Skip to main content
Log in

Entrepreneurial Planning in a Regulated Environment: the U.S. Federal Maritime Commission and the Maritime Industry

  • Published:
The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics

Abstract

Entrepreneurs exploit market opportunities and innovate to achieve or maintain strategic advantage over their competitors. In the absence of government regulation, entrepreneurs are free to focus on improving satisfaction of customer wants, for example, by enhancing current goods, supplying new goods, or supplying established goods at lower cost. In a regulated market, entrepreneurs focus on satisfying regulatory authorities, for example, to earn rate increases, subsidies, or tax benefits. Economists normally conceptualize regulation as restricting entrepreneurial choice over prices charged, including general prohibitions against price discrimination, or as imposing additional costs on business enterprises through mandating actions entrepreneurial planners would not otherwise have chosen, or prohibiting actions which would have been freely chosen. This paper examines the role of a specific regulatory agency, the Federal Maritime Commission, and its regulatory oversight of the maritime shipping sector. Business strategy and public policy implications will be developed, as well as implications for the growth and development of the shipping industry. The history and nature of government intervention in the maritime sector will be reviewed. The presence of a regulatory authority at least partly substitutes a kind of bureaucratic sovereignty over the consumer sovereignty of an unregulated market. Regulated firms compete for favors from the regulatory authority, and in a regulated environment strategic advantage is directed away from entrepreneurial planners to political entrepreneurs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Kirzner’s (1984a, b) initial explorations of market process drew heavily on Hayek’s (1937, 1945, 1978), and Mises’s (1936, 1949) critiques of the informational inadequacy of central planning. He later introduced the distinction between Knowledge Problems A and B (Kirzner 1990).

  2. Under the Foreign Shipping Practices Act of 1988 and Section 19 of Merchant Marine Act of 1920, the Commission is obligated to protect U.S. shipping trades from unfair foreign practices. One aspect of this responsibility is the need to remove nonmarket barriers from ocean transportation in foreign ports. These laws provide authority for countervailing action to impose penalties on foreign flag carriers who adversely affect U.S. carriers through nonmarket forces. Though this authority is used very little, it acts as a deterrent.

    The Commission has a longstanding and a very effective record of dealing with a host of foreign government practices in various trades. We have addressed restrictions against third-flag carriers in our trade with Ecuador, Venezuela and Colombia; laws preventing U.S. companies from establishing subsidiaries in the PRC; discrimination against non-Korean intermediaries by the Republic of Korea; restrictions on U.S. flag carriage of military cargo to Iceland; and general cargo reservation schemes in Argentina, Brazil, and Peru. (Speech, U.S. Federal Maritime Commission, 1997)

    More recently, the Commission has intervened to reverse adverse actions by Brazil, where a labor action prevented U.S. ships from being unloaded; and Japan where discriminatory terminal access fees were impeding U.S. ships from access to that market. In the case of Japan, the U.S. Coast Guard turned back Japanese ships until an agreement to provide equal access to U.S. and Japanese port facilities was finalized.

  3. The U.S. Federal Maritime Commission investigates allegations of price discrimination. Because discussion agreements may result in uniform price-setting, the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice could not prosecute participants for their part in a government authorized activity. The Antitrust Division could still prosecute firms for charging anticompetitive prices. The Commission plays no role in regulating prices beyond enforcing the prohibition against price discrimination and enforcing the requirement that tariff increases be published with 30 days advance notice. The prohibition against price discrimination prevents collusive oligopolists from extracting all consumer surplus through acting as a perfectly discriminating monopolist. Some scope for price discrimination remains in that service contracts are exempt from the prohibition. Prior to 1984, the Commission did review and sometimes comment on proposed tariff increases.

  4. Controlled carriers, that is, foreign-government-owned carriers, are subject to a 30 day advance notice requirement for both price increases and decreases. The Federal Maritime Commission reviews controlled carrier rates for reasonableness, unlike with privately-owned firms. APL, formerly American President Lines and now a Singaporean controlled carrier, recently received an exemption to this requirement because it had no service contracts which would have avoided the regulation.

References

  • Afriat, S. 1967. “The Construction of a Utility Function from Expenditure Data.” International Economic Review 8: 67–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, William L., and Ronald L. Ross. 2005. “The Methodology of Profit Maximization: an Austrian Alternative.” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 8(4): 31–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, P.W.S. 1964. On Competition in Economic Theory. New York: St. Martins Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, Kalman J., and Richard M. Cyert. 1965. Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cournot, Augustin. 1897. Researches into the Mathematical Principles of the Theory of Wealth. Trans. Nathaniel T. Bacon. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diewert, E. 1973. “Afriat and Revealed Preference Theory.” Review of Economic Studies 40: 419–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Efroymson, Clarence W. 1943. “A Note on Kinked Demand Curves.” American Economic Review 33(1): 98–109. Reprinted 1950 in Ed. R.V. Clemence. Readings in Economic Analysis 2: 218–29. Cambridge, Mass.: Addison-Wesley.

  • Fellner, William. 1949. Competition Among the Few. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, J.W. 1977. Oligopoly and the Theory of Games. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harper, David A. 1996. Entrepreneurship and the Market Process: An Enquiry into the Growth of Knowledge. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • ______. 1998. “Institutional conditions for entrepreneurship.” Advances in Austrian Economics 5: 241–75. London & Stamford, Conn.: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ______. 2003. Foundations of Entrepreneurship and Economic Development. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, Friedrich A. 1937. “The meaning of competition.” Economica 4: Reprinted 1949 in Individualism and Economic Order. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

  • ______. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society.” American Economic Review 35(4): 519–30. Reprinted 1980 in F.A. Hayek, Individualism and Economic Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • ______. 1978. New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics, and the History of Ideas. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. [1939] 1946. Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ______. 1956. A Revision of Demand Theory. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoppe, Hans-Hermann. 1999. “Murray Rothbard: Economics, Science, and Liberty.” In 15 Great Austrian Economists. Ed. Randall Holcombe. Pp. 223–44. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Houthakker, H.S. 1950. “Revealed Preference and the Utility Function.” Econometrica 17: 159–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ikeda, Sanford. 1997. Dynamics of the Mixed Economy: Toward a Theory of Interventionism. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, Israel M. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ______. 1984a. “Prices, the communication of knowledge, and the discovery process.” In The Political Economy of Freedom: Essays in Honor of F.A. Hayek. Ed. Kurt Leube and Albert Zlabinger. Amsterdam: Philosophia Verlag. Reprinted 1992 in Kirzner, The Meaning of Market Process. London: Routledge. Pp. 139–51.

  • ______. 1984b. “Economic planning and the knowledge problem.” Cato Journal 4(2). Reprinted 1992 in Kirzner, The Meaning of Market Process. London: Routledge. Pp. 152–62.

  • ______. 1990. “Knowledge problems and their solutions: some relevant distinctions.” Cultural Dynamics. Reprinted 1992 in Kirzner, The Meaning of Market Process. London: Routledge. Pp. 161–79.

  • Menger, Carl (1871 [1976]) Principles of Economics. English translation of Grundsätze der Volksvirtschaftslehre. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, Ludwig von. [1936] 1981. Socialism. New ed. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics.

  • ______. [1949] 1998. Human Action, 5th ed. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Niskanen, William A., Jr. 1971. Bureaucracy and Representative Government. New York: Aldine/Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, Richard A. 1971. “Taxation by Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics 2: 22–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ______. 1975. “The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation.” Journal of Political Economy 83(4): 807–27. Reprinted 1988 in George A. Stigler, Chicago Studies in Political Economy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • ______. 1976. Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, Murray N. [1962] 1993. Man, Economy, and State. 2nd ed. Auburn, Ala.: Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • ______. 1977. Power and Market: Government and the Economy. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews & McMeel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, Paul A. 1948. “Consumption Theory in Terms of Revealed Preference.” Economica 15: 243–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ______. 1950. “The Problem of Integrability in Utility Theory.” Economica 17: 355–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, Joseph A. [1912] 1934. The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge, MA.: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trans-Atlantic Conference Agreement (TACA). 2006. Official website. http://www.tacaconf.com/ (19 February).

  • United States Code. 2006. (Section 6(g) of the Act, 46 App. U.S.C. 1705). Viewable at http://www.gpoaccess.gov/uscode/index.html (14 March).

  • U.S. Federal Maritime Commission. 1997 Speech. http://www.fmc.gov/speeches/newsrelease.asp?SPEECH_ID=20 (6 November).

  • U.S. Federal Maritime Commission. 2005a. Official website. http://www.fmc.gov/ (5 December).

  • U.S. Federal Maritime Commission. 2005b. Correspondence with Commission senior staff (17 August).

  • Wold, H. 1943. A Synthesis of Pure Demand Analysis. I–III. Skandinavisk Aktuarietidskrift 26, 27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yokoyama, T. 1953. A Logical Foundation of the Theory of Consumer’s Demand. Osaka Economic Papers 2: 71–79. Reprinted 1968 in Ed. P. Newman. Readings in Mathematical Economics 1. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert F. Mulligan.

Additional information

The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the United States Merchant Marine Academy, the Maritime Administration, the Department of Transportation, the U.S. Federal Maritime Commission, or any other U.S. Government agency. Thanks are due to William L. Anderson and an anonymous referee for helpful and constructive comments. The authors remain responsible for any shortcomings.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mulligan, R.F., Lombardo, G.A. Entrepreneurial Planning in a Regulated Environment: the U.S. Federal Maritime Commission and the Maritime Industry. Quart J Austrian Econ 11, 106–118 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12113-008-9036-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12113-008-9036-4

Keywords

Navigation