Skip to main content
Log in

Endogenous formation of entrepreneurial networks

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The purpose of this paper is to study the incentives of entrepreneurial actors to collaborate with others in order to achieve superior performance. We consider an environment composed of n entrepeneurial actors who are identical with regard to the type of innovation and their costs for innovative activities. Innovation takes place in a contest where actors invest in knowledge in order to increase their chances of winning. Prior to these investments, actors have the opportunity to collaborate with others and to form an entrepreneurial network. The benefits of such a cooperation arise from the commitment to share knowledge. For a given network structure, we first completely characterize the actors’ investments in knowledge and their resulting payoffs. In particular, we show that bigger entrepeneurial networks are not always more beneficial than smaller ones. Using these results, we then analyze the optimal endogenous formation of entrepeneurial networks in the open and the exclusive membership game. Our results indicate that the size of entrepreneurial networks is rather limited.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, e.g., the reviews by Hoang and Antoncic (2003), Witt (2004), Street and Cameron (2007), or Slotte-Kock and Coviello (2010).

  2. Note that we focus on the sharing of knowledge but do not consider the case in which members of a network can coordinate their investments as well. See also our discussion in Section 6.

  3. See also Silipo (2005) for an experiment on the evolution of competing networks in a patent race. He finds that the larger the number of players in the experiment, the lower the probability of colluding in the race.

  4. This result is in line with previous literature on R&D competition (see, e.g., Poyago-Theotoky 1999 or Kamien and Zang 2000). However, these studies do not consider network competition but only competition between individual firms.

  5. See also Bloch (1995), Yi (1997), or Greenlee (2005) for a sequential formation game, called unanimity game. Bloch (2002) also considers the formation of a single RJV as an open membership game.

  6. The nature of market competition is also analyzed in the context of cost-reducing process innovations by Goyal and Joshi (2006) who show that if competition is in prices, no coalitions will be formed in equilibrium.

  7. See also Jost and van der Velden (2007) for modelling product innovation as a patent race in the context of ex-post merger organization.

  8. For the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship, see Audretsch and Keilbach (2007), or Acs et al. (2009, 2013).

  9. For the knowledge filter theory, see also Audretsch and Keilbach (2007), Braunerhjelm et al. (2010), or Acs et al. (2012).

  10. This is why studies on the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship assume that there are no interregional spillovers, but only local ones (see, e.g., Audretsch and Feldman 1996, Anselin et al. 1997, or Acs et al. 2004). See also Wieser (2005) for an estimation of spillovers within industries which are relatively small.

  11. The assumption of complete spillovers is common in the literature on RJV (see, e.g., Kamien et al. 1992, Poyago-Theotoky 1995, Vonortas 1994).It is consistent with the equilibrium that emerges when spillovers are endogenized (see Beath et al. 1998, S.49). In the case of partial spillovers within a RJV, consider Greenlee (2005). For external spillovers, see, e.g., d’Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988).

  12. This assumption is in line with the literature on RJVs (see Loury 1979 and Lee and Wilde 1980). A situation in which the losers may get positive payoffs can be analyzed in a similar way (see Beath et al. 1998 in the context of RJVs).

  13. This function has been widely used to describe R&D competition as well as interest group competition, lobbying, or labor market tournaments (see Baye et al. 1998 for economic applications of contests, and Nitzan 1994 for a survey on the literature on Tullock’s functional form). This form of market uncertainty in the R&D contest also arises from a more elaborate probability structure (see Fullerton and McAfee 1999). Moreover, Baye and Hoppe (2003) show that R&D tournaments in which the innovation process follows a stochastic process are equivalent to our simple contest function in which the probability of winning equals the share of aggregate expenditures.

  14. Note that for jNr(i) \(\frac {\partial }{\partial x_{j}} p_{i}=\frac {\left ({\sum }_{j=1}^{n}\tilde {x}_{j}\right ) -\tilde {x}_{i}+\beta \left (n-m_{r}\right ) }{\left ({\sum }_{j=1}^{n}\tilde {x}_{j}\right )^{2}}>0\).

  15. Note, that this result is in contrast with Greenlee (2005, p. 364f) who finds in Proposition 1 that larger networks are always more profitable than smaller ones, and in Proposition 2(i) that an individual actor always finds it profitable to switch to a weakly larger network.

  16. Again, this result is in contrast to the finding of Greenlee (2005), who shows that network members prefer rivals to be dispersed (see Proposition 2 (ii) and (iii)).

  17. See Footnote 20 for a discussion on situations where such side payments are allowed.

  18. Our results are similar to the findings by Baik and Lee (2001): In their framework, only one equilibrium coalition structure occurs for n ≤ 5, whereas for n > 5, the grand coalition is never formed and when more than one group is formed, every player belongs to one of the groups (see their Proposition 1).

  19. The condition that \(k_{1}^{\ast }+k_{2}^{\ast }-1\geq m^{\ast }\) follows from the observation that an actor in network Ni has higher payoffs than a non-cooperating actor if mi < k − 1 (see the discussion below Corollary 1).

  20. This statement is not true if we allow for side payment. In fact, members of a network Nj of size m will always benefit from allowing an additional member i if they redistribute payoffs ex-post. To see this, compare the ex-post payoffs of all member in a network of size m + 1 with their ex ante payoffs. Then,

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \left( m+1\right) {\Pi}_{j}^{\ast }\left( k-1;m+1,1,{\ldots} 1\right) &>&m{\Pi}_{j}^{\ast }\left( k;m,1,{\ldots} 1\right)\\ &&+{\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( k;m,1,{\ldots} 1\right) \end{array} $$

    is satisfied for all m and k.

  21. Note that our results on network formation differ from those of Yi and Shin (2000) due to the underlying innovative process. In their framework, members of a larger network invest more in knowledge than members of smaller networks, whereas the opposite is true in our model. Corollary 3 is, however, similar to the result by Sánchez-Pagés (2007) (see his Proposition 4). He shows that the only equilibrium coalition structure is the singleton structure {1, 1,..., 1}. The difference stems from the fact that in his framework, some groups may remain inactive because their members value a successful contest less, whereas in our model, each actor carries out positive investments in Knowledge independent of her affiliation.

  22. Note that because all members of a certain network choose identical investments in knowledge, they all have identical payoff functions and therefore prefer the same network-specific degree of spillovers.

  23. This assumption is without loss of generality. In general, of course, knowledge spillovers depend on the type of knowledge and the industry considered. If, for example, the design of the innovation process requires the choice of a particular technology, external spillovers cannot be completely controlled by networks.

  24. Of course, for (β1, β2,...,βk) = (β,β,...,β) optimal investments are identical to the ones in Proposition 2.

  25. This formulation of T differs from the previous literature on productive contests which assumes that there are no dynamics in the contest (see Denicolo 1999 or Guerra et al. 2016). They assume that T is constant and independent of the contestants’ innovative activities.

  26. This implies that

  27. This follows from the characterization of the optimal investment \( x_{i}^{\ast }\) in Proposition 2 and the characterization of the effective investments \(\tilde {x}_{i}^{\ast }\) in (3) for mi = n/k.

  28. Note that W/k = 0 implies

    $$ T^{\prime }\left( \tilde{X}^{\ast }\right) \frac{V}{k^{2}}\left( 1-\beta \right) =n\frac{V}{n^{2}}\frac{1-\beta }{\left( k\beta -\beta +1\right)^{2}} , $$

    and W/β = 0 implies

    $$ T^{\prime }\left( \tilde{X}\right) V\frac{\left( k-1\right) }{k}=nV\frac{k}{ n^{2}}\frac{\left( k-1\right) }{\left( k\beta -\beta +1\right)^{2}}. $$
  29. Note that \(\frac {\partial }{\partial k}\left [ \frac {\left (k+1\right ) \left (m_{1}-1\right ) -k}{\left (k+1\right )^{2}\left (m_{1}-1\right )^{2}}-\frac { k\left (m_{1}-1\right ) +1}{k^{2}{m_{1}^{2}}}\right ] >0\).

References

  • Acs, Z.J., Audretsch, D.B., Braunerhjelm, P., Carlsson, B. (2004). The missing link: the knowledge filter and endogenous growth.

  • Acs, Z.J., Audretsch, D.B., Braunerhjelm, P., Carlsson, B. (2005). The knowledge filter and entrepreneurship in endogenous growth. Papers on entrepreneurship, growth and public policy, No. 08, Max Planck Institute of Economics. Jena, Germany.

  • Acs, Z.J., Braunerhjelm, P., Audretsch, D.B., Carlsson, B. (2009). The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 32(1), 15–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z.J., Audretsch, D.B., Braunerhjelm, P., Carlsson, B. (2012). Growth and entrepreneurship. SSSmall Business Economics, 39(2), 213–245.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acs, Z.J., Audretsch, D.B., Lehmann, E.E. (2013). The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. SSSmall Business Economics, 41(4), 757–774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amir, R., & Wooders, J. (1999). Effects of one-way spillovers on market shares, industry price, and innovative cooperation. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 8, 233–249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anselin, L., Varga, A., Acs, Z. (1997). Local geographic spillovers between university research and high technology innovations. Journal of Urban Economics, 42(3), 422– 448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. (1995). Innovation and industry evolution. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D.B., & Feldman, M.P. (1996). R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. The American Economic Review, 86(3), 630–640.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D.B., & Keilbach, M. (2007). The theory of knowledge spillover entrepreneurship. Journal of Management Studies, 44(7), 1242–1254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baik, K.H., & Lee, S. (2001). Strategic groups and rent dissipation. Economic Inquiry, 39, 672–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baye, M.R., & Hoppe, H.C. (2003). The strategic equivalence of rent-seeking, innovation, and patent-race games. Games and Economic Behavior, 44(2), 217–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baye, M.R., Kovenock, D., De Vries, C. (1998). A general linear model of contests. Manuscript, Dept. Econ., Indiana Univ.

  • Beath, J., Poyago-Theotoky, J., Ulph, D. (1998). Organization design and information-sharing in a entrepreneuerial network with spillovers. Bulletin of Economic Research, 50(1), 47–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, F. (1995). Endogeneous structures of association in oligopoly. Rand Journal of Economics, 26, 537–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, F. (1997). Noncooperative models of coalition formation in games with spillovers. In Carraro, C, & Siniscalco, D. (Eds.) New directions in the economic theory of the environment: Cambridge University Press.

  • Bloch, F. (2002). Coalitions and networks in industrial organization. Manchester School, 70, 36–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, F. (2009). Endogenous formation of alliances in conflicts. Ecole Polytechnique. Cahier no. 2009–46.

  • Bloch, F., Sanchez-Pages, S., Soubeyran, R. (2006). When does universal peace prevail? Secession and group formation in conflict. Economics of Governance, 7, 3–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandenburger, A.M., & Nalebuff, B.F. (1996). Coopetition. London: Harper Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braunerhjelm, P., Acs, Z.J., Audretsch, D.B., Carlsson, B. (2010). The missing link: knowledge diffusion and entrepreneurship in endogenous growth. SSSmall Business Economics, 34(2), 105–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, B., & Butler, J.E. (1995). Competitors as allies: a study of entrepreneurial networks in the U.S. wine industry. Journal of Small Business Management, 33(3), 57–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassiman, B., Di Guardo, M.C., Valentini, G. (2009). Organising R&D projects to profit from innovation: Insights from coopetition. Long Range Planning, 42, 216–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceccagnoli, M. (2009). Appropriability, preemption, and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 81–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont, C., & Jacquemin, A. (1988). Cooperative and noncooperative innovative in duopoly with spillovers. American Economic Review, 78, 1133–1137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denicolo, V. (1999). The optimal life of a patent when the timing of innovation is stochastic. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 17(6), 827–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dari-Mattiacci, G., Langlais, E., Lovat, B., Parisi, F. (2007). Crowding-out in productive and redistributive rent-seeking. Public Choice, 133(1–2), 199–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bondt, R., & Veugelers, R. (1991). Strategic investments with spillovers. European Journal of Political Economy, 7, 345–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bondt, R., & Wu, C. (1997). Research joint venture cartels and welfare. In Competition, cooperation, research and development (pp. 39–56). London: Palgrave Macmillan.

