Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Quantifying the relative importance of export industries in a small open economy during the great depression of the 1930s: an input–output approach

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper provides a quantification of the relative importance of export industries in a small open economy using new data provided by input–output tables describing the Finnish economy in 1928. The Finnish analysis of the Great Depression of the 1930s has been particularly focused on the importance of foreign trade. Despite the lack of quantified evidence, it is commonly accepted that the export industries had a major role in the economic development. The basic input–output framework is extended into a production–consumption model to produce a more elaborate model that provides a quantification of changes in final demand of some key industries in the economy. Results suggest that even though the role of export industries was dominant, domestic market industries and private consumption also had a significant role in the depression.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, von Tunzelmann (1982).

  2. See also Eichengreen (1992b); On the Great Depression in the United States, see for example Bordo et al. (1998).

  3. For further readings on cliometrics and studies under new economic history see, for example, Rawski et al. (1996); Field (1987); McCloskey (1978); Fogel (1975); Fogel (1966).

  4. The term “historical” input–output tables refers to tables describing the economy before the Second World War.

  5. The social-accounting matrix is basically an extension of the input–output framework, and incorporates the demand side in order to describe the circular flow of incomes from firms to households and back again.

  6. Detailed description of methods and sources used for compiling the input–output table are presented in Kauppila (2007).

  7. The growth study series is published in the Bank of Finland series and includes 13 studies on Finnish economic growth by industry. The latest series was compiled in Hjerppe (1996).

  8. The industrial classification used in the compilation process was based on the Industrial Classification comparable to the European NACE, Rev. 1 industry classification. The product classification used follows the European Union’s Classification of Products by Activity (CPA) classification. The industries and product groups were formed mainly at the 3-digit level.

  9. This approach is presented in Ten Raa (1995), while the calculation of the 95% confidence interval is partly based on Feinstein and Thomas (2001).

  10. See Appendix 1 for a detailed mathematical presentation of the method.

  11. The structure of methodological description is based mainly on Miller and Blair (1985). On applications of input–output analysis see also Chiasini (1988); Economic Systems Res 2 (2000). For mathematical presentation, see Appendix 2.

  12. The Great Depression is typically thought to have started in 1929 when industrial production in the United States began to fall. The Finnish case clearly demonstrates that this only worsened the already critical position of the country.

  13. Finland abandoned the gold standard in the autumn of 1931. Following the floatation of the currency, the Finnish markka was undervalued against its main trading partners, which helped to promote exports during the 1930s.

  14. For more on wages in construction in Helsinki, see also Hannikainen (2004).

  15. For detailed description of sources used for calculating entrepreneurial income, savings and direct taxes, see Kauppila (2007). Estimates of entrepreneurial incomes, savings and direct taxes are available from the author by request, together with related input coefficients and inverse matrices for the closed model.

  16. Using current prices will change results slightly. In the open model, total impact of wood products would have been a decrease of 3.7 % in total output, of paper products 2.6% increase in total output and of construction 4.3% decrease in total output. It will not change, however, the way impacts will be distributed.

  17. On basic methodology and its applications, see, for example, Knottnerus (2003, 21–22). Mikko Myrskylä from Statistics Finland has been of great help in formulating this approach.

  18. This holds true on the technical condition that P(|x i | < M) = 1 for every i.

  19. This can be done on the technical condition that the determinant of (– A) is non-zero; if it is zero the inverse does not hold.

References

  • Abildgren K, Nørskov A (1992) Var valutacentralens allokering af importen i 1934 beskæftigelsesmæssig optimal? Nationalokon Tidsskr 130:591–604

    Google Scholar 

  • Abildgren K, Nørskov A (1991) Konstuktion af en input–output tabel for 1934 samt illustration af dens anvendelsesmuligheder til analyse af dansk økonomisk historie. Statsvidenska-plig afhandling ved Københavns Universitets Økonomisk Institut

  • Bernstein M (1987) The great depression: delayed recovery and economic change in America, 1929–1939, New York

  • Bordo M, Goldin C, White E (eds) (1998) The defining moment. The great depression and the American economy in the twentieth century. National Bureau of Economic Research, Chicago

  • Capie F (1978) The British tariff and industrial protection in the 1930s. Econ Hist Rev New Ser 31(3):399–409

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiasini M (1988) Input–output analysis, current developments, New York

  • Economic Systems Res 2 (2000)

  • Eichengreen B (1992a) The golden fetters, the gold standard and the great depression 1919–1939, New York

