Skip to main content
Log in

The impact of taxation on international assignment decisions: a principal–agent approach

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of Managerial Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In many industries like consulting or construction, highly qualified employees, i.e., experts or executive managers, have to be assigned to temporary projects. Obviously, the employees’ productivities in the respective projects are crucial for the employer’s optimal assignment decision, but assignment can also be affected by risk-incentive trade-offs. Moreover, taxation can alter the assignment decision, especially if employees are sent abroad as expatriates so that international tax law has to be taken into account. To address these issues simultaneously, we combine a human resource assignment problem with a principal–agent problem of the LEN type. Both wage taxation at the agents’ level and corporate taxation at the principal’s level are integrated. We show that national tax rules, the methods for avoiding double taxation, and the agents’ tax characteristics are important determinants of international assignment decisions. The effects of tax rate variations can be ambiguous and depend on whether the exemption method or the credit method are applied, in particular if agents make differing choices of residence. From a tax policy perspective, the exemption method should be preferred as the tax effects are more transparent and intuitive than under the credit method.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This research gap is rather surprising given current levels of individual and corporate income taxes in OECD countries and the resulting potential tax rate differentials. In the OECD countries, top statutory personal income tax rates were between 15.0 and 60.2 % with an average of 42.5 % in 2012 and corporate tax rates between 12.5 and 39.1 % with an average of 25.5 % in 2013; see OECD (2013a, b).

  2. See, e.g., Voßmerbäumer (2013) and the references cited therein.

  3. See, e.g., Niemann (2008) or Ewert and Niemann (2014).

  4. See Burkhard et al. (2012) for a textbook introduction into assignment problems and Pentico (2007) for a research survey.

  5. See, e.g., Reiche and Harzing (2011). Suutari and Tornikoski (2001), however, report that low taxes are a crucial determinant of expatriates’ satisfaction with their compensation.

  6. See Niemann (2008), Niemann (2011), or Voßmerbäumer (2013) for a discussion of gross and net performance measures.

  7. To see this denote actual effort costs \(\tilde{e}_{ij}/\alpha _{ij}\) and the actual productivity parameter \(\tilde{\pi }_{ij}\). Rescale the unit in which effort is measured according to \(e_{ij} = \sqrt{2/\alpha _{ij}} \tilde{e}_{ij}\), and hence effort costs amount to \(\tilde{e}_{ij}^2/\alpha _i = e_{ij}^2/2\). The job’s return, \(\tilde{\pi }_{ij} \tilde{e}_{ij}\), then amounts to \(\tilde{\pi }_{ij} \sqrt{\alpha _{ij}/2} e_{ij}\). The required rescaling of the productivity parameter is therefore \(\pi _{ij} = \sqrt{\alpha _{ij}/2} \tilde{\pi }_{ij}\).

    But, to simplify the analysis and the exposition, the model does not include tax-deductible effort costs nor fixed profits or fixed agent costs.

  8. See Article 15 No. 2 of the OECD model tax convention. The assumption of a long-term assignment is typically met for expatriates. Moreover, in the construction industry long-term building sites are regularly considered as permanent establishments; cf. Article 5 No. 3 of the OECD model tax convention.

  9. We assume that a double taxation convention between the home country and the host country exists. Therefore, we neglect the case of unrelieved double taxation.

  10. In principle, the agent’s decision to move his center of vital interests could be modeled endogenously by productivity coefficients \(\pi _{ij}\) depending on this decision. However, to keep the model simple, we assume an exogenously given center of vital interests.

  11. See Article 15 of the OECD model tax convention. Throughout the paper we do not take the nationality principle into account. This principle means that taxpayers are taxed according to their citizenship. Except for the U.S., the nationality principle is rarely applied.

  12. See, e.g., Articles 23A, 23B of the OECD model tax convention. Jacobs et al. (2005) give an international overview of the taxation of expatriates.

  13. We neglect carrybacks or carryforwards of foreign tax credits and do not distinguish between a worldwide or a per-country limitation. See, e.g., Blouin (2012, pp. 10) for the US case.

  14. See Articles 15, 24 (2) of the double taxation convention between Austria and the UK and Articles 15, 23 (2) of the double taxation convention between Austria and Germany.

  15. See Articles 15, 23 (2) of the double taxation convention between Croatia and Austria and Articles 15, 23 (2) of the double taxation convention between Croatia and Germany.