  • Deng, W., & Hendrikse, G. (2018). Social interactions and product quality: the value of pooling in cooperative entrepreneurial networks. SSSmall Business Economics, 50(4), 749–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eickelpasch, A., & Fritsch, M. (2005). Contests for cooperation—a new approach in German innovation policy. Research Policy, 34(8), 1269–1282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteban, J., & Sakovicz, J. (2003). Olson vs. coase: coalitional worth in conflict. Theory and Decision, 55, 339–357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faems, D., Janssens, M., Van Looy, B. (2010). Managing the cooperation–competition dilemma in R&D alliances: a multiple case study in the advanced materials industry. Creativity and Innovation Management, 19, 3–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franke, J., & Ozturk, T. (2009). Conflict networks.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, M.P. (1999). The new economics of innovation, spillovers and agglomeration: areview of empirical studies. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 8(1–2), 5–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fullerton, R.L., & McAfee, R.P. (1999). Auctionin entry into tournaments. Journal of Political Economy, 107(3), 573–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garfinkel, M. (2004). Stable alliance formation in distributional conflict. European Journal of Political Economy, 20, 829–852.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal, S., & Joshi, S. (2006). Unequal connections. International Journal of Game Theory, 34, 319–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grandjean, G., Tellone, D., Vergote, W. (2017). Endogenous network formation in a Tullock contest. Mathematical Social Sciences, 85, 1–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenlee, P. (2005). Endogenous formation of competitive research sharing joint ventures. Journal of Industrial Economics, 53, 355–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenlee, P., & Cassiman, B. (1999). Product market objectives and the formation of reserach joint ventures. Managerial and Decision Economics, 20, 115–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groth, G. (2006). We have a winner: programming contests show impressive growth. IEEE Software, 23(6), 99–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grünfeld, L.A. (2006). Multinational production, absorptive capacity, and endogenous R&D spillovers. Review of International Economics, 14(5), 922–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guerra, A., Luppi, B., Parisi, F. (2016). Productive and unproductive competition: a unified framework. Economia Politica, 1–20.

  • Hiller, T. (2017). Friends and enemies: a model of signed network formation. Theoretical Economics, 12(3), 1057–1087.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1971). The private and social value of information and the reward to inventive activity. The American Economic Review, 61(4), 561–574.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoang, H., & Antoncic, B. (2003). Network-based research in entrepreneurship: a critical review. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(2), 165–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howells, J.R. (2002). Tacit knowledge, innovation and economic geography. Urban Studies, 39(5–6), 871–884.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johannisson, B., Alexanderson, O., Nowicki, K., Senneseth, K. (1994). Beyond anarchy and organization: entrepreneurs in contextual networks. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 6(4), 329–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jost, P.J., & van der Velden, C. (2007). Organizational design of innovative after mergers and the role of budget responsibility. Journal of Business and Economics, 60, 469–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M., Müller, E., Zang, I. (1992). Entrepreneuerial networks and innovative Cartels. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1293–1306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M., & Zang, I. (1993). Competing entrepreneuerial networks. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 2(1), 23–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M.I., & Zang, I. (2000). Meet me halfway: research joint ventures and absorptive capacity. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18(7), 995–1012.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, M. (1986). An analysis of co-operative research and development. Rand Journal of Economics, 17, 527– 543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, T., & Wilde, L.L. (1980). Market structure and innovations: a reformulation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94, 429–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitas, E., & McFadyen, M. A. (2009). Managing liquidity in research-intensive firms: signaling and cash flow effects of patents and alliance activities. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 659–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, P. (1997). License to be more innovative. Review of Industrial Organization, 12(2), 271–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loury, G.C. (1979). Market structure and innovation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93, 395–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morasch, K. (2000). Strategic alliances as Stackelberg cartels - concept and equilibrium alliance structure. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18, 257–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, M.H., Koçak, A., Özer, A. (2007). Coopetition as a small business strategy: implications for performance. Journal of Small Business Strategy, 18(1), 35–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Motta, M. (1992). Cooperative innovative and vertical product differentiation. International Journal of Industrial Economics, 10, 643–661.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nitzan, S. (1994). Modelling rent-seeking contests. European Journal of Political Economy, 10(1), 41–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell, A., Carson, D., Gilmore, A. (2002). Competition and co-operation between small actors and their competitors. Journal of Research in Marketing and Entrepreneurship, 4(1), 7–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plummer, L.A., & Acs, Z.J. (2014). Localized competition in the knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship. Journal of Business Venturing, 29(1), 121–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poyago-Theotoky, J. (1995). Equilibrium and optimal size of entrepreneuerial networks in an oligopoly with spillovers. Journal of Industrial Economics, 43, 209–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poyago-Theotoky, J. (1999). A note on endogenous spillovers in a non-tournament R & D duopoly. Review of Industrial Organization, 15(3), 253–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivette, K.G., & Kline, D. (2000). Discovering new value in intellectual property. Harvard Business Review, 78, 54– 66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roach, G. (2011). Horizontal networks and collaborative marketing in the Tasmanian wine industry. Diss. University of Tasmania.

  • Ross, L.W., & Byrd, K. (2011). Business plan competitions: start-up’idols’ and their twenty-first century launch pads. Journal of Higher Education Theory and Practice, 11(4), 53–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez-Pagés, S. (2007). Endogenous coalition formation in contests. Review of Economic Design, 11, 139–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silipo, D.B. (2005). The evolution of cooperation in patent races: theory and experimental evidence. Journal of Economics, 85(1), 1–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas, S. (1998). On the formation of alliances in conflicts and contests. Public Choice, 96, 25–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slotte-Kock, S., & Coviello, N. (2010). Entrepreneurship research on network processes: a review and ways forward. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34(1), 31–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sofka, W., de Faria, P., Shehu, E. (2018). Protecting knowledge: how legal requirements to reveal information affect the importance of secrecy. Research Policy, 47(3), 558–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Street, C.T., & Cameron, A.-F. (2007). External relationships and the small business: a review of small business alliance and network research. Journal of Small Business Management, 45(2), 239–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suzumura, K. (1992). Cooperative and noncooperative innovative in an oligopoly with spillovers. American Economic Review, 82, 1307–1320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tan, G., & Wang, R. (1997). Endogenous coalition formation in rivalry, Queen’s Economics Department Working paper 956. Queen’s University, Kingston, Canada.

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In Buchanan, J.M., Tollison, R.D., Tullock, G. (Eds.) Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station.

  • Vonortas, N.S. (1994). Inter-firm cooperation with imperfectly appropriable research. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 12, 413–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wieser, R. (2005). Research and development productivity and spillovers: empirical evidence at the firm level. Journal of Economic Surveys, 19(4), 587–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies, p. 2630. New York.

  • Witt, P. (2004). Entrepreneurs’ networks and the success of start-ups. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 16(5), 391–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi, S.-S. (1997). Stable coalition structures with externalities. Games and Economic Behavior, 20, 201–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi, S.-S. (1998). Endogenous formation of joint ventures with efficiency gains. Rand Journal of Economics, 29, 610–631.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yi, S.-S., & Shin, H.S. (2000). Endogenous formation of research coalitions with spillovers. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 18, 229–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter-J. Jost.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Proposition 1

  1. 1.

    Consider first effective investments. Equation (2) implies that \( \tilde {x}_{i}^{\ast } = \tilde {x}_{j}^{\ast }\frac {\alpha _{j}}{\alpha _{i}}< \tilde {x}_{j}^{\ast },\)since αj < αi for mj < mi. Hence,

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }&=&m_{i}x_{i}^{\ast }+\beta m_{j}x_{j}^{\ast }+\sum\limits_{\begin{array}{lll} r=1 \\ r\neq i,j \end{array}}^{k}\beta m_{r}x_{r}^{\ast }<\tilde{x}_{j}^{\ast }\\ &=&m_{j}x_{j}^{\ast }+\beta m_{i}x_{i}^{\ast }+\sum\limits_{\begin{array}{lllll} r=1 \\ r\neq i,j \end{array}}^{k}\beta m_{r}x_{r}^{\ast }, \end{array} $$

    that is, \(\left (1-\beta \right ) m_{i}x_{i}^{\ast }<\left (1-\beta \right ) m_{j}x_{j}^{\ast }\). Since mj < mi, \(x_{i}^{\ast }<\frac {m_{j}}{m_{i}} x_{j}^{\ast }<x_{j}^{\ast }\).

  2. 2.

    Using Eq. (2), the probability of being successful in the contest is given by

    $$ p_{i}=\frac{\tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }}{\tilde{X}^{\ast }}=\frac{\tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }}{\tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }\sum\limits_{j=1}^{n}\frac{\alpha_{i}}{\alpha_{j}}}=\frac{1}{\alpha_{i}}\left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}}{\alpha_{r}} \right)^{-1}. $$

    Then, mi > mj implies αi > αj and the proposition follows.

  3. 3.

    Equations (2) and (3) imply that

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \tilde{X}^{\ast } &=&\sum\limits_{j=1}^{n}\tilde{x}_{j}^{\ast }=\tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }\cdot \sum\limits_{j=1}^{n}\frac{\alpha_{i}}{\alpha_{j}}\\ &=&\frac{V}{\alpha_{i}} \cdot \frac{\left( \sum\limits_{j=1}^{n}\frac{1}{\alpha_{j}}\right) -1}{\left( \sum\limits_{j=1}^{n}\frac{1}{\alpha_{j}}\right)^{2}}\cdot \alpha_{i}\sum\limits_{j=1}^{n}\frac{1}{\alpha_{j}} \\ &=&V\cdot \frac{\left( \sum\limits_{j=1}^{n}\frac{1}{\alpha_{j}}\right) -1}{\left( \sum\limits_{j=1}^{n}\frac{1}{\alpha_{j}}\right) }=V\cdot \frac{\left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}}{\alpha_{r}}\right) -1}{\left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k} \frac{m_{r}}{\alpha_{r}}\right) }. \end{array} $$

    Define \(f\left (\beta \right ) :=\left (\sum \limits _{r=1}^{k}\frac {m_{r}}{\alpha _{r} }\right ) \). Then

    $$ \frac{\partial }{\partial \beta }\tilde{X}^{\ast }=V\cdot \frac{\partial }{ \partial \beta }\left( \frac{f\left( \beta \right) -1}{f\left( \beta \right) }\right) =\frac{f^{\prime }\left( \beta \right) }{f\left( \beta \right)^{2}} . $$

    Since αr = mr + β (nmr) , we have

    $$ f^{\prime }\left( \beta \right) =-\left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}\left( n-m_{r}\right) }{{\alpha_{r}^{2}}}\right) <0. $$

Proof of Proposition 2

Define

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} A&=&\left( \begin{array}{cccc} m_{1} & \beta m_{2} & {\ldots} & \beta m_{k} \\ \beta m_{1} & m_{2} & {\ldots} & \beta m_{k} \\ {\vdots} & {\vdots} & {\ddots} & {\vdots} \