  • Eichengreen B (1992b) The origins and nature of the great slump revisited. Econ Hist Rev N Ser 45(2):213–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eurostat (1996) European System of Accounts—ESA 1995, Eurostat

  • Feinstein C, Temin P, Toniolo G (1997) The European economy between the wars, Oxford

  • Feinstein C, Thomas M (2001) A plea for errors. Discussion papers in economic and social history, number 41, July 2001, University of Oxford

  • Field A (2006) Technological change and US productivity growth in the interwar years. J Econ Hist Camb Univ Press 66(01):203–236

    Google Scholar 

  • Field A (1987) The future of economic history, Boston

  • Fogel R (1975) The limits of quantitative methods in history. Am Hist Rev 80(2):329–350. doi:10.2307/1850498

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fogel R (1966) The new economic history. I. It’s findings and methods. Econ Hist Rev N Ser 19(3):642–656

    Google Scholar 

  • Grytten OH (2006) Why was the Great Depression not so Great in the Nordic Countries? Economic policy and unemployment. Department of Economics, Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration, Discussion Papers 24/06. Available via http://www.nhh.no/research-and-faculty/academic-organisation/economics/discussion-papers/2006.aspx. Accessed 30 September 2009

  • Halme V (1955) Vienti Suomen suhdannetekijänä vuosina 1870–1939. Suomen Pankin taloustieteellisen tutkimuslaitoksen julkaisuja, Sarja B:16, Helsinki

  • Hannikainen M (2004) Rakentajat suhdanteissa. Palkat, työttömyys ja työmarkkinakäytännöt Helsingin rakennustoiminnassa 1930-luvun laman aikana. Bidrag till kännedom av Finlands nature och folk 162, Vammala

  • Heikkinen S, Kuusterä A (2001) 1990s economic crisis. In: Kalela J, Kiander J, Kivikuru U, Loikkanen HA, Simpura J (ed) The research programme on the economic crises of the 1990s in Finland: Down from the heavens, up from the ashes. The Finnish economic crisis of the 1990s in the light of economic and social research, VATT—julkaisuja 27:6, Valtion taloudellinen tutkimuskeskus, Helsinki

  • Hjerppe R (2004) Den stora depressionen och Finland. Strukturernas dynamik. Kontinuitet och förändring i ekonomisk historia. In: Andersson-Skog L, Lindmark M (ed), Festskrift till Olle Krantz, occasional papers in economic history no. 8, Umeå Universitet

  • Hjerppe R (1996) Finland’s historical national accounts 1860–1994: calculation methods and statistical tables. Jyväskylän yliopisto, Suomen historian julkaisuja 24, Jyväskylä

  • Hjerppe R (1989) Finnish economy 1860–1985. Growth and Structural Change, Kasvututkimuksia XIII, Suomen Pankin julkaisuja, Helsinki

    Google Scholar 

  • Horrell S, Humphries J, Weale M (1994) An input-output table for 1841. Econ Hist Rev XLVII 3:545–566. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0289.1994.tb01390.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalela J (1987) Pulapolitiikka, Valtion talous- ja sosiaalipolitiikka Suomessa lamavuosina 1929–1933. Työväen taloudellinen tutkimuslaitos, Tutkimuksia 13, Helsinki

  • Kauppila J (2007) The Structure and Short-Term Development of Finnish Industries in the 1920s and 1930s: an input–output approach. Statistics Finland research reports 246, Helsinki

  • Kitson M, Solomou S, Weale M (1991) Effective protection and economic recovery in the United Kingdom during the 1930s. Econ Hist Rev XLIV 2:328–338

    Google Scholar 

  • Knottnerus P (2003) Sample survey theory. Some pythagorean perspectives, New York

  • Kohli M (2001) Leontief and the US Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1941–54. In: Developing a framework for measurement. In: Klein J, Morgan M (ed)The age of economic measurement, annual supplement to volume 33, History of Political Economy, Durham

  • Leontief W (1951) The structure of American economy, 1919–1939. An empirical application of equilibrium analysis. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison A (2003) Monitoring the World economy 1820–1992, Paris

  • McCloskey D (1978) The achievements of the Cliometric school. J Econ Hist 38(1). The tasks of economic history, pp 13–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller R, Blair P (1985) Input–output analysis: foundations and extensions, New Jersey

  • Rawski T, Carter S, Cohen J, Cullenberg S (1996) Economics and the historian, Berkeley

  • Siriwardana M (1995) The causes of the depression in Australia in the 1930s: a general equilibrium evaluation. Explor Econ Hist 32:51–81. doi:10.1006/exeh.1995.1003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suviranta B (1931a) Suomi ja maailman talouspula. Taloudellisen neuvottelukunnan julkaisuja 12, Helsinki

