Skip to main content
Log in

Honesty in intra-organizational reporting

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this experimental study we analyze the trade-off between the subjects’ preference for wealth on the one hand and their preference for honesty on the other hand. The purpose of this research is to examine the effect of communication medium on reporting behavior. We want to know whether situational cues, such as the communication method—digital (via computer) vs. hard-copy (via paper and pencil) matter, while considering deception. Furthermore, we are interested in the relationship between the social value orientation (SVO) and the reporting behavior. While the experimental evidence shows that participants in both treatments have a preference for truthful reporting and they avoid major lies, there are also remarkable differences between the treatments which we attribute to the reporting medium: computer treatment CT versus paper-and-pencil treatment PPT. Agents are willing to report more honestly via a hard-copy medium than via a digital medium. It seems like participants perceive the digital report more confidential and anonymous than the hard-copy report, and that is why they tend to misrepresent in the CT rather than in the PPT. Further, we found that the SVO influences reporting behavior.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The values of X used in these two treatments are different. However, there are no systematical differences between them, because the same programmed random algorithm was used to forecast these values. We tested the difference between values of X used in the CT and in the PPT also statistically and found no significant differences.

  2. The regression of integrity (i) on SVO gives similar results, in the CT even the same (because h = i) and in the PPT we find slightly higher difference between the integrity of cooperative and individualistic types: β = 0.226 and p < 0.02 (R 2 =  0.076).

References

  • Antle R, Eppen GD (1985) Capital rationing and organizational slack in capital budgeting. Manage Sci 31(2):415–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold MC (2007) Experimentelle forschung in der budgetierung—luegen, nichts als luegen? J fuer Betriebswirtschaft 57(2):69–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baiman S, Lewis BL (1989) An experiment testing the behavioral equivalence of strategically equivalent employment contracts. J Account Res 27(1):1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bandura A (1991) Social cognitive theory of moral thought and action. In: Kurtines WM, Gewirtz L (eds) Handbook of moral behavior and development, vol 1. Erlbaum, Hillsdale, pp 45–103

  • Bandura A (1999) Moral disengagement in the perpetration of inhumanities. Pers Soc Psychol Rev (Lawrence Erlbaum Associates) 3(3):193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bogaert S, Boone C, Declerck C (2008) Social value orientation and cooperation in social dilemmas: a review and conceptual model. Br J Soc Psychol 47(3):453–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown JL, Evans JH III, Moser DV (2009) Agency theory and participative budgeting experiments. J Manag Account Res 21:317–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Covaleski MA, Evans JH III, Luft JL, Shields MD (2007) Budgeting research: three theoretical perspectives and criteria for selective integration. Handb Manag Account Res 2:587–624

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daft RL, Lengel RH (1984) Information richness: a new approach to managerial behaviour and organizational design. Res Organ Behav 6:191–233

    Google Scholar 

  • Daft RL, Lengel RH (1986) Organizational information requirements, media richness and structural design. Manage Sci 32(5):554–571

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daft RL, Lengel RH, Trevino LK (1987) Message equivocality, media selection, and manager performance: implications for information systems. MIS Q 11(3):354–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DePaulo BM, Kashy DA, Kirkendol SE, Wyer MM, Epstein JA (1996) Lying in everyday life. J Pers Soc Psychol 70(5):979–995

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diekman A, Przepiorka W, Rauhut H (2011) Die Präventivwirkung des Nichtwissens im Experiment. Zeitschrift für Soziologie 40:74–84

    Google Scholar 

  • Erat S, Gneezy U (2012) White lies. Manage Sci 58(4):723–733

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans JH III, Hannan RL, Krishnan R, Moser DV (2001) Honesty in managerial reporting. Account Rev 76(4):537–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fandel G, Trockel J (2011a) A game theoretical analysis of an extended manager–auditor-conflict. Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft 4:33–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fandel G, Trockel J (2011b) Optimal lot sizing in a non-cooperative material manager–controller game. Int J Prod Econ 133:256–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fandel G, Trockel J (2013) Avoiding non-optimal management decisions by applying a three-person inspection game. Eur J Oper Res 226:85–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher U (2007) z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp Econ 10(2):171–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher U, Heusi F (2008) Lies in disguise—an experimental study on cheating. TWI Research Paper Series 40, Thurgau Institute of Economics

  • Gneezy U (2005) Deception: the role of consequences. Am Econ Rev 95(1):384–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hannan RL, Rankin FW, Towry KL (2006) The effect of information systems on honesty in managerial reporting: a behavioral perspective. Contemp Account Res 23(4):885–918

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koford K, Penno M (1992) Accounting, principal–agent theory, and self-interested behavior. In: Bowie NE, Freeman RE (eds) Ethics and agency theory, vol 1. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 127–142

  • Laffont J-J, Martimort D (2002) The theory of incentives: the Principal–Agent Model, vol 1. Princeton University Press, Princeton

  • Liebrand WBG (1984) The effect of social motives, communication and group size on behaviour in an n-person multi-stage mixed-motive game. Eur J Soc Psychol 14(3):239–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liebrand WBG, McClintock CG (1988) The ring measure of social values: a computerized procedure for assessing individual differences in information processing and social value orientation. Eur J Pers 2(3):217–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matuszewski LJ (2010) Honesty in managerial reporting: is it affected by perceptions of horizontal equity? J Manag Account Res 22:233–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mazar N, Amir O, Ariely D (2008) The dishonesty of honest people: a theory of self-concept maintenance. JMR 45(6):633–644

    Google Scholar 

  • McClintock CG (1972) Social motivation—a set of propositions. Behav Sci 17(5):438–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meinert D, Vitell SJ, Blankenship R (1998) Respondent “honesty”: a comparison of computer versus paper and pencil questionnaire administration. J Mark Manag (10711988) 8(1):34–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Mietek A, Leopold-Wildburger U (2011) Honesty in budgetary reporting—an experimental study. In: Klatte et al (eds) Operations research proceedings 2011, vol 1. Springer, Berlin, pp 205–210

  • Mittendorf B (2006) Capital budgeting when managers value both honesty and perquisites. J Manag Account Res 18:77–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naquin CE, Belkin LY, Kurtzberg TR (2010) The finer points of lying online: e-mail versus pen and paper. J Appl Psychol 95(2):387–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rankin FW, Schwartz ST, Young RA (2008) The effect of honesty and superior authority on budget proposals. Account Rev 83(4):1083–1099

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rasmußen A (2012) The influence of face-to-face communication. A principal–agent experiment. Cent Eur J Oper Res. doi: 10.1007/s10100-012-0270-7 (Online first)

  • Shalvi S, Handgraaf MJJ, De Dreu CKW (2011) Ethical manoeuvring: why people avoid both major and minor lies. Br J Manag 22:16–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sprinkle GB (2007) Perspectives on experimental research in managerial accounting. Handb Manag Account Res 1:415–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tourangeau R, Yan T (2007) Sensitive questions in surveys. Psychol Bull 133(5):859–883

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trockel J (2013) Changing bonuses and the resulting effects of employees’ incentives to an inspection game. J Bus Econ. doi:10.1007/s11573-013-0680-6

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful for valuable hints by Reinhard Selten and two anonymous referees.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Arleta Rasmußen.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Instructions CT

Dear participants!

Thank you for your participation in this experiment. Please read carefully the instructions before starting the experiment! Your decisions during the experiment are connected with real payoffs. I.e. the more experimental Lira you earn in the experiment, the higher is your payoff in €. The exact conversion rate is: 1 experimental Lira = 0.20€.

The experiment consists of three parts: (1) the reporting experiment, (2) a short post-experimental questionnaire and (3) the preferences questionnaire.

1.1 The experimental task

The experiment reproduces the relationship between two parties within a company: the department manager (you) and the hypothetical shareholder (computer). You are the department manager of a company that has recently started a project that runs over five periods. You have been chosen as the main responsible person for the project.

It is common knowledge that the actual period’s production X ranges between 200 and 400 pieces, in steps of 20. You are however, due to your experience, able to forecast the actual period’s production for sure. You receive, at the beginning of each period, private perfect (100 % certain) information regarding the production. The level of production is random in each period.

Your task, each period, is to make a report regarding the production to the shareholder.

The following table includes your payoffs and payoffs of the shareholder for all possible XB-combinations (your payoff/shareholders payoff) and it shell help you to determine your compensation:

 

Actual production X

200

220

240

260

280

300

320

340

360

380

400

Report B

 200

50/60

56/65

62/70

68/75

74/80

80/85

86/90

92/95

98/100

104/105

110/110

 220

48/58

54/63

60/68

66/73

72/78

78/83

84/88

90/93

96/98

102/103

108/108

 240

46/56

52/61

58/66

64/71

70/76

76/81

82/86

88/91

94/96

100/101

106/106

 260

44/54

50/59

56/64

62/69

68/74

74/79

80/84

86/89

92/94

98/99

104/104

 280

42/52

48/57

54/62

60/67

66/72

72/77

78/82

84/87

90/92

96/97

102/102

 300

40/50

46/55

52/60

58/65

64/70

70/75

76/80

82/85

88/90

94/95

100/100

 320

38/48

44/53

50/58

56/63

62/68

68/73

74/78

80/83

86/88

92/93

98/98

 340

36/46

42/51

48/56

54/61

60/66

66/71

72/76

78/81

84/86

90/91

96/96

 360

34/44

40/49

46/54

52/59

58/64

64/69

70/74

76/79

82/84

88/89

94/94

 380

32/42

38/47

44/52

50/57

56/62

62/67

68/72

74/77

80/82

86/87

92/92

 400

30/40

36/45

42/50

48/55

54/60

60/65

66/70

72/75

78/80

84/85

90/90

After the last period one period-production level will be determined by chance and your payoff will be calculated accordingly your reporting decision in that particular period.

The shareholder will never find out, whether you have reported truthfully or not.

Try to put yourself into the situation and try to behave as if you were involved in a real decision making process.

Thank you for your participation!

Appendix 2: Instructions PPT

Dear participants!

Thank you for your participation in this experiment. Please read carefully the instructions before starting the experiment!

Your decisions during the experiment are connected with real payoffs. I.e. the more experimental Lira you earn in the experiment, the higher is your payoff in €.

The exact conversion rate is: 1 experimental Lira = 0.20€.

The experiment consists of three parts: (1) the reporting experiment, (2) a short post-experimental questionnaire and (3) a preferences questionnaire.

2.1 The experimental task

The experiment reproduces the relationship between two parties within a company: the department manager (you) and the hypothetical shareholder. You are the department manager of a company that has recently started a project that runs over five periods. You have been chosen as the main responsible person for the project.

It is common knowledge that the actual period’s production X ranges between 200 and 400 pieces, in steps of 20. You are however, due to your experience, able to forecast the actual period’s production for sure. You receive, at the beginning of each period, private perfect (100 % certain) information regarding the production. The level of production is random in each period.

Your task, each period, is to make a report regarding the production to the shareholder.

The following table includes your payoffs and payoffs of the shareholder for all possible X–B-combinations (your payoff/shareholder’s payoff) and it shell help you to determine your compensation:

 

Actual production X

200

220

240

260

280

300

320

340

360

380

400

Report B

 200

50/60

56/65

62/70

68/75

74/80

80/85

86/90

92/95

98/100

104/105

110/110

 220

48/58

54/63

60/68

66/73

72/78

78/83

84/88

90/93

96/98

102/103

108/108

 240

46/56

52/61

58/66

64/71

70/76

76/81

82/86

88/91

94/96

100/101

106/106

 260

44/54

50/59

56/64

62/69

68/74

74/79

80/84

86/89

92/94

98/99

104/104

 280

42/52

48/57

54/62

60/67

66/72

72/77

78/82

84/87

90/92

96/97

102/102

 300

40/50

46/55

52/60

58/65

64/70

70/75

76/80

82/85

88/90

94/95

100/100

 320

38/48

44/53

50/58

56/63

62/68

68/73

74/78

80/83

86/88

92/93

98/98

 340

36/46

42/51

48/56

54/61

60/66

66/71

72/76

78/81

84/86

90/91

96/96

 360

34/44

40/49

46/54

52/59

58/64

64/69

70/74

76/79

82/84

88/89

94/94

 380

32/42

38/47

44/52

50/57

56/62

62/67

68/72

74/77

80/82

86/87

92/92

 400

30/40

36/45

42/50

48/55

54/60

60/65

66/70

72/75

78/80

84/85

90/90

After the last period one period-production level will be determined by chance and your payoff will be calculated accordingly your reporting decision in that particular period.

After you have read the instructions take the large envelope containing:

  • a set of report forms sequentially ordered (beginning with period 1) (yellow sheet of paper with the appropriate period number),

  • very short post-experimental questionnaire (blue form) and

  • preferences questionnaire (red form).

Each report form provides the perfect (100 % certain) information regarding the period’s production and also the payoff-table. At the beginning of each period:

  1. 1.

    take one report form from the envelope,

  2. 2.

    put your confidential participant number on it,

  3. 3.

    after seeing the perfect information of the production consult the payoff-table make your report decision and

  4. 4.

    proceed to the next period.

The shareholder will never find out, whether you have reported truthfully or not.

Try to put yourself into the situation and try to behave as if you were involved in a real decision making process.

After the last experimental period fill in all questionnaires ((1) the post-experimental questionnaire and (2) the preferences questionnaire). Please put your confidential participant number on each form in the field “your confidential participant number”.

Thank you for your participation!

Appendix 3: Post-experimental questionnaire

See Table 6.

Table 6 Post-experimental questionnaire

Appendix 4: Ring measure of social values

Appendix 5: CT—experimental task

See Fig. 6.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Screen shot of the experimental task (CT)

Appendix 6: Report Form PPT

 

Actual production X

200

220

240

260

280

300

320

340

360

380

400

Report B

 200

50/60

56/65

62/70

68/75

74/80

80/85

86/90

92/95

98/100

104/105

110/110

 220

48/58

54/63

60/68

66/73

72/78

78/83

84/88

90/93

96/98

102/103

108/108

 240

46/56

52/61

58/66

64/71

70/76

76/81

82/86

88/91

94/96

100/101

106/106

 260

44/54

50/59

56/64

62/69

68/74

74/79

80/84

86/89

92/94

98/99

104/104

 280

42/52

48/57

54/62

60/67

66/72

72/77

78/82

84/87

90/92

96/97

102/102

 300

40/50

46/55

52/60

58/65

64/70

70/75

76/80

82/85

88/90

94/95

100/100

 320

38/48

44/53

50/58

56/63

62/68

68/73

74/78

80/83

86/88

92/93

98/98

 340

36/46

42/51

48/56

54/61

60/66

66/71

72/76

78/81

84/86

90/91

96/96

 360

34/44

40/49

46/54

52/59

58/64

64/69

70/74

76/79

82/84

88/89

94/94

 380

32/42

38/47

44/52

50/57

56/62

62/67

68/72

74/77

80/82

86/87

92/92

 400

30/40

36/45

42/50

48/55

54/60

60/65

66/70

72/75

78/80

84/85

90/90

Appendix 7: Statistics: Post-experimental Questionnaire

See Table 7.

Table 7 Statistics: post-experimental questionnaire

Appendix 8: Honesty measures

See Tables 8 and 9.

Table 8 Honesty h
Table 9 Integrity i

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Rasmußen, A., Leopold-Wildburger, U. Honesty in intra-organizational reporting. J Bus Econ 84, 929–958 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11573-014-0740-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11573-014-0740-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation