Skip to main content
Log in

Multidimensional Pigou–Dalton transfers and social evaluation functions

  • Published:
Theory and Decision Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We axiomatize, in the multidimensional case, a social evaluation function that can accommodate a natural Pigou–Dalton principle and correlation increasing majorization. This is performed by building upon a simple class of inframodular functions proposed by Müller and Scarsini under risk.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Note that throughout the paper we assume \(n\ge 3\). Indeed, to obtain an additive representation in a parsimonious way through the classical independence axiom as in Debreu’s theorem (1960), it is known that \(n>2\) is required, which in any case appears to make sense for applications.

  2. Since this paper has been performed, we are aware of a similar Pigou–Dalton principle introduced by (Bosmans et al., 2009). Nevertheless, main differences persist between the two papers: our definition is model-free and our main motivation is to link this principle to inframodularity.

  3. Let \((X, Y) \in \mathbb {R}^{m} \times \mathbb {R}^{m}, X \wedge Y=(\ldots , \min (x_{i}, y_{i}), \ldots ), X \vee Y=(\ldots , \max (x_{i}, y_{i}), \ldots )\). Correlation Increasing Majorization stipulates the meaningful requirement that replacing two individuals endowed initially with X and Y by individuals endowed with \(X \wedge Y\) and \(X \vee Y\) increases inequality. Since an inframodular function u is submodular, i.e., \(u(X)+u(Y) \ge u(X \wedge Y)+u(X \vee Y)\), one gets this property.

  4. In 2010, the HDI functional has changed its additive form to a multiplicative form as introduced above. Section 6 includes a discussion about this ‘new’ HDI. Details are in Zambrano (2014).

  5. See the Proof of Theorem 2, in Sect. 3

  6. Indeed, \(X^{(p)}\downarrow X\) and \(X^{(p)}\uparrow X\) means that the sequences \(X^{(p)}\) are, respectively, decreasing (increasing) with respect to the pointwise order in \(\mathbb {R}^{m}\) while converging towards X.

  7. Indeed, below \(\mathbb {Z}, \mathbb {N}\) and \(\mathbb {Q}\) (respectively, \(\mathbb {Z^{*}}, \mathbb {N^{*}}\) and \(\mathbb {Q^{*}}\)) denote as usually the set of integers, non-negative integers, rational numbers (respectively, non-null elements in \(\mathbb {Z}, \mathbb {N}\) and \(\mathbb {Q}\)).

  8. See, e.g., Kolm 1976a, b; Atkinson 1970 or else Aczél 1966 to get this result.

  9. Each column represents an individual.

  10. For more details, see UNDP (1990).

  11. Zambrano (2014) has a discussion about this new index, its computation and axiomatization. See also Herrero et al. (2010).

  12. This exam is called ENEM (Exame Nacional do Ensino Médio—National high school exam). This exam is non-mandatory and has been used both as an admission test for enrollment in federal universities and educational institutes, as well as for certification for a high school degree.

  13. Kovacevic (2010) offers a good review and discussion about the importance of the inequality to evaluate the human development.

  14. Note that \(u_{j}\) increasing comes from our monotonicity axiom A.3.

References

  • Aczél, J. (1966). Lectures on functional equations and their applications. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B. (1970). On the measurement of inequality. Journal of economic theory, 2(3), 244–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B. (1987). On the measurement of poverty. Econometrica, 55(4), 749–764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. B., & Bourguignon, F. (1982). The comparison of multi-dimensioned distributions of economic status. The Review of Economic Studies, 49(2), 183–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boland, P. J., & Proschan, F. (1988). Multivariate arrangement increasing functions with applications in probability and statistics. Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 25(2), 286–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosmans, K., Lauwers, L., & Ooghe, E. (2009). A consistent multidimensional Pigou–Dalton transfer principle. Journal of Economic Theory, 144(3), 1358–1371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon, F., & Chakravarty, S. R. (2003). The measurement of multidimensional poverty. The Journal of Economic Inequality, 1(1), 25–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. (1960). Topological methods in cardinal utility theory. In K. J. Arrow, S. K, & P. Suppes (Eds.), Mathematical methods in the social sciences (pp. 16–26). Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gajdos, T., & Weymark, J. A. (2005). Multidimensional generalized Gini indices. Economic Theory, 26(3), 471–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrero, C., Martínez, R., & Villar, A. (2010). Multidimensional social evaluation: an application to the measurement of human development. Review of Income and Wealth, 56(3), 483–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolm, S.-C. (1976a). Unequal inequalities. I. Journal of Economic Theory, 12(3), 416–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolm, S.-C. (1976b). Unequal inequalities. II. Journal of Economic Theory, 13(1), 82–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kolm, S.-C. (1977). Multidimensional egalitarianisms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91(1), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kovacevic, M. (2010). Measurement of inequality in human development-a review. Human Development Research Paper 35. New York: UNDP.

  • Marinacci, M., & Montrucchio, L. (2005). Ultramodular functions. Mathematics of Operations Research, 30(2), 311–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller, A., & Scarsini, M. (2001). Stochastic comparison of random vectors with a common copula. Mathematics of operations research, 26(4), 723–740.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller, A., & Scarsini, M. (2012). Fear of loss, inframodularity, and transfers. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(4), 1490–1500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richard, S. F. (1975). Multivariate risk aversion, utility independence and separable utility functions. Management Science, 22(1), 12–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1976). Poverty: an ordinal approach to measurement. Econometrica, 44(2), 219–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaked, M. (1982). A general theory of some positive dependence notions. Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 12(2), 199–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsui, K.-Y. (1995). Multidimensional generalizations of the relative and absolute inequality indices: the Atkinson–Kolm–Sen approach. Journal of Economic Theory, 67(1), 251–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsui, K.-Y. (1999). Multidimensional inequality and multidimensional generalized entropy measures: an axiomatic derivation. Social Choice and Welfare, 16(1), 145–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNDP (1990) Human Development Report 1990. Concept and measurement of human development (p. 189). New York: Oxford university press.

  • Wakker, P. P. (1989). Additive representations of preferences: A new foundation of decision analysis. New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Weymark, J. A. (1981). Generalized Gini inequality indices. Mathematical Social Sciences, 1(4), 409–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zambrano, E. (2014). An axiomatization of the human development index. Social Choice and Welfare, 42(4), 853–872.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to anonymous referees for very helpful suggestions and comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paulo Casaca.

Additional information

Alain Chateauneuf gratefully acknowledges the hospitality and the support of the University of Rome La Sapienza, during his stay as visiting professor in Spring 2014. Also, Paulo Casaca acknowledges the National Council of Scientific and Technologic Development (CNPq) on the support to stay in Paris as visiting Phd student during the academic year 2015–2016.

Appendices

Appendix

We split up the Appendix in two parts: Appendix A includes the proof of Theorem 1 and Appendix B gives the proofs of Lemmas 1 and 2.

1.1 Appendix A

Theorem 1

Proof

We give only the sufficient part, since the necessary proof is immediate.

From A.1, A.2, A.3, A.4 (weak order, continuity, monotonicity and independence) and \(n\ge 3\), Theorem 3 in Debreu (1960) implies that there exist n increasingFootnote 14 and continuous functions \(u_{j}:\mathbb {R}^{m}\longrightarrow \mathbb {R}\) such that

$$\begin{aligned} A\succsim B\Longleftrightarrow \sum \limits _{j=1}^{n}u_{j}(A_{j})\ge \sum \limits _{j=1}^{n}u_{j}(B_{j}) \end{aligned}$$

where \(u_{j}\) are unique up to affine transformation \(\alpha u_{j}+\beta _{j}\) with \(\alpha >0\) and \(\beta _{j}\in \mathbb {R}\). Thus, we can assume that for all j, \(u_{j}(0)=0\).

From A.5 (Anonymity), let us see that we can assume that there exists \(u:\mathbb {R}^{m}\longrightarrow \mathbb {R}\), increasing and continuous such that

$$\begin{aligned} A\succsim B\Longleftrightarrow \sum \limits _{j=1}^{n}u(A_{j})\ge \sum \limits _{j=1}^{n}u(B_{j}) \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

Then, fix \(u_{j}\) such that \(u_{j}(0)=0\), for all j. By symmetry, we only need to prove that \(u_{1}=u_{2}.\) Take any \(A_{1}\in \mathbb {R}^{m}\) and consider \(\left( A_{1},0,A_{3},\ldots ,A_{n}\right) \) and \(\left( 0,A_{1},A_{3},\ldots ,A_{n}\right) \). Through A.5: \(u_{1}(A_{1})+u_{2}(0)+\sum _{j=3}^{n}u_{j}(A_{j})= u_{1}(0)+u_{2}(A_{1})+\sum _{j=3}^{n}u_{j}(A_{j})\), this entails straightforwardly \( u_{1}(A_{1})=u_{2}(A_{1})\); thus \(u_{1}=u_{2}=\cdots =u_{n}=u.\) Therefore, there exists \(u:\mathbb {R}^{m}\longrightarrow \mathbb {R}\) increasing continuous (satisfying \(u_{j}(0)=0\)) such that (A.1) holds. Clearly, u is defined up to a positive affine transformation \(\square \)

Appendix B

Marinacci and Montrucchio (2005) provided a thorough analysis of ‘Ultramodular Functions’, thus (by reversing the inequality in the definition) of what Müller and Scarsini (2012) called ‘Inframodular Functions’ defined in Sect. 2.

We intend now to prove that inframodular functions agree with our Pigou–Dalton regressive transfers (see Sect. 1).

Lemma 1

if \(u:\mathbb {R}^{n}\rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) is inframodular then u satisfies the property (1) quoted in Sect. 2.

Proof

Let \(x,y\in \mathbb {R}^{n}\), \(x\le y\) and \(\varepsilon \ge 0\). Set \(x^{\prime }=x-\varepsilon \) and \(y^{\prime }=y\), \(\varepsilon ^{\prime }=\varepsilon \), so \(x^{\prime }\le y^{\prime }\) and \(\varepsilon ^{\prime }\ge 0\). Then from the Definition 1 in Section 2 of u inframodular,

$$\begin{aligned} u(x^{\prime }+\varepsilon )-u(x^{\prime })\ge u(y^{\prime }+\varepsilon )-u(y^{\prime }), \end{aligned}$$

i.e.,

$$\begin{aligned} u(x)-u(x-\varepsilon )\ge u(y+\varepsilon )-u(y) \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Lemma 2

(Proof of Theorem 4) First, it is known that if u is inframodular, then u is submodular, i.e., for all \(a,b\in \mathbb {R}^{m}, u(a)+u(b)\ge u(a\wedge b)+u(a\vee b)\) (see, e.g., Marinacci and Montrucchio 2005).

Let us show it again for sake of completeness.

Let \(x=a\wedge b\), so \(a=a\wedge b+\varepsilon \) with \(\varepsilon \ge 0.\)

Let \(y=b\), one has \(x\le y\) and \(\varepsilon \ge 0\) then u inframodular implies \(u(x+\varepsilon )-u(x)\ge u(y+\varepsilon )-u(y)\), i.e., \(u(a)-u(a\wedge b)\ge u(b+a-a\wedge b)-u(b)\). But \(b+a-a\wedge b=a\vee b\), hence, the result

$$\begin{aligned} u(a)+u(b)\ge u(a\wedge b)+u(a\vee b). \end{aligned}$$

Thus, one has \(u(A_{1})+u(A_{2})\ge u(A_{1}\vee A_{2})+u(A_{1}\wedge A_{2})\).

Since by hypothesis neither \(A_{1}\le A_{2}\) nor \(A_{2}\le A_{1}\), u strict inframodular implies \(u(A_{1})+u(A_{2})>u(A_{1}\vee A_{2})+u(A_{1}\wedge A_{2})\).

Actually, since not \(A_{2}\le A_{1}\), we get \(A_{1}\wedge A_{2}<A_{2}\ \) then letting \(x=A_{1}\wedge A_{2}\), \(y=A_{2}\), \(\varepsilon =A_{1}- A_{1}\wedge A_{2}\), we get

$$\begin{aligned}&u(x+\varepsilon )+u(y)> u(y+\varepsilon )+u(x),\hbox { i.e., } u(A_{1}) \\&\quad + u(A_{2})>u(A_{1}\vee A_{2})+u(A_{1}\wedge A_{2}). \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Basili, M., Casaca, P., Chateauneuf, A. et al. Multidimensional Pigou–Dalton transfers and social evaluation functions. Theory Decis 83, 573–590 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-017-9605-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-017-9605-0

Keywords

Navigation