  • Suviranta B (1931b) Finland and the World depression, Helsinki

  • Ten Raa T (1995) Linear analysis of competitive economies, LSE handbooks in economics. Prentice Hall/Harvester Wheatsheaf

  • Thomas M (1987) General equilibrium models and research in economic history. In: Field AJ (ed) The future of economic history, Boston

  • Thomas M (1983) Rearmament and economic recovery in the late 1930s. Econ Hist Rev 36:552–579. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0289.1983.tb01248.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations (1999) Handbook of input–output table compilation and analysis. studies in methods, series F no. 74. Handbook of National Accounting, United Nations

  • von Tunzelmann N (1982) Structural change and leading sectors in British manufacturing. 1907–1968. In: Kindleberger C, di Tella G (ed) Economics in the long view, vol 3, London & Basingstoke

  • Waris K (1945) Kuluttajain tulot, kulutus ja säästäminen suhdannekehityksen valossa Suomessa vuosina 1926–1938, Helsinki

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jari Kauppila.

Additional information

During the time of writing, the author was affiliated with the Department of Social Science History at the University of Helsinki. The work has been supported by the Finnish Cultural Foundation, the Toivo Eklund Foundation and the Academy of Finland. The author would like to thank two anonymous referees for their very helpful comments.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Reliability analysis of data

Here we suggest that the 95% confidence interval for total output and GDP can be calculated by applying the Lindeberg-Feller variant of the central limit theorem,Footnote 17 according to which for independent variables, x i, x 2, …, x n , whose expectation and variance are E(x i ) = μ i and Var(x i ) = σ 2 i , respectively, the distribution of the standardised sum

$$ \frac{{\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n} {(x_{i} - \mu_{i} )} }}{S},{\text{ where }}S = \sqrt {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n} {\sigma_{i}^{2} } } , $$
(1)

is close to the standard normal distribution for large n.Footnote 18 When this normal approximation holds, the 95% confidence interval for the unknown \( \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{n} {\mu_{i} } , \) is

$$ \left( {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n} {x_{i} } - 1.96 \times S,\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n} {x_{i} + 1.96 \times S} } \right). $$
(2)

In the case of the supply and use tables constructed, n = 30 since the final use table of domestic products presents output at the level of 30 product groups. This is large enough to justify the normal approximation. What we need to estimate is \( \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{30} {\mu_{i} } , \) the total output, which is the sum of unknown product-group outputs. For each product group i, there are two observations forμ i : supply and use. It is assumed that errors in these observations are random and independent with zero means, but not necessarily normal.

The point estimate, x i in (1) for the true product-group output μ i is the mean of supply and use in the corresponding product group i. The point estimate for \( \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{30} {\mu_{i} } \) is the sum of the product-group means, that is, \( \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{30} {x_{i} } . \) From (2) it is possible to see that for the 95% confidence interval for\( \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{30} {\mu_{i} }, \) an estimate \( \hat{S} \) is needed for the unknown S. For this, variance estimates s 2 i are required for unknown variances σ 2 i . These are obtained by applying the standard formula using information on supply and use by product group.

$$ s_{i}^{2} = \frac{{\left( {x_{c} - \frac{{x_{c} + (z_{c} + y_{c} + e_{c} )^{2} }}{2}} \right) + \left( {(z_{c} + y_{c} + e{\kern 1pt}_{c} ) - \frac{{x_{c} + (z_{c} + y_{c} + e_{c} )^{2} }}{2}} \right)}}{2 - 1} $$
(3)

Now the 95% confidence interval for the unknown total output \( \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{30} {\mu_{i}} \) is obtained by plugging the calculated values \( \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{30} {x_{i} } \) and \(\hat {S}=\sqrt{s_{1}^{2}+s_{2}^{2}+\ldots+s_{30}^{2}}\) into (2).

Appendix 2: Basic input–output equations

The structure of description is based on Miller and Blair (1985).

2.1 Static open input–output model

Mathematically, the basic input-output assumptions are as follows. Denote the observed monetary flows from industry i to industry j by z ij . Thus, if the economy is divided into n industries, and if the total output of industry i is denoted by X i and the total final demand for industry i’s output by Y i , the equation can be written as

$$ X_{i} = z_{i1} + z_{i2} + \ldots + z_{ii} + \ldots + z_{in} + Y_{i} . $$
(1)

The above equation thus describes the distribution of industry i’s output. It is the sum of all of its inter-industry sales as well as of sales to final demand. Each industry has a similar equation, reflecting the sales of its output. Thus,

$$ \begin{array}{l} \begin{aligned} {X_{1} = z_{11} + z_{12} + \ldots + z_{1i} + \ldots + z_{1n} + Y_{1} } \end{aligned} \hfill \\ \begin{aligned} {X_{2} = z_{21} + z_{22} + \ldots + z_{2i} + \ldots + z_{2n} + Y_{2} } \end{aligned} \hfill \\ \vdots \begin{aligned} \hfill \\ X_{i} = z_{i1} + z_{i2} + \ldots + z_{ii} + \ldots + z_{in} + Y_{i} \hfill \\ \end{aligned} \hfill \\ \vdots \begin{aligned} \hfill \\ X_{n} = z_{n1} + z_{n2} + \ldots + z_{ni} + \ldots + z_{nn} + Y_{n} \hfill \\ \end{aligned} \hfill \\ \end{array}. $$
(2)

The input–output theory assumes that for one unit of every industry’s output a fixed amount of input of each kind is required. Thus, the inter-industry flows from industry i to industry j depend entirely on the total output of industry j for that same period of time. These fixed input relationships between industries are obtained by dividing the entries in the column by the total output of the consuming industry. In its mathematical form, the computation of the input coefficient matrix is thus

$$ a_{ij} = \frac{{z_{ij} }}{{X_{j} }}, $$
(3)

where z ij stands for the flow of input from industry i to industry j, and X j is the total output of industry j. The corresponding output coefficients (b ij ) describe the proportion of industry i’s total output sold to industry j. In its mathematical form

$$ b_{ij} = \frac{{z_{ij} }}{{X_{i} }}. $$
(4)

Now Eq. 2 can be rewritten as

$$ \begin{array}{l} \begin{aligned} {X_{1} = a_{11} X_{1} + a_{12} X_{2} + \ldots + a_{1i} X_{i} + \ldots + a_{1n} X_{n} + Y_{1} } \end{aligned} \\ \begin{aligned} {X_{2} = a_{21} X_{1} + a_{22} X_{2} + \ldots + a_{2i} X_{i} + \ldots + a_{2n} X_{n} + Y_{2} } \end{aligned} \\ \vdots \begin{aligned} \\ X_{i} = a_{i1} X_{1} + a_{i2} X_{2} + \ldots + a_{ii} X_{i} + \ldots + a_{in} X_{n} + Y_{i} \\ \end{aligned} \\ \vdots \begin{aligned} \\ X_{n} = a_{n1} X_{1} + a_{n2} X_{2} + \ldots + a_{ni} X_{i} + \ldots + a_{nn} X_{n} + Y_{n} \\ \end{aligned} \\ \end{array} . $$
(5)

Equation (5) can be solved in terms of X by moving all the X terms to the left-hand side. Thus,

$$ \begin{array}{l} \begin{aligned} {X_{1} - a_{11} X_{1} - a_{12} X_{2} - \ldots - a_{1i} X_{i} - \ldots - a_{1n} X_{n} = Y_{1} } \end{aligned} \\ \begin{aligned} {X_{2} - a_{21} X_{1} - a_{22} X_{2} - \ldots - a_{2i} X_{i} - \ldots - a_{2n} X_{n} = Y_{2} } \end{aligned} \\ \vdots \begin{aligned} \\ X_{i} - a_{i1} X_{1} - a_{i2} X_{2} - \ldots - a_{ii} X_{i} - \ldots - a_{in} X_{n} = Y_{i} \\ \end{aligned} \\ \vdots \begin{aligned} \\ X_{n} - a_{n1} X_{1} - a_{n2} X_{2} - \ldots - a_{ni} X_{i} - \ldots - a_{nn} X_{n} = Y_{n} \\ \end{aligned} \\ \end{array} . $$
(6)

For reasons of simplicity, the above equations are often presented in matrix form. Thus,

$$ A = \left[ {\begin{array}{llllllll} {a_{11} } & {a_{12} } & \cdots & {a_{1i} } & \cdots & {a_{1n} } \\ {a_{21} } & {a_{22} } & \cdots & {a_{2i} } & \cdots & {a_{2n} } \\ \vdots & \vdots & \ddots & \vdots & \ddots & \vdots \\ {a_{n1} } & {a_{n2} } & \cdots & {a_{ni} } & \cdots & {a_{nn} } \\ \end{array} } \right], \quad X = \left[ {\begin{array}{l} {X_{1} } \\ {X_{2} } \\ \vdots \\ {X_{n} } \\ \end{array} } \right],Y = \left[ {\begin{array}{l} {Y_{1} } \\ {Y_{2} } \\ \vdots \\ {Y_{n} } \\\end{array} } \right] $$
(7)

and let I denote the n X n identity matrix. Equation 6 then can be rewritten simply as

$$ {X} - {AX} = {Y}, $$
(8)

where matrix A stands for the input-output coefficients of the intermediate use of domestic products, X is the vector of output and Y is the net final demand. In the basic matrix,

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}c} {X - AX = Y} \\ {(I - A)X = Y} \\ {X = (I - A)^{ - 1} Y} \\ \end{array} , $$
(9)

where (I - A)–1is the so-called Leontief inverse.Footnote 20 This basic model is also called the static open input–output model, and it forms the basis of most input–output analysis.

2.2 Production–consumption model

In order to arrive at the production–consumption model, the exogenous household sector is moved to the technically interrelated input–output coefficient table. This is also known as closing the model in relation to households, and was introduced by Leontief in his early work.

In practice, the household row and column are added to the coefficient table at the bottom and to the right respectively. The flow of money to households (wages) is shown in the last row ((n + 1)st row), representing at the same time the labour input required for the industry to produce its products. The money flow from the households is shown in the last column of the coefficient table ((n + 1)st column), representing the purchase of goods by the household sector. In its mathematical form the flow Eq. 1 now becomes

$$ X_{i} = z_{i1} + z_{i2} + \ldots + z_{ii} + z_{in} + z_{i,n + 1} + Y_{i} * $$
(10)

where the last term represents the remaining final demand for sector i’s output after the closing of the model in terms of households. In addition, the total value of households’ sales of labour services to other industries is presented as a new equation

$$ X_{n + 1} = z_{n + 1,1} + z_{n + 1,2} + \ldots + z_{n + 1,i} + \ldots + z_{n + 1,n} + z_{n + 1,n + 1} + Y_{n + 1} *. $$
(11)

The element z n+1, n+1 represents the household purchase of labour services (such as paid household work), while the last term on the right includes payments to government employees, for example. The household input coefficients are calculated in the same way as in the open model. The value of industry j’s purchase of labour is divided by the total output of the industry j. The “household industry’s” coefficients are obtained by dividing the purchase of industry i’s product by the total household consumption. Thus, the ith equation in (5) becomes simply

$$ X_{i} = a_{i1} X_{1} + a_{i2} X_{2} + \ldots + a_{ii} X_{i} + \ldots + a_{in} X_{n} + a_{i,n + 1} X_{n + 1} + Y_{i} * $$
(12)

and the new equation relating household output to the total output of industries becomes

$$ X_{n + 1} = a_{n + 1,1} X_{1} + a_{n + 1,2} X_{2} + \ldots + a_{n + 1,i} X_{i} + \ldots + a_{n + 1,n} X_{n} + a_{n + 1,n + 1} X_{n + 1} + Y_{n + 1} * $$
(13)

Similarly, the ith term in Eq. 6 becomes

$$ - a_{i1} X_{1} - a_{i2} X_{2} - \ldots + (1 - a_{ii} )X_{i} - \ldots - a_{in} X_{n} - a_{i,n + 1} X_{n + 1} = Y_{i} * $$
(14)

and for the household sector, rewriting Eq. 12 gives

$$ - a_{n + 1,1} X_{1} - a_{n + 1,2} X_{2} - \ldots - a_{n + 1,i} X_{i} - \ldots - a_{n + 1,n} X_{n} + (1 - a_{n + 1,n + 1} )X_{n + 1} = Y_{n + 1} * $$
(15)

Finally, if the (n + X n + 1) coefficient matrix is nonsingular, the unique solution can again be found by using an inverse matrix. Thus, if we denote the new coefficient matrix A new, the (n + 1)-element column vector of gross output X new, and the (n + 1)-element vector of final demand, including that for the output of households Y new, we can rewrite the solution of the open model simply as

$$ X_{\rm new} = (I - A_{\rm new} )^{ - 1} Y_{\rm new} . $$
(16)

Thus, with the above model it is possible to estimate the impact of a change in the final demand on the economy as a whole as well as on individual industries. It further takes into account the relationship between industries and households in terms of income and consumption. The impact (ΔX) is then written simply as the difference between the original output and the new calculated output

$$ \Updelta X = X - X_{\rm new} . $$
(17)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kauppila, J. Quantifying the relative importance of export industries in a small open economy during the great depression of the 1930s: an input–output approach. Cliometrica 3, 245–273 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-008-0034-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-008-0034-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation