Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Financial appraisal of efficiency investments: why the good may be the worst enemy of the best

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Energy Efficiency Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This methodological paper has a didactic goal: improving our understanding of what “cost optimal energy performance of buildings” means and how financial appraisal of efficiency investments must be set up. Three items merit improvement. First, focus on the endowment character of energy performance of long-living assets like buildings. Second, defining cost optimal requires more than a comparative static trade-off scheme; cost optimal refers to dynamic efficiency, which results from technology dynamics induced by changes in society and policy. Third, financial appraisal is a more complex issue than simple net present value and life cycle cost calculations. It must reflect the time sequential dynamics of real-life processes including real-life decision making. Financial appraisal is embedded in a complex framework made up by three dimensions: future time, doubt and irrevocability. The latter dimension connects with issues like lock-in and path dependency that are generally overlooked in net present value calculations. This may lead to very erroneous recommendations regarding efficiency investments, in particular regarding the energy performance endowment of buildings. Mostly irrevocability is used as an argument to “wait and learn” what has, for example, blocked the pace of climate policy. But the opposite “choose or lose” is the logical outcome when the methodology is fed with evidenced expectations. The latter boosts energy efficiency to its boundaries, saving it from the middle-of-the-river quagmire where incomplete appraisals are dropping it too often (making the good the worst enemy of the best).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Functional use refers on the one hand to the main function intended for the building (e.g. living, education, office work, health care), but on the other hand to the use intensity of provided capabilities of the building (e.g. number of actual occupants with time and duration of their occupation of the building, number of hot meals prepared in the building’s kitchen, laundry—washing, drying, ironing—at home or processed externally, etc.). Regulations are or can be specific for intended functions, but cannot cover actual functional use (Verbruggen 2008).

  2. Events are out of control of given decision makers, while decisions (also called strategies) are created by decision makers or selected from a range of alternatives under control.

  3. It may be understood that the standard option theory as described in the “wait and learn” case and in Dixit and Pindyck (1994) also can be applied to find the optimum date for starting the construction as such, a timing also influenced by EPE choice opportunities. However, many other (for people more important) considerations will fix the date of constructing, and therefore, analytical separation of the two decisions is plausible.

Abbreviations

CBA:

Cost–benefit analysis

EPBD:

Energy Performance of Buildings Directive (2010/31/EU)

EPE:

Energy performance endowment

NPV:

Net present value

References

  • Arrow, K. J., & Fisher, A. C. (1974). Environmental preservation, uncertainty, and irreversibility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88, 312–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bierman, H., & Smidt, S. (1971). The capital budgeting decision. New York: The Macmillan Cy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bierman, H., Bonini, C. P., & Hausman, W. H. (1977). Quantitative analysis for business decisions. Richard D. Irwin.

  • BPIE. (2010). Cost optimality. Discussing methodology and challenges within the recast Energy Performance of Buildings Directive. The Buildings Performance Institute Europe, Brussels. http://dl.dropbox.com/u/4399528/BPIE/BPIE_costoptimality_publication2010.pdf. Accessed 8 March 2012.

  • Dixit, A. K., & Pindyck, R. S. (1994). Investment under uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ECEEE (2009). Net zero energy buildings: Definitions, issues and experience. European Council for an Energy Efficient Economy, Stockholm. http://www.eceee.org/buildings/Steering-2-zerobldgs.pdf. Accessed 8 March 2012.

  • EU (2010). Directive 2010/31/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 19 May 2010 on the energy performance of buildings. Official Journal of the European Union 18.6.2010L153/13-35.

  • Fisher, A. C. (2001). Uncertainty, irreversibility, and the timing of climate policy. Conference on the “Timing of Climate Change Policies”, Pew Center on Global Climate Change.

  • Grubb, M. (1997). Technologies, energy systems and the timing of CO2 emissions abatement. Energy Policy, 25(2), 159–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IPCC. (2007). Climate change 2007. Fourth assessment report. Working Group III Report “Mitigation of Climate Change”. Cambridge University Press. http://www.ipcc.ch/publications_and_data/publications_ipcc_fourth_assessment_report_wg3_report_mitigation_of_climate_change.htm. Accessed 8 March 2012.

  • Jelen, F. C., & Black, J. H. (1983). Cost and optimization engineering. New York: McGraw-Hill Book Cy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kolstad, C. D. (1996). Fundamental irreversibilities in stock externalities. Journal of Public Economics, 60, 221–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laustsen, J. (2008). Energy efficiency requirements in building codes, energy efficiency policies for new buildings. IEA Information Paper. Paris: International Energy Agency.

    Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R. (Ed.). (1972). Cost–benefit analysis. London: Penguin Modern Economics Readings. Penguin Books Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lind, R. C. (1999). Analysis for intergenerational decision-making. In P. R. Portney & J. P. Weyant (Eds.), Discounting and intergenerational equity (pp. 173–180). Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manne, A. S., & Richels, R. G. (1991). Buying greenhouse insurance. Energy Policy July/August, 53–62.

  • Matheson, J. E., & Howard, R. A. (1968). An introduction to decision analysis. Stanford Research Institute.

  • Munasinghe, M., Meier, P., Hoel, M., Hong, S. W., & Aaheim, A. (1995). Applicability of techniques of cost–benefit analysis to climate change. In IPCC “Climate Change 1995. Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change”, pp. 145–177.

  • Portney, P. R., & Weyant, J. P. (Eds.). (1999). Discounting and intergenerational equity. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raiffa, H. (1970). Decision analysis. Introductory lectures on choices under uncertainty. Reading: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rushing, A., & Lippiatt, B. (2008). Energy price indices and discount factors for life-cycle cost analysis. National Institute of Standards and Technology, U.S. Department of Commerce.

  • Sartori, I., & Hestnes, A. G. (2007). Energy use in the life cycle of conventional and low-energy buildings: A review article. Energy and Buildings, 39, 249–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stirling, A. (1999). On science and precaution in the management of technological risk. SPRU, University of Sussex.

  • Taleb, N. N. (2010). The Black Swan: The impact of the highly improbable. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verbruggen, A. (2008). Reftrofit of a century old land-house to a low-energy house. International Journal of Environmental Technology and Management, 9(4), 402–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verbruggen, A., Al Marchohi, M., & Janssens, B. (2011). The anatomy of investing in energy efficient buildings. Energy and Buildings, 43, 905–914.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Webster, M. (2002). The curious role of “learning” in climate policy: Should we wait for more data? The Energy Journal, 23(2), 97–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

Improvements suggested by an anonymous reviewer are incorporated in the present version. All shortcomings remain the responsibility of the author.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aviel Verbruggen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Verbruggen, A. Financial appraisal of efficiency investments: why the good may be the worst enemy of the best. Energy Efficiency 5, 571–582 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12053-012-9149-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12053-012-9149-7

Keywords

Navigation