Skip to main content
Log in

The treatment effect of borders on trade. The great war and the disintegration of Central Europe

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Cliometrica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the impact of changes in national border demarcation on economic integration. It treats the national breakups in Central Europe due to WWI as a natural experiment. The set-up allows to control for selection bias when estimating the impact of national borders on trade. A gravity model of trade is used to analyze goods-specific trade among Central European regions. The main results are, first, that systematic deviations of the observations under “border treatment” are found. Regions pairs that became separated by a new national border after WWI, tended to have below average levels of economic integration already before the war. A comparison of actual and biased result for goods-specific trade yields a difference of between 21 and 86% ad-valorem tariff equivalent, and might well be higher for certain goods. Second, the analysis indicates that cross-border integration was indeed lower after WWI but that this change was economically significant only for certain sectors. Third, in the interwar period, international trade was less diverted by borders first established after the war than by borders existing already before WWI. The results stress the importance of relative barriers to trade in attenuating the adverse effects of WWI on economic integration.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The existence of intra-national and international trade frictions coinciding with political barriers was confirmed by many studies, e.g. Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) or Hillberry and Hummels (2003).

  2. The ATE will be equal to the ATET if the treated trade flows are a random selection out of the entire sample.

  3. Other studies concerned with national disintegration (e.g. Fidrmuc and Fidrmuc 2005 or De Ménil and Maurel 1994) have neither identified the effect of new borders nor controlled for possible self-selection.

  4. The number of countries in the world increased from 74 in 1946 to 192 in 1995 (Alesina et al. 2000, p. 1276). Thus, events of political disintegration are frequent and understanding their economic implications is important.

  5. Only one, the third, of the Fourteen Points issued by U.S. President Wilson on January 8, 1918 was concerned with the economy and was not even explicitly aimed at Europe: “[The program of the world’s peace... is this:] III. The removal, so far as possible, of all economic barriers and the establishment of an equality of trade conditions among all the nations consenting to the peace and associating themselves for its maintenance.“

  6. During the years 1922–1924 alone, Poland concluded 13 agreements (Puchert 1963, p. 48). Yet, still in 1925 Germany accounted for about half of Poland’s imports and about one quarter of its exports.

  7. The term two-stage budgeting refers to the consecutiveness of allocation decisions. In a first step, consumers allocate their budget to either traded or non-traded goods. In the second step, only the decision is considered on which variety of the traded goods they spend their budget.

  8. It would certainly be desirable to choose a year more proximate to WWI in order to compare the state of economic integration. However, 1926 provides for extensive data, whose interpretation is more immediate than that at earlier dates. Such data would be biased by all the direct consequences of war, e.g. guerilla fights.

  9. Titles in English (in the order of appearance): Statistics of the Goods’ Movement on German Railways, Goods’ Movement on German Railways, and Statistical Yearbook of Goods’ Movements on Polish State Railways.

  10. For this approximation, I followed the definition of the German statistics, e.g. in case of TD Galicia, I used data on Galicia as well as on the Bukovina provided by the Austrian authorities.

  11. The share of railway shipments in Polish domestic trade was about 99% in the 1930s (Wolf 2005). In Germany, the 1926 share of railways was smaller, namely about four fifth (Statistisches Bundesamt 1926/78). In Russia, the respective share in 1910 was at least two thirds and much higher for most sectors (Žarago 1914), in Germany the share in 1910 was about 84% for rye and coal (Statistisches Jahrbuch 1913).

  12. One further postwar observation is the dissolution of the national border between Alsace–Lorraine and France.

  13. That is the case with the Saargebiet, West Prussia as well as Alsace and Lorraine. The reshaping of TDs in case Northern Schleswig, Eupen and Memel is unproblematic, because of their negligible economic influence.

  14. Data were taken for Galicia and the Bukovina from the Austrian statistics as to make them comparable to the German definition of the TD Galicia.

  15. Center cities are determined according to their economic importance and position in space, see Appendix B.

  16. The Jarque-Bera test on the normality of residuals was rejected at the 5% significance level. The residuals from various regression specifications indicate that errors are heterogeneous implying inefficiency of the estimator. Thus, I applied White’s heteroskedasticity consistent covariance matrix estimator instead of standard OLS using the Eviews package.

  17. Note that the indicator for \(({new\_OTHER^k})\) covers the impact of the new borders between Alsace–Lorraine, the Saargebiet, and Germany, as well as the impact on trade between the former two and the Western Polish regions.