  16. We neglect deduction limits like Section 162 (m) of the U.S. Internal Revenue Code. For the economic effect of deduction limits see, e.g., Halperin et al. (2001) and Göx (2008) for the U.S. case or Voßmerbäumer (2012) for the current discussion in Germany.

  17. See Burkhard et al. (2012, §§1.2, 4). In particular, the costs in the canonical LSAP formulation associated with the assignment of agent i to job j can be defined as \(-(1-\tau _j) P_{ij} + \max _{i,j} (1-\tau _j) P_{ij}\).

  18. For a discussion of reservation utilities before and after taxes see Niemann (2008, 2011), and Voßmerbäumer (2013).

  19. See, for example, Niemann (2008, 2011), Voßmerbäumer (2013), and the references cited there.

  20. Income from the home country as well as the exemption-with-progression method are neglected here.

  21. Dutta and Reichelstein (Dutta and Reichelstein 1999, p. 239), Dutta and Zhang (Dutta and Zhang 2002, p. 74), and Wagenhofer (Wagenhofer 2003, p. 293), among others, make the same assumption.

  22. See, e.g., Spremann (1987) in the pre-tax case and Niemann (2008) or Ewert and Niemann (2014) in the after-tax case.

References

  • Blouin J (2012) Taxation of multinational corporations. Found Trends Acc 6:1–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burkhard R, Dell’Amica M, Martello S (2012) Assignment problems, 2nd edn. Society for Industrial and Applied Mathematics, Philadelphia

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dam K, Perez-Castrillo D (2006) The principal–agent matching market. Front Theor Econ 2:1–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta S, Reichelstein S (1999) Asset valuation and performance measurement in a dynamic agency setting. Rev Acc Stud 4:235–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutta S, Zhang XJ (2002) Revenue recognition in a multiperiod agency setting. J Acc Res 40:67–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2011) Proposal for a council directive on a common consolidated corporate tax base (CCCTB). COM(2011) 121

  • Ewert R, Niemann R (2014) A theory of tax avoidance – managerial incentives for tax planning in a multi-task principal-agent model. CESifo Working Paper No. 4851

  • Fellingham JC, Wolfson MA (1985) Taxes and risk sharing. Acc Rev 40:10–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Göx RF (2008) Tax incentives for inefficient executive pay and reward for luck. Rev Acc Stud 13:452–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halperin RM, Kwon YK, Rhodes-Catanach SC (2001) The impact of deductibility limits on compensation contracts: a theoretical examination. J Am Tax Assoc 23(Supplement):52–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hemmer T (2004) Lessons lost in linearity: a critical assessment of the general usefulness of LEN models in compensation research. J Manag Acc Res 16:149–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmström B, Milgrom P (1987) Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica 55:303–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs OH, Spengel C, Endres D, Elschner C, Höfer R, Schmidt O (2005) International taxation of expatriates—survey of 20 tax and social security regimes and analysis of effective tax burdens on international assignments. Fachverlag Moderne Wirtschaft, Frankfurt

    Google Scholar 

  • Martini JT, Niemann R (2013) The impact of taxation on international assignment decisions: a principal–agent approach, CESifo Working Paper No. 4323

  • Martini JT, Niemann R, Simons D (2014) Management incentives under formula apportionment – tax-induced distortions of effort and compensation in a principal-agent setting. arqus Working Paper No. 168

  • Niemann R (2008) The effects of differential taxation on managerial effort and risk taking. Finanz Arch Public Financ Anal 64:273–310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niemann R (2011) Asymmetric taxation and performance-based incentive contracts. CESifo Working Paper No. 3363

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (2013a) OECD tax database, top marginal combined personal income tax rates on gross wage for a single individual. http://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/Table%20I.7_Mar_2013.xlsx

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (2013b) OECD tax database—basic (non-targeted) corporate income tax rates. http://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/Table%20II.1_May%202013.xlsx

  • Pentico DW (2007) Assignment problems: a golden anniversary survey. Eur J Oper Res 176:774–793

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reiche S, Harzing AW (2011) International assignments. In: Harzing AW, Pinnington AH (eds) International human resource management, 3rd edn. Sage, Los Angeles, pp 185–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapley LS, Shubik M (1971) The assignment game I: the core. Int J Game Theory 1:111–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spremann K (1987) Agent and principal. In: Bamberg G, Spremann K (eds) Agency theory, information, and incentives. Springer, Berlin, pp 3–37

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Suutari V, Tornikoski C (2001) The challenge of expatriate compensation: the sources of satisfaction and dissatisfaction among expatriates. Int J Hum Resour Manag 12:389–404

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voßmerbäumer J (2012) Effizienzwirkungen einer Regulierung von Managergehältern durch das Steuerrecht. arqus Working Paper No. 125

  • Voßmerbäumer J (2013) Incentive effects and the income tax treatment of employer-provided workplace benefits. Rev Manag Sci 7:61–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagenhofer A (2003) Accrual-based compensation, depreciation, and investment decisions. Eur Acc Rev 12:287–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolfson MA (1985) Tax, incentive, and risk-sharing issues in the allocation of property rights: the generalized lease-or-buy problem. J Bus 58:159–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jan Thomas Martini.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 6   (1) “If” part: Evaluating (9) for \(\tau _1=\tau _2\) and \(t_{11}=t_{12}=t_{21}=t_{22}=0\) yields (22).

(2) “Only if” part: By definition, tax neutrality implies the equivalence of optimality conditions (9) and (22) for all \(\pi _{ij}\) and \(\underline{u}_{i1}=\underline{u}_{i2}\). With \(\underline{u}_{i} \equiv \underline{u}_{i1}=\underline{u}_{i2}\), the optimality conditions (9) and (22) are equivalent only if

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\tau _1) \left( \frac{2\underline{u}_1}{1-t_{11}} - \frac{2\underline{u}_2}{1-t_{21}} \right) = (1-\tau _2) \left( \frac{2\underline{u}_1}{1-t_{12}} - \frac{2\underline{u}_2}{1-t_{22}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(35)

Rearranging and simplifying this condition yields

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \frac{1-\tau _1}{1-t_{11}} - \frac{1-\tau _2}{1-t_{12}} \right) \underline{u}_1 = \left( \frac{1-\tau _1}{1-t_{21}} - \frac{1-\tau _2}{1-t_{22}} \right) \underline{u}_2 , \end{aligned}$$
(36)

which holds for arbitrary reservation remunerations \(\underline{u}_i\) if and only if the terms in parentheses vanish. Thus, the conditions

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\tau _1) (1-t_{12})&= (1-\tau _2) (1-t_{11}) \end{aligned}$$
(37)

and

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\tau _1) (1-t_{22})&= (1-\tau _2) (1-t_{21}) \end{aligned}$$
(38)

hold.

Exploiting these conditions to simplify (9) results in

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\tau _1) \left[ (1-t_{11}) \pi _{11}^2 - (1-t_{21}) \pi _{21}^2 \right] \mathrel {\left\{ \gtreqqless \right\} } (1-\tau _2) \left[ (1-t_{12}) \pi _{12}^2 - (1-t_{22}) \pi _{22}^2 \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(39)

This optimality condition, in turn, is equivalent to (22) for arbitrary productivity parameters \(\pi _{ij}\) if and only if

$$\begin{aligned} t_{11}=t_{21}&, t_{12}=t_{22}, \end{aligned}$$
(40)

and

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\tau _1)(1-t_{11})&=(1-\tau _2)(1-t_{12}) . \end{aligned}$$
(41)

Conditions (37) and (41), in turn, imply \(\tau _1=\tau _2\) and \(t_{11}=t_{12}\), and hence we have shown that tax neutrality holds only if \(\tau _1=\tau _2\) and \(t_{11}=t_{12}=t_{21}=t_{22}\). As tax neutrality does not hold for \(\tau _1=\tau _2\) and \(t_{11}=t_{12}=t_{21}=t_{22}>0\), tax neutrality implies \(\tau _1=\tau _2\) and \(t_{11}=t_{12}=t_{21}=t_{22}=0\).\(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 1   After exploiting Assumption 2 to simplify condition (9), the proof follows the same lines as that of Proposition 6 and is therefore omitted. The crucial difference is that the equivalence of the simplified condition (9) and condition (22) also holds for \(\tau _1=\tau _2\) and \(t_{11}=t_{12}=t_{21}=t_{22}>0\). \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 2   After exploiting Assumption 3 to simplify condition (9), the proof follows the same lines as that of Proposition 6 and is therefore omitted. The crucial difference is that only conditions (40) and (41) remain. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Martini, J.T., Niemann, R. The impact of taxation on international assignment decisions: a principal–agent approach. Rev Manag Sci 9, 703–729 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11846-014-0134-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11846-014-0134-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation