Skip to main content
Log in

Religious Charities and Government Funding

  • Published:
International Advances in Economic Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The government has the responsibility of providing a social service to its citizens. It decides whether to award funds to a religious nonprofit, secular nonprofit, or to produce the service itself. Religious charities are willing to provide the service at lower costs if they can use the funds as an opportunity to proselytize their doctrine. This proselytizing alters the religious preferences of believers in society. In a situation of equal grants to religious charities, this has the consequence of reducing the number of extremists. Furthermore, conservative religious denominations may discriminate against non-religious individuals in the provision of the social service.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The literature on the economics of nonprofits and altruistic behavior has developed substantially over the years in the areas of economic theory and empirical research. Rose-Ackerman (1996) states that many theories have been developed to explain the motives behind charitable donations, ranging from donations driven by a sense of commitment as in Sen (1977) and Sugden (1984), to donations driven by the intention of signaling one’s wealth to others as in Glazer and Konrad (1996). Andreoni (1990) also presented another explanation for altruistic behavior based on the desire to gain utility from the act of giving, referred to as the warm-glow effect. Additional literature has focused on the economic behavior of nonprofit institutions in particular, such as Rose-Ackerman (1996), Steinberg and Gray (1993), and Weisbrod (1989).

  2. Much of the empirical work has focused on testing the hypothesis of the crowding out of private contributions by public spending with results ranging from complete crowding out as in Roberts (1984), Sugden (1982) and Warr (1982), to partial crowding out as in Steinberg (1987) and Andreoni (1990). With regards to the effectiveness of nonprofits, Rose-Ackerman (1996) states that initial studies such as Clarkson and Martin (1980) concluded that for-profits were more efficient than nonprofits due to the advantage that the profit motive presents. Others, such as Hawes and Phillips (1986) and Aaranson et al. (1994), concluded using data from nursing homes, that the lack of the profit incentive served as an advantage for nonprofits over competing agencies. Also, Rose-Ackerman (1996) argues that some studies such as Kagan (1991) conclude that for-profits provide services at a lower cost but also at a lower quality.

  3. A careful examination of the methods by which religious charities convey religious messages or doctrine as part of their social service delivery process is done by Unruh (2004). One method, that she calls religious self-descriptions, is through printed media such as program descriptions, brochures, pamphlets, etc. Another method is through religious objects present in the surrounding environment. This may include wall pictures, architecture of the buildings, artifacts, etc. The religious music played may also have a spiritual effect on the recipients of social services (Unruh 2004). In addition to these subtle and indirect ways, more direct methods can be employed such as prayers for the recipients, reading religious text or quotations out loud, and participation in group worship (Unruh 2004). Also, the staff can also have an effect through their dress codes, manner of conduct, and their informal conversations with the consumers or recipients of this social service.

  4. Similar to the religious human capital method used by Smith and Sawkins (2003), the formation of preferences represents a long period of learning by the individual in his/her interactions in the society. It also represents an accumulation of parental investment decisions over time, in addition to the cumulative influence of the social and cultural environment. We assume that the individual has been primarily exposed to the influence of only one denomination.

  5. In his survey of the literature on economics of religion, Iannaccone (1998) remarks that most measures of religious involvement such as voluntary contributions or participation in religious activities are positively related to the level of religiosity in the denomination. For example, he states, “[that] the members of liberal Protestant denominations contribute a relatively small proportion of their income to churches (around 1.5 %), whereas the members of conservative Protestant denominations, such as the Southern Baptists and the Assemblies of God, contribute significantly more (between 2 % and 4 %), and Mormon contributions average 6 % of income” (Iannaccone 1998). Furthermore, he states that religious involvement in terms of, “rates of church attendance, follow a similar pattern, with liberal Protestant denominations ranking lowest, conservative Protestants attending more, and sect members, such as Mormons and Jehovah’s Witnesses, attending still more (Hoge and Yang 1994; Iannaccone 1992, 1994).” In a statistical survey on the determinants of religious participation, Iannaccone (1998) comments that, “members of conservative and sectarian denominations attend and give much more than members of liberal denominations even after controlling for socioeconomic differences.”

  6. Awarding one denomination more funds is a similar situation to funding only one denomination.

  7. Barros and Garoupa (2002) label a similar group as the ‘non-church’.

References

  • Aaranson, I. E., Zinn, J. S., & Rosko, M. D. (1994). Do for-profit and not-for-profit nursing homes behave differently? Gerontologist, 34(6), 775–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm-glow giving. The Economic Journal, 100, 464–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barros, P. P., & Garoupa, N. (2002). An economic theory of church strictness. The Economic Journal, 112(481), 559–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1974). A theory of social interactions. Journal of Political Economy, 82(6), 1063–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berrien, J., McRoberts, O., & Winship, C. (2000). Religion and the Boston miracle: the effect of black ministry on youth violence. In M. J. Bane, B. Coffin, & R. Thiemann (Eds.), Who will provide? The changing role of religion in American social welfare (pp. 266–85). Boulder: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarkson, K. W., & Martin, D. L. (Eds.). (1980). The economics of nonproprietary organizations. Greenwich: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desmond, D., & Maddux, J. (1981). Religious programs and careers of chronic heroin users. The American Journal of Drug and Alcohol Abuse, 8(1), 71–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebaugh, H. R., Pipes, P. F., Chafetz, J. S., & Daniels, M. (2003). Where’s the religion? Distinguishing faith-based from secular social service programs. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 42(3), 411–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, A., & Konrad, K. A. (1996). A signaling explanation for charity. The American Economic Review, 86(4), 1019–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawes, C., & Phillips, C. D. (1986). The changing structure of the nursing home industry and the impact of ownership on quality, cost, and access. In B. H. Gray (Ed.), For-profit enterprise in health care (pp. 492–541). Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoge, D. R., & Yang, F. (1994). Determinants of religious giving in american denominations: data from two nationwide surveys. Review of Religious Research, 36(2), 123–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. The Economic Journal, 39(153), 41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1992). Sacrifice and stigma: reducing free-riding in cults, communes and other collectives. Journal of Political Economy, 100(2), 271–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1994). Why strict churches are strong. The American Journal of Sociology, 99(5), 1180–1211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1998). An introduction to the economics of religion. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(September), 1465–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kagan, S. L. (1991). Examining profit and nonprofit child care: an odyssey of quality and auspices. Journal of Social Issues, 47(2), 87–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, R. D. (1984). A positive model of private charity and public transfers. Journal of Political Economy, 92(1), 136–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. (1996). Altruism, nonprofits, and economic theory. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(June), 701–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1977). Rational fools: a critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory. Philosophy and Public Affairs, 6(4), 317–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, I., & Sawkins, J. W. (2003). The economics of regional variation in religious attendance. Applied Economics, 35(14), 1577–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steinberg, R. S. (1987). Voluntary donations and public expenditures in a federalist system. The American Economic Review, 77(1), 24–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steinberg, R., & Gray, B. H. (1993). The role of nonprofit enterprise in 1993: Hansmann revisited. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 22(4), 297–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J., & Becker, G. S. (1977). De Gustibus Non Est Disputandum. The American Economic Review, 67(2), 76–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (1982). On the economics of philanthropy. The Economic Journal, 92(371), 341–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (1984). Reciprocity: the supply of public goods through voluntary contributions. The Economic Journal, 94(376), 772–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Unruh, H. R. (2004). Religious elements of church-based social service programs: types, variables, and integrative structures. Review of Religious Research, 45(4), 317–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warr, P. G. (1982). Pareto-optimal redistribution and private charity. Journal of Public Economics, 19(1), 131–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weisbrod, B. (1989). Rewarding performance that is hard to measure: the private nonprofit sector. Science, 244(4904), 541–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ayman Reda.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Reda, A. Religious Charities and Government Funding. Int Adv Econ Res 18, 331–342 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11294-012-9358-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11294-012-9358-z

Keywords

JEL

Navigation