  18. The H0 of equality of coefficients was rejected in case of trade in coals and chemicals using the Wald test.

  19. Whereas rye and coke are considered very homogeneous goods, varieties of coals, especially of hard coal, differ a lot in their product properties. The manufactured products are given in baskets implying heterogeneity.

  20. The estimated coefficients are comparably large because the scale factors account for the effect of barriers on the probability of trade, which is obviously most affected for low-value-to-weight goods as coals, coke, and rye.

  21. Time-varying distance coefficients did not yield statistically and economically significant changes in results.

  22. Substantial means that changes the conclusion from the regressions based on the LSE, e.g. a contradiction.

  23. The area of the postwar TD is definitely not comparable to the prewar TD. However, one can argue that the area-specific intercepts account for the change in Upper Silesia’s economic size as major negative economic shock that equally affect all of Upper Silesia’s trade relations.

  24. Because of heterogeneity a quasi-maximum likelihood estimator (QMLE) was applied instead of a MLE.

  25. This is likely due to the large amount of censored observations of trade in the other goods.

References

  • Alesina A, Spolaore E, Wacziarg R (2000) Economic integration and political disintegration. Am Econ Rev 90(5):1276–1296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, van Wincoop E (2003) Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. Am Econ Rev 93(1):170–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, van Wincoop E (2004) Trade costs. J Econ Lit 42(3):691–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bairoch P (1989) European Trade Policy, 1815–1914. In: Peter M, Sidney P (eds) The Cambridge economic history of Europe, vol 8. The industrial economics: the development of economic and social policies, pp 1–160

  • De Ménil G, Maurel M (1994) Breaking up a customs union: the case of the Austro-Hungarian Empire in 1919. Weltwirtsch Arch 130(3):553–575

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen BJ, Irwin DA (1995) Trade blocs, currency blocs and the disintegration of world trade in the 1930s. J Int Econ 38:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans C (2003) The economic significance of national border effects. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1291–1312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fidrmuc J, Fidrmuc J (2003) Disintegration and trade. Rev Int Econ 11(5):811–829

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Mayer T (2000) Non-Europe: the magnitude and causes of market fragmentation in the EU. Weltwirtsch Arch 136(2)

  • Hillberry R, Hummels D (2003) Intra-national home bias: some explanations. Rev Econ Stat 58(4):1089–1092

    Google Scholar 

  • Jezierski A (1967) Handel Zagraniczny Królestwa Polskiego 1815–1914. Warsaw, Panstwowe Wydawnictwo Naukowe. Dissertation

  • Judge GG, Carter Hill R, Griffiths WE, Lütkepohl H, Lee T-C (1988) Introduction to the theory and practice of econometrics, 2nd edn. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger CP (1989) Commercial policy between the wars. In: Mathias P, Pollard S (eds) The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, vol 8. The industrial economies: the development of economic and social policies. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 161–196

  • Kowal S (2002) Economic co-operation between Poland, the former partition states and their successors in the inter-war period. In: Müller U, Schultz H (eds) National borders and economic disintegration in modern East Central Europe. Berlin Verlag, Berlin, pp 143–154

  • Landau Z (1992) The economic integration of Poland 1918–1923. In: Latawski P (ed) The reconstruction of Poland 1914–1923. Macmillan, London, pp 1–2

  • Landau Z, Tomaszewski J (1977) Druga Rzeczpospolita. Gospodarka—Społeczenstwo—Miejsce w Swiecie (sporne problemy badan). Ksią \({\dot{\hbox{z}}}\) ka i Wiedza, Warsaw

  • Liepmann H (1938) Tariff levels and the economic unity of Europe: an examination of tariff policy, export movements and the economic integration of Europe, 1913–1931. Allen and Unwin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • McCallum J (1995) National borders matter: Canada–US Regional Trade Patterns. Am Econ Rev 85(3):615–623

    Google Scholar 

  • Müller U (2002) Integration and disintegration: the eastern provinces of the German Empire between National Economy and an East-Central European Regional Division of Labour. In: Müller U, Schultz H (eds) National borders and economic disintegration in modern East Central Europe. Berlin Verlag, Berlin, pp 51–66

  • Pollard S (1981) The integration of the European economy since 1815. Allen and Unwin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Puchert B (1963) Der Wirtschaftskrieg des Deutschen Imperialismus Gegen Polen 1925–1934. Akademie Verlag, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Ritschl A, Wolf N (2003) Endogeneity of currency areas and trade blocs. Evidence from the Interwar Period. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 4112

  • Rose A (2000) One money, one market. Estimating the effect of common currencies on trade. Econ Policy 30:7–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz H (2002) Self-determination and economic interest: border drawing after the World Wars. In: Müller U, Schultz H (eds) National borders and economic disintegration in modern East Central Europe. Berlin Verlag, Berlin, pp 109–124

  • Teichova A (1989) East Central and South-East Europe, 1919–1939. In: Mathias P, Pollard S (eds) The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, vol 8. The industrial economies: the development of economic and social policies, pp 887–983

  • Tomaszewski J (1970) Die Polnisch-Sowjetischen Handelsbeziehungen in den Jahren 1920–1929. Studia Historiae Oeconomicae 5:281–301

    Google Scholar 

  • Tomaszewski J (2002) Economic consequences of the new Eastern Borders and the polish economy between the two World Wars. In: Müller U, Schultz H (eds) National borders and economic disintegration in modern East Central Europe. Berlin Verlag, Berlin pp 125–142

  • Wolf HC (2000) Intra-national home bias in trade. Rev Econ Stat 82(4):555–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolf N (2005) Path dependent border effects: the case of Poland’s reunification (1918–1939). Explor Econ Hist 42(3):414–438

    Article  Google Scholar 

Data sources

  • This sections only lists sources referred to in the text. For further data sources cf. Appendix C

  • Biegeleisen LW (1921) Stan ekonomiczny Małopolski. Na podstawie bilansu handlowego. Biuro Prac Kongres. Min. Spraw Zagranicznych, Warsaw

  • Filippi T (1910) Uwagi o Handlu Weglem w Galicyi, Cracow: n.p.

  • Główny Urząd Statystyczny (GUS) (2003) Historia Polski w Liczbach. Państwo i Społeczenstwo, vol 1. GUS, Warsaw

  • Handelsstatistischer Dienst des K.K. Handelsministeriums (1911) Statistik des Auswärtigen Handels des Vertragszollgebiets der Österreichisch-Ungarischen Monarchie 1910, vol 1 (Spezialhandel). Kaiserlich-Königliche Hof- und Staatsdruckerei, Vienna

  • Kaiserliches Statistisches Amt (1913) Statistisches Jahrbuch für das Deutsche Reich 1912. Puttkammer und Mühlbrecht, Berlin

  • Kaiserliches Statistisches Amt (1911) Statistik der Güterbewegung auf Deutschen Eisenbahnen. Hobbing, Berlin

  • K.K. Statistische Zentralkommission (1913) Österreichisches Statistisches Handbuch für die im Reichsrate Vertretenen Königreiche und Länder 1912. Hölder, Vienna

  • K.K. Eisenbahnministerium (1912) Österreichische Eisenbahnstatistik für das Jahr 1910, vol 1. Kaiserlich-Königliche Hof- und Staatsdruckerei, Vienna

  • Krajowe Biuro Statystyczny (1913) Podręcznik Statystyki Galicji, vol 9, No.1, Lwów: n.p.

  • Lewy M (1915) Rosyjskie Taryfy Celne i Kolejowe i ich Wpływ na \({\dot{\hbox{z}}}\) ycie Ekonomiczne Królestwa Polskiego. Gebethner and Wolff, Warsaw

  • Ministerstwo Komunikacji (1927) Rocznik Statystyczny Przewozu Towarów na Polskich Kolejach Panstwowych Według Poszczególnych Rodzajów Towarów za rok 1926, vol I, vol III-A, vol VII. Koziański, Warsaw

  • Schilling K (1931) Die Wirtschaftliche Eingliederung der Elsaß -Lothringischen Montanindustrie in den Französischen Wirtschaftsorganismus. Hofer, Cologne. Dissertation

  • Statistisches Bundesamt (1927/1978a) Die Güterbewegung auf Deutschen Eisenbahnen im Jahre 1926. Statistik des Deutschen Reichs, Neue Folge, vol 344. Otto Zeller, Berlin

  • Statistisches Bundesamt (1927/1978b) Der Auswärtige Handel Deutschlands im Jahre 1926 Verglichen mit den Jahren 1913 und 1925, Statistik des Deutschen Reichs, Neue Folge, vol 339. Otto Zeller, Osnabrück

  • Statistisches Reichsamt (1927) Statistisches Jahrbuch für das Deutsche Reich 1927. Hobbing, Berlin

  • Tennenbaum, Henryk (1916) Bilans Handlowy Królestwa Polskiego. E. Wende, Warsaw

  • Žarago WI (1914) Statističeskij Ežegodnik na 1912 god. Sovět sězdov predstavitelej promyšlennosti i torgovli, St. Petersburg

