Skip to main content
Log in

Estimating Water Rights Demand and Supply: Are Non-market Factors Important?

  • Published:
Water Resources Management Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Water rights demand and supply in the upper Maipo river basin (Metropolitan Region of Chile) are estimated for the period July 1998 to June 2003, as well as a reduced form model for the equilibrium water rights price based on supply and demand determinants, as well as characteristics of the participating agents such as the economic sector of each agent and their individual market experience. Results show that the main participants in the market are both agriculture and real estate sectors (developers); agriculture buying 57 % and selling 68 % of transactions. The estimated supply and demand system shows that market forces indeed drive market water right prices. Demand is inelastic to price while supply is highly elastic. Furthermore, supplied and demanded water rights quantities are functions of water right price as well as the economic sector of buyer and sellers, sectoral profits, and geographic location of the water right. Additionally, the agent’s previous water rights market-experience is an important determinant of water rights demands and supply.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A water entitlement in Australia is the maximum amount of water authorized to be taken and used by a person under specific conditions/specifications; however, the Government retains the overall right to the use, flow and control of all surface water and groundwater. This definition is similar to Chile’s definition of a water right, and thus from here on we use the term water right. Water entitlement prices refer to the value of the water right; thus, it is the value obtained in the permanent water right market.

  2. In Australia, water allocation is the amount of water actually available for use or trade under an entitlement to water in a given year. The allocation depends on the conditions during the year and in a dry year, an allocation will be reduced. A water allocation price is the exchange value for water in a given period. The transaction does not imply the transfer of water rights and, thus, this represents a spot market. Chile’s Water Code of 1981 does not specify water allocations. Each WR indicates the maximum water flow the WR holder is allowed to extract, when there is sufficient water flow to satisfy all of the permanent consumptive WRs. In the case that there is not sufficient WR can extract a proportion of actual water flows; the proportion is defined by the percentage that the water flow of the WR represents of the total granted water flows.

  3. Chile’s Water of 1981 specifies consumptive water rights for both surface and groundwater, and non-consumptive water rights for surface waters. Non-consumptive water rights allow the owner to divert water from a river with the obligation to return the same water unaltered to its original channel. Consumptive use rights do not require that the water be returned once it has been used. Consumptive and non-consumptive water rights are, by law specified as a volume per unit of time. However, given that river flows are highly variable in most basins, these WR are recognized in times of scarcity as shares of water flows. This study centers only on consumptive water rights market and, thus, we use the term water rights from here on.

  4. WR trading existed prior to the Water Law of 1981. There is evidence of WR trading under the Water Code of 1951. However, this water code did not explicitly allow for the creation and operation of efficient WR markets.

  5. A river section consists of the geographic area where the river flow begins (or restarts) and its water flow is extinguished. These sections are treated legally as independent areas and the total quantities of water rights are defined for each river section.

  6. There are no interanual reservoirs in the Maipo Basin, thus WR in the basin are defined in terms of water flows.

  7. This equivalency is the average available water flow per permanent consumptive surface WR; it does not indicate the water flow a specific WR holder can extract. As pointed out, the allowed extraction is defined as a water flow up to a cap. There is not limit to the cap defined in each WR. Thus, the maximum water flow of each WR is variable.

  8. Given that a WR entitles the user to extract the specified water flow, a transaction of 0.001 WR represents a transaction of 0.001 of the specified water flow.

  9. UF (unidad de fomento) is an official, inflation-adjusted unit. As of July 22, 2013, 1 UF = US$ 45.9

  10. Since the water flows defined in each WR are variable, prices/WR are variable and depend on the defined water flows. The higher the water flows, the higher the WR price.

  11. The main regulatory measure established in the WC 1981 to control for potential negative effects on third parties and/or the environment due to the transfer of WR between water users is when the transfer implies a change of water intake location, the transfer must be authorized by the DGA.

  12. Water demand functions have traditionally used linear, log–log or log–linear functional forms Wheeler et al. 2008. A variety of models was tested and the linear functional form is presented here. We lacked basis to sustain a specific functional form and thus chose to present the linear model. It is important to point out that the conclusions do not depend on the functional form.

  13. Given that WR allow WR holders to extract a water flow up to a defined maximum, but a proportion of water flows when there is not sufficient water flows to satisfy all permanent consumptive WR, actual demand and supply of WR depend on actual water flows. Actual water flows is the best information WR buyers and sellers have when trading since historic hydrologic information is not readily available (personal communication Fuentes, Jose, Asociación Canalistas del Maipo). An interested party must petition the DGA for hydrologic information. The answer time of the DGA is variable.

