Skip to main content
Log in

On the Use of Shadow Prices for Sustainable Well-Being Measurement

  • Published:
Social Indicators Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper tries to answer the following research question: can multidimensional concepts like well-being or sustainability be measured by using a single metric such as shadow prices? The defence of shadow prices is generally based on the pragmatic argument that different dimensions (economic, social, environmental,…) cannot be aggregated when measured by means of different metrics, thus a common measurement rod has to be found, that is shadow prices have to be used. Here the following conclusions are drawn: (1) The choice of shadow prices is not neutral, in fact implicit assumptions such as that substitutability is always desirable need to be accepted. This means that the use of shadow prices is not consistent with a simple measurement objective but with a precise weltanschauung. (2) Shadow prices are primarily meant to implement efficiency, i.e. prices reflect conditions at the margin, and thus this is their natural objective. In the framework of sustainable well-being measurement, this may give rise to counterintuitive results, such as that the loss of an important well-being component is not perceived since its physical scarcity is compensated by its increase in monetary value. (3) The pragmatic measurement argument is not well grounded, since multidimensional measurement frameworks exist, such as multi-criteria evaluation. Since incommensurability between different metrics does not imply incomparability, there is no obvious reason for not using multidimensional techniques to measure multidimensional concepts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. One obvious problem here is that many natural resources (e.g. air, water and wilderness) do not have observable prices. Thus one would need to find implicit or shadow prices in some way. Even those prices that do exist may not be useful; they may be affected by market imperfections and taxes, and they may exclude externalities involved with the production and use of the resource. In terms of history of the economic thought, it is also worthy to remember that the issues concerning the nature, role and measurement of capital goods was the focus of the so-called Cambridge controversy (Harcourt 1972). Although the term capital was referred to artificial capital, the results can be extended to natural capital too, if money valuation is used, in particular the problem of circularity among the quantity of capital, its monetary value and the rate of interest.

  2. In terms of history of the economic thought, it is worthy to remember that indeed shadow prices were invented as a solution to the debate on economic calculus in a socialist economy. Hayek, replying to Neurath wrote (Neurath 1973, p. 31): “Neurath was quite oblivious of the insuperable difficulties which the absence of value calculations would put in the way of any rational economic use of the resources…”. Or, as Von Mises had put it (Von Mises, 1920, in Hayek, ed. 1935, p. 111), "Where there is no free market, there is no pricing mechanism; without a pricing mechanism, there is no economic calculation". Kantorovich (1939) found a possible solution to this dilemma by inventing shadow prices (see also Karmiloff, 1963 for an overview of shadow prices use in the former Soviet Union).

  3. Cabeza Gutés (1996) notes that the concept of weak sustainability is nothing but a by-product of growth theory with exhaustible resources when:

    1. the definition of inter-generational equity is restricted to a non-declining level of consumption per capita;

    2. the relationship environment-economy is restricted to the introduction of an aggregate input called natural capital into the production function.

    Indeed, weak sustainability is simply a different statement of the so called Hartwick-Solow rule (Hartwick 1977, 1978; Solow Solow 1974a, b, 1986), stating that in order to have a stream of constant level of consumption per capita to infinity, society should invest all the current returns from the utilisation of the flows from the stock of exhaustible resources. These authors generally recognise that even if the production technologies of an economy can potentially yield increases in output commensurate with increases in inputs, overall output will be constrained by limited supplies of resources (growth theory with exhaustible resources). But these limits can be overcome by technological progress: if the rate of technological progress is high enough to offset the decline in the per capita quantity of natural resource services available, output per worker can rise indefinitely. A stronger statement is the claim of weak sustainability: even in the absence of any technological progress exhaustible resources do not pose a fundamental problem if reproducible artificial capital is sufficiently substitutable for natural resources.

  4. Emphasis added to the original.

References

  • Arrow, K. J., Dasgupta, P., Goulder, L. H., Mumford, K. J., & Oleson, K. (2012). Sustainability and the measurement of wealth. Environment and Development Economics, 17(03), 317–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cabeza Gutés, M. (1996). On the concept of weak sustainability. Ecological Economics, 17(3), 147–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, R. (Ed.). (1997). Incommensurability, incomparability, and practical reason. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P. (2001). Valuing objects and evaluating policies in imperfect economies. Economic Journal, 111, C1–C29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duclos, J. Y., Sahn, D. E., & Younger, S. D. (2006). Robust multidimensional poverty comparisons. Economic Journal, 116, 943–968.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (1995). Will raising the incomes of all increase the happiness of all? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 27, 35–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (2001). Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. Economic Journal, 111, 465–484.

    Google Scholar 

  • Figueira, J., Greco, S., & Ehrgott, M. (Eds.). (2005). Multiple-criteria decision analysis: State of the art surveys. New York: Springer International Series in Operations Research and Management Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002). What can economists learn from happiness research? Journal of Economic Literature, 15, 402–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (1986). Economists favour the price system who else does? Kyklos, 39(4), 537–563.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (ed.) (1935) Collectivist economic planning. Reprinted Augustus M. Kelley, New York, 1970.

  • Harcourt, G. C. (1972). Some Cambridge controversies in the theory of capital. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hartwick, J. M. (1977). Intergenerational equity and the investing of rents from exhaustible resources. American Economic Review, 67(5), 972–974.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartwick, J. M. (1978). Substitution among exhaustible resources and inter-generational equity. Review of Economic Studies, 45, 347–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kantorovich, L.V. (1939) Mathematical Methods of Organizing and Planning Production, Leningrad University Press, published in English in Management Science, 6(4), 366–422 (1960).

  • Karmiloff, G. (1963). Soviet economic models investment criteria and prices: An analytical review. Kyklos, 16(1), 83–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michalos, A. C. (1980). Satisfaction and happiness. Social Indicators Research, 8(4), 385–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michalos, A. C. (1997). Combining social, economic and environmental indicators to measure sustainable human well-being. Social Indicators Research, 40(1–2), 221–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G. (1997). Environmental economics, ecological economics and the concept of sustainable development. Environmental Values, 6(2), 213–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G. (2004). Social multi-criteria evaluation (SMCE): methodological foundations and operational consequences. European Journal of Operational Research, 158(3), 662–677.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G. (2005). Measuring sustainability: A multi-criterion framework. Environment, Development and Sustainability, 7(1), 117–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G., & Nardo, M. (2009). Non-compensatory/non-linear composite indicators for ranking countries: A defensible setting. Applied Economics, 41, 1513–1523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G., & Saisana, M. (2011). Methodological considerations on regional sustainability assessment based on multicriteria and sensitivity analysis. Regional Studies, 45(2), 261–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G. (2012a). Choosing aggregation rules for composite indicators. Social Indicators Research, 109(3), 337–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G. (2012b). Intensity of preference and related uncertainty in non-compensatory aggregation rules. Theory and Decision, 73(4), 649–669.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G. (forthcoming) Beyond GDP: An Overview of Measurement Issues in Redefining “Wealth”. Journal of Economic Surveys.

  • Nardo, M., Saisana, M., Saltelli, A., Tarantola, S., Hoffman, A., & Giovannini, E. (2008). Handbook on constructing composite indicators: methodology and user guide. Paris: OECD Statistics Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neurath, O. (1973). Empiricism and sociology. Dordrecht: Reidel.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D. W., & Turner, K. R. (1990). Economics of natural resources and the environment. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D. W., & Atkinson, G. D. (1993). Capital theory and the measurement of sustainable development: an indicator of “weak” sustainability. Ecological Economics, 8, 103–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabinowicz, W. (2012). Value relations revisited. Economics and Philosophy, 28, 133–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roy, B. (1996). Multicriteria methodology for decision analysis. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1979). Personal utilities and public judgment: Or what’s wrong with welfare economics? Economic Journal, 89(355), 537–558.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1985). Commodities and capabilities. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1974a). The economics of resources or the resources of economics. American Economic Review, 64, 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1974b). Intergenerational equity and exhaustible resources. Review of Economic Studies, 67, 29–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. M. (1986). On the intergenerational allocation of natural resources. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 88(1), 141–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J., Sen A., & Fitoussi, J.P. (2009). Report by the Commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress, available at http://www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr/en/index.htm.

  • Turner, R. K., Pearce, D. W., & Bateman, I. (1994). Environmental economics: An elementary introduction. London: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Victor, P. A. (1991). Indicators of sustainable development: Some lessons from capital theory. Ecological Economics, 4, 191–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von WeizsÄcker, C. C. (1974). Substitution along the time axis. Kyklos, 27(4), 732–756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2011). The changing wealth of nations: Measuring sustainable development in the new millennium. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giuseppe Munda.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Munda, G. On the Use of Shadow Prices for Sustainable Well-Being Measurement. Soc Indic Res 118, 911–918 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-013-0446-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-013-0446-0

Keywords

Navigation