  • Deutscher Industrie- und Handelstag (DIHT) (1925) Zollhandbuch für Frankreich und das Saargebiet. Zollhandbücher für den Welthandel, vol 3. Hobbing, Berlin

Download references

Acknowledgments

I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Fritz Thyssen Foundation (project grant “The trade network of Central Europe, 1850–1939”). I would like to thank Niko Wolf, Ariel Stern, Volker Nitsch, Andreas Thams, and participants of the 2nd BETA-Workshop in Historical Economics as well as two anonymous referees for helpful comments. David Stenzel provided excellent research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hans Christian Heinemeyer.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM1 (DOC 191 kb)

Appendices

Appendix A: Derivation of the gravity equation

Anderson and van Wincoop (2004) formulate the consumer maximization function as follows

$${\mathop {\max}\limits_{c^{k}_{{ij}}}}\;\;U_{j} = {\sum\limits_k {{\left({{\sum\limits_i {{\left({\beta ^{k}_{i}} \right)}^{{(1 - \sigma_{k})/\sigma_{k}}} {\left({c^{k}_{{ij}}} \right)}^{{(\sigma_{k} - 1)/\sigma_{k}}}}}} \right)}^{{\sigma_{k} /(\sigma_{k} - 1)}}}} \hbox{s.t. the budget constraint}$$
(13)
$$Y_{j} = {\sum\limits_k {E^{k}_{j}}} = {\sum\limits_k {{\sum\limits_i {p^{k}_{{ij}} c^{k}_{{ij}}}}}}$$
(14)

where

c k ij :

denotes region j’s consumption of region i’s goods in product class k.

σ k :

is the elasticity of substitution between all goods in product class k.

β k i :

is some positive distribution parameter.

Y j :

is the nominal income of region j’s inhabitants.

E k j :

is the nominal expenditure of region j’s inhabitants on product k.

p k ij :

denotes the price charged by region i for exports of product k to region j.

Demand for region i’s goods by region j’s consumers has to satisfy maximization of (13) subject to the budget constraint (14). From the Lagrangian we obtain the first order conditions:

$${\left({{\sum\limits_i {{\left({\beta ^{k}_{i}} \right)}^{{(1 - \sigma_{k})/\sigma_{k}}} {\left({c^{k}_{{ij}}} \right)}^{{(\sigma_{k} - 1)/\sigma_{k}}}}}} \right)}^{{1/(\sigma_{k} - 1)}} {\left({\beta ^{k}_{i}} \right)}^{{(1 - \sigma_{k})/\sigma_{k}}} {\left({c^{k}_{{ij}}} \right)}^{{- 1/\sigma_{k}}} \frac{{\sigma_{k} - 1}}{{\sigma_{k}}} = \lambda {\kern 1pt} p^{k}_{{ij}} \quad \forall i \ne j$$
(15)
$${\left({{\sum\limits_i {{\left({\beta ^{k}_{i}} \right)}^{{(1 - \sigma_{k})/\sigma_{k}}} {\left({c^{k}_{{ij}}} \right)}^{{(\sigma_{k} - 1)/\sigma_{k}}}}}} \right)}^{{1/(\sigma_{k} - 1)}} {\left({\beta ^{k}_{j}} \right)}^{{(1 - \sigma_{k})/\sigma_{k}}} {\left({c^{k}_{{jj}}} \right)}^{{- 1/\sigma_{k}}} \frac{{\sigma_{k} - 1}}{{\sigma_{k}}} = \lambda {\kern 1pt} p^{k}_{{jj}} $$
(16)
$${\sum\limits_k {{\sum\limits_i {p^{k}_{{ij}} c^{k}_{{ij}} = Y_{j}}}}}$$
(17)

where (15a) and (15b) hold for all sectors k. Set equal (15a) and (15b). Rearranging them yields

$$p^{k}_{{ij}} c^{k}_{{ij}} = {\left({\frac{{\beta ^{k}_{i}}}{{\beta ^{k}_{j}}}} \right)}^{{(1 - \sigma_{k})}} c^{k}_{{jj}} {\left({p^{k}_{{ij}}} \right)}^{{1 - \sigma_{k}}} {\left({p^{k}_{{jj}}} \right)}^{{\sigma_{k}}} \quad \forall i,k$$
(18)