  14. Table 1 presents a list of variables used in the econometric models and their definitions.

  15. The data identifies each buyer and seller for each transaction. Thus, if a specific buyer or seller participated in a transaction on a previous date, we consider that this agent has previous experience in the WR market.

References

  • (Saliba) C, Bush BD, Martin W, Brown T (1987) Do water market prices appropriately measure water values? Nat Resour J 27:617–651

    Google Scholar 

  • Alicera, M., E. Brown, and J. E. Doña (1999), Bases para el análisis del mercado de derechos de aprovechamiento de aguas en la cuenca del rio Maipo. VI Jornadas del CONAPHI Chile. Available at: http://www.unesco.org.uy/PHI/libros/VIJornadas/C32.pdf

  • Bauer C (1997) Bringing water markets down to earth: the political economy of water rights in Chile, 1976–95. World Dev 25(5):639–656

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley D, Kuh E, Welsch R (1980) Regression diagnostics: identifying influential data and sources of collinearity. Wiley, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bjornlund, H., (2002), Signs of maturity in Australian markets. New Zealand Property Journal July: 31–46

  • Bjornlund H, McKay J (1998) Factors affecting water prices in a rural water market: a South Australian experience. Water Resour Res 34(6):1568–1570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjornlund H, McKay J (2002) Aspects of water markets for developing countries: experiences form Australia, Chile and the US. Environ Dev Econ 7(4):769–795

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjornlund H, Rossini P (2005) Fundamentals determining prices and activities in the market for temporary water. Int J Water Resour Dev 21(2):355–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjornlund H, Rossini P (2007) Fundamentals determining prices in the market for water entitlements — An Australian case study. Int J Water Resour Dev 23(3):537–553

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks R, Harris E (2008) Efficiency gains from water markets: empirical analyses of watermove in Australia. Agric Water Manag 95:391–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brookshire, D., B. Colby, M. Ewers, and T. Ganderton. (2004), Market prices for water in the semiarid West of the United States. Water Resources Research 40, W09S04, doi:10.1029/2003WR002846.

  • Burke, S. M., R. M. Adams, and W. W. Wallender (2004), Water banks and environmental water demands: Case of the Klamath Project, Water Resources Research 40, doi:10.1029/2003WR002832

  • Colby B, Crandall K, Bush D (1993) Water right transactions: market values and price dispersion. Water Resour Res 29(6):1565–1572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crouter JP (1987) Hedonic estimation applied to a water rights market. Land Econ 63:259–271

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DGA (Dirección General de Aguas) (2014), Solicitudes de Cambio de Punto de Captación en la Primera Sección del Río Maipo, Dirección General de Aguas (DGA), Mendez Hernandez, Laura, personal communication, Santiago, Chile. March 27, 2014

  • del Río F, Simón L (1995) Asignación y Distribución de las Aguas Terrestres. Editorial Universidad Gabriela Mistral, Chile, 143 pp

    Google Scholar 

  • DGA (Dirección General de Aguas) (2007) Bases para la Formulación de un Plan Director para la Gestión de los Recursos Hídricos Cuenca del Río Maipo, Etapa I Diagnóstico/Ministerio de Obras Públicas, Dirección General de Aguas (DGA), Departamento de Estudios y Planificación. CONIC BF Ingenieros Civiles Consultores. Santiago, Chile, 620 pp

    Google Scholar 

  • Donohew Z (2009) Property rights and western United States water markets. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 53:85–103

    Google Scholar 

  • Donoso G (2006) Water markets: case study of Chile’s 1981 water code. Ciencia e Investigación Agraria 33(2):157–171

    Google Scholar 

  • Donoso G, Montero JP, Vicuña S (2001) Análisis de los Mercados de Derechos de Aprovechamiento de Agua en las Cuencas del Maipo y el Sistema Paloma en Chile: Efectos de la Variabilidad en la Oferta Hídrica y de los Costos de Transacción. Rev de Derecho Administrativo Económico III 2:363–366

    Google Scholar 

  • Ganderton P (2002) Western water market prices and the economic value of water, 2nd congress of environmental and resource economists. Monterrey, México

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardner R, Miller T (1983) Price behavior in the water market of Northeastern Colorado. Water Resour Bull 19:557–562

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomez-Limon J, Riesgo L (2004) Water pricing: analysis of differential impacts on heterogeneous farms. Water Resour Res 40:W07S05

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadjigeorgalis, E. (2000), Private water Markets in Agriculture and the Effects of Risk, Uncertainty and Institutional Constraints. Dissertation. Agricultural and Resource Economics Department. University of California, Davis, California. 208pp

  • Hadjigeorgalis E, Riquelme C (2002) Análisis de los Precios de los Derechos de Aprovechamiento de Aguas En el Rio Cachapoal. Cien Inv Agr 29(2):91–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Hearne R, Donoso G (2005) Water institutional reforms in Chile. Water Policy 7:53–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Hearne, R., and W.K. Easter. (1995), Water Allocation and Water Markets. An Analysis of Gains-from-trade in Chile, World Bank Technical Paper n. 315. The World Bank.Washington, DC.

  • Hook MA, Alexander WE (1999) Estimating the demand for irrigation water in the Central Valley of California. J Am Water Resour Assoc 34(3):497–505

    Google Scholar 

  • Jouravlev AS (2010) Código de Aguas de Chile: Desafíos Pendientes. Presentation to the Directorate General of Water, Chile

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuehne G, Bjornlund H (2006) ‘Custodians’ or ‘Investors’ — classifying irrigators in Australia’s Namoi Valley. In: Lorenzini G, Brebbia CA (eds) Sustainable Irrigation Management. Technologies and Policies. WIT Press, Southampton, pp 225–236

    Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G. (2010), Water Rights and Markets in the U.S. Semi-Arid West: Efficiency and Equity Issues, Document prepared for the Conference on “The Evolution of Property Rights Related to Land and Natural Resources, September 20–21, 2010, http://www2.bren.ucsb.edu/~glibecap/Lincolndevelopmentwaterrights.pdf, Accessed April 15, 1014.

  • Livingston ML (1995) Designing water institutions: market failures and institutional response. Water Resour Manag 9(3):203–220

    Google Scholar 

  • Pullen JL, Colby BG (2008) Influence of climate variability on the market price for water in the Gil-San Francisco basin. J Agric Resour Econ 33(3):473–487

    Google Scholar 

  • Rios M, Quiroz J (1995) The market of water rights in Chile: major issues. Cuad Econ 32:317–345

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosegrant M, Gazmuri R (1995) Reforming water allocation policy through markets in tradable waters rights. Lessons from Chile, Mexico and California. Cuad Econ 32:291–315

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosegrant M, Ringler C, McKinney DC, Cai X, Keller A, Donoso G (2000) Integrated economic-hydrologic water modelling at the basin scale: the Maipo River Basin. Agric Econ 24(1):33–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Saleth, R. M., and A. Dinar (1999), Evaluating water institutions and water sector performance, Tech. Pap. 447, World Bank, Washington, D. C.

  • Saleth, R. M., and A. Dinar (2004), The institutional economics of water: a cross-country analysis of institutions and performance, Edward Elgar, Northampton, Mass

  • Vergara A (1998) Derecho de Aguas. Editorial Jurídica de Chile, Santiago, 548 pp

    Google Scholar 

  • Wheeler S, Bjornlund H, Shanahan M, Zuo A (2008) Price elasticity of water allocations demand in the Goulburn–Murray Irrigation District. Aust J Agric Resour Econ 52:37–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Wheeler S, Bjornlund H, Shanahan M, Zuo A (2009) Who trades water? Evidence of the characteristics of early adopters in the Goulburn-Murray Irrigation District, Australia 1998–99. Agric Econ 40:631–643

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wheeler S, Bjornlund H, Zuo A, Shanahan M (2010) The changing profile of water traders in the Goulburn-Murray Irrigation District, Australia between 1998–99 and 2003–06. J Agric Water Manag 97(9):1333–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang LH, Jia SF, Leung CK, Guo LP (2013) An analysis on the transaction costs of water markets under DPA and UPA Auctions. Water Resour Manag 27:475–484. doi:10.1007/s11269-012-0197-8

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to G. Donoso.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Donoso, G., Melo, O. & Jordán, C. Estimating Water Rights Demand and Supply: Are Non-market Factors Important?. Water Resour Manage 28, 4201–4218 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11269-014-0739-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11269-014-0739-3

Keywords

Navigation