobs in the formal economy. Terreblanche (2002: 13–14).

  62. Terreblanche (2002: 30, 427, 433); Carmody (2002: 269).

  63. For a detailed development of the East Asian side of the argument made here see Arrighi 2007 and Arrighi and Zhang 2010; also Arrighi 2002: 24–31.

References

  • Alexander P, Chan A. Does China have an apartheid pass system? J Ethnic Migr Stud. 2004;30(4):609–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amin S. Unequal development. An essay on the social formations of peripheral capitalism. New York: Monthly Review; 1976.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrighi G. The political economy of Rhodesia. The Hague: Mouton; 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrighi G. Labor supplies in historical perspective: a study of the proletarianization of the African peasantry in Rhodesia. J Dev Stud. 1970;6(3):197–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrighi G. The African crisis: world systemic and regional aspects. New Left Rev. 2002;II/15:5–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrighi G. The social and political economy of global turbulence. New Left Rev. 2003;II/20:5–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrighi G. Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the twentyfirst century. New York: Verso Books; 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrighi G, Zhang L. Beyond the Washington consensus: A new Bandung? Forthcoming in Globalization and Beyond: New Examinations of Global Power and Its Alternatives. Shefner J, Fernandez Kelly P (eds), Penn State University Press; 2010.

  • Arrighi G, Silver BJ, Brewer BD. Industrial convergence and the persistence of the North-South divide. Stud Comp Int Dev. 2003;38(1):3–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barber WJ. The economy of British Central Africa. 9. Stanford: Stanford University Press; 1961.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beinert W. Twentieth century South Africa. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black A. Manufacturing development and the economic crisis: A reversion to primary production? In: Gelb S, editor. South Africa’s economic crisis. London: Zed Books; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bond P, Desai A. Explaining uneven and combined development in South Africa. In: Dunn B, Radice H, editors. 100 years of permanent revolution: Results and prospects. London: Pluto; 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burawoy M. The functions and reproduction of migrant labor: comparative material from Southern Africa and the United States. Am J Sociol 1976;81(5).

  • Carmody P. Between globalization and (Post) apartheid: the political economy of restructuring in South Africa. J South Afr Stud. 2002;28(2).

  • Castells M, Portes A. World underneath: The origins, dynamics, and effects of the informal economy. In: Portes A, Castells M, Benton LA, editors. The informal economy. Studies in advanced and less developed countries. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press; 1989. p. 11–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan A. A ‘race to the bottom’. Globalisation and China’s labour standards. China Perspect. 2003;46:42–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deegan H. The politics of the New South Africa: Apartheid and After. Harlow: Pearson Education; 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drucker P. The age of discontinuity. New York: Harper & Row; 1968.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freeman R. What really ails Europe (and America): The doubling of the global workforce. www.theglobalist.com June 3; 2005.

  • Gelb S. South Africa’s economic crisis: an overview. In: Gelb S, editor. South Africa’s economic crisis. London: Zed Books; 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrison B. Lean and mean: the changing landscape of corporate power in the age of flexibility. New York: Basic Books; 1994.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart G. Disabling globalization: Places of power in post-apartheid South Africa. Berkeley: University of California Press; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey D. The new imperialism. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch A. Season of hope. Scottsville: University of KwaZulu-Natal Press; 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones S, Muller A. The South African economy, 1910–90. London: MacMillan; 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplinksy R. Capital intensity in South African manufacturing and unemployment, 1972–90. World Dev. 1995;23(2):179–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Legassick M. South Africa: Forced labor, industrialization, and racial differentiation. In: Harris R, editor. The political economy of Africa. New York: Wiley; 1975.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowenberg AD. Why South Africa’s apartheid economy failed. Contemp Econ Policy. 1997;15:62–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundahl, M. (Ed.), Fredriksson, P., & Moritz, L. (1992). South Africa 1990: Pressure for Change. Apartheid in Theory and Practice: An Economic Analysis. Boulder: Westview Press.

  • Marais H. South Africa: Limits to change: The political economy of transition. London: Zed Books; 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  • McMichael P. Development and social change: A global perspective. Thousand Oaks: Pine Forge; 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • Padayachee V. Foreign capital and economic development in South Africa: recent trends and postapartheid prospects. World Dev. 1995;23(2):163–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piore MJ, Sabel CF. The second industrial divide: Possibilities for prosperity. New York: Basic Books; 1984.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson CM. Beyond racial fordism: Restructuring industry in the ‘New’ South Africa. Tijdschr Econ En Soc Geografie. 1991;82(5):355–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider GE. The development of the manufacturing sector in South Africa. J Econ Issues. 2000;34(2):413–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider F, Frey B. Economic and political determinants of foreign direct investment. World Dev. 1985;13(2):161–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schrire R, editor. The Homelands: Political perspectives. South Africa: Public policy perspectives. Capetown: Juta and Company; 1982.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seidman G. Is South Africa Different? Sociological comparisons and theoretical contributions from the land of Apartheid. Annu Rev Sociol. 1999;25:419–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silver B. Forces of labor: Workers’ movements and globalization since 1870. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2003.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Terreblanche S. A History of inequality in South Africa. Pietermaritzburg: University of Natal Press; 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  • Terreblanche S, Nattrass N. A periodization of the political economy from 1910. In: Nattrass N, Ardington E, editors. The political economy of South Africa. Cape Town: Oxford University Press; 1990.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas D, Martin WG. South Africa’s economic trajectory: South Africa crisis or world-economic crisis? In: Vieira S, Martin WG, Wallerstein I, editors. How fast the wind? Southern Africa, 1975–200. Trenton: African World; 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitehouse D. Chinese workers and peasants in three phases of accumulation. Available at http://www.ukzn.ac.za/ccs/files/Whitehouse%20China.pdf, Paper delivered at the Colloquium on Economy, Society and Nature, sponsored by the Centre for Civil Society at the University of KwaZulu-Natal, 2 March 2006. Accessed March 2010.

  • Wolpe H. Capitalism and cheap labour-power in South Africa: from segregation to Apartheid. Econ Soc. 1972;1(4):425–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. 2001, 2006. World Development Indicators (CD ROM). Washington, D.C.: World Bank Publications.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ben Scully.

Additional information

Previous versions of this paper were presented at the Institute of Social and Economic Research, Rhodes University, Grahamstown, South Africa, May 3, 2007; the Department of Sociology, University of California, Berkeley, February 28, 2008; and the Seminar on International Development, Department of Sociology, The Johns Hopkins University, March 2009. The authors would like to thank the participants at the seminars in which the paper was presented for their useful comments which inspired substantive revisions. We would also like to thank Peter Evans, Martin Legassick, Greg Ruiters, Sampie Terreblanche and Edward Webster for their helpful comments on a previous version of the paper. Special thanks are due to Beverly J. Silver, who provided extensive suggestions on multiple versions of the paper.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Arrighi, G., Aschoff, N. & Scully, B. Accumulation by Dispossession and Its Limits: The Southern Africa Paradigm Revisited. St Comp Int Dev 45, 410–438 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-010-9075-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-010-9075-7

Keywords

Navigation