Summing up (16) over all i and using the definition from the budget constraint (14) gives

$${\sum\limits_i {p^{k}_{{ij}} c^{k}_{{ij}}}} = E^{k}_{j} = {\left({\beta ^{k}_{j}} \right)}^{{- (1 - \sigma_{k})}} c^{k}_{{jj}} {\left({p^{k}_{{jj}}} \right)}^{{\sigma_{k}}} {\sum\limits_i {{\left({\beta ^{k}_{i} p^{k}_{{ij}}} \right)}^{{^{{(1 - \sigma_{k})}}}}}}\quad \forall k$$
(19)

Now, one replaces the terms in (17) that do not depend on i (except for E k j ) by the terms in (16) that do not depend on i. After some rearrangement that yields

$$\frac{{{\left({p^{k}_{{ij}} \beta ^{k}_{i}} \right)}^{{(1 - \sigma_{k})}}}}{{{\sum_i {{\left({\beta ^{k}_{i} p^{k}_{{ij}}} \right)}^{{^{{(1 - \sigma_{k})}}}}}}}}E^{k}_{j} = p^{k}_{{ij}} c^{k}_{{ij}} = X^{k}_{{ij}} \quad \forall k$$
(20)

where the latter equation stems from the definition that demand X in region i for products k from region j is given by price times quantity, i.e. \({X_{ij}^k = p_{ij}^k\, c_{ij}^k}.\) One may simplify (18) assuming equal weights β k i for each region of origin. This assumption yields

$$X^{k}_{{ij}} = {\left({\frac{{{\mathop p\nolimits_{ij}^k}}}{{{\mathop P\nolimits_j^k}}}} \right)}^{{1 - \sigma_{k}}} E^{k}_{j} $$
(21)

where P k j is the CES price index in j defined as

$$P^{k}_{j} \equiv {\left[ {{\sum\limits_i {{\left({{\mathop p\nolimits_{ij}^k}} \right)}}}^{{1 - \sigma_{k}}}} \right]}^{{1/(1 - \sigma_{k})}} $$
(22)

Prices p k ij differ between locations due to a mark-up on p k i , which is the supply price received by producers of k in region i. To achieve a formulation like (19) and (20), several assumptions were needed. (i) I assumed that the mark-up on prices contains only the ad-valorem tariff equivalent of trade costs t k ij . (ii) A further assumption is that trade costs are proportional to trade volumes. Taken together, (i) and (ii) imply \({p_{ij}^k = p_i^k\, t_{ij}^k}.\) (iii) Trade costs are assumed to be borne by the exporter, i.e. formally the exporter incurs export costs equal to (t ij − 1) for each good shipped from i to j. The nominal value of exports from i to j is, thus, the sum of the value of production at the origin p i   c ij plus the trade cost that the exporter passes on to the importer, i.e. \({X_{ij}^k = p_{ij}^k\, c_{ij}^k = p_i^k c_{ij}^k + (t_{ij}^k - 1) p_i^k c_{ij}^k}.\) Imposing market clearing conditions for all regions and sectors

$$Y^{k}_{i} = {\sum\limits_j {{\mathop X\nolimits_{ij}^k}}} \quad \forall \,i,k$$
(23)

and inserting equations (19) into (21) as well as the assumption on the equivalence of trade costs and trade volumes (ii) into (19) gives that

$$Y^{k}_{i} = \;\;\;{\sum\limits_j {{\left({\frac{{{\mathop p\nolimits_{ij}^k}}}{{{\mathop P\nolimits_j^k}}}} \right)}^{{1 - \sigma_{k}}} E^{k}_{j}}}\;\; = \;\;{\sum\limits_j {{\left({\frac{{{\mathop p\nolimits_i^k}{\mathop t\nolimits_{ij}^k}}}{{{\mathop P\nolimits_j^k}}}} \right)}^{{1 - \sigma_{k}}} E^{k}_{j}}}$$
(24)

which has to be rearranged in order to solve for p k i :

$${\left({p^{k}_{i}} \right)}^{{1 - \sigma_{k}}} = \frac{{Y^{k}_{i}}} {{{\sum\nolimits_j {{\left({{\mathop t\nolimits_{ij}^k}/{\mathop P\nolimits_j^k}} \right)}^{{1 - \sigma_{k}}} E^{k}_{j}}}}}\,\;,\quad \forall {\kern 1pt} i$$
(25)

Now, Eq. 23 can be substituted in Eqs. 19 and 20. The result is the theory-based gravity model, which is described by Eqs. 13.

Appendix B

Table 8 Compilation of regions; definition of center cities

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Heinemeyer, H.C. The treatment effect of borders on trade. The great war and the disintegration of Central Europe. Cliometrica 1, 177–210 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-007-0010-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11698-007-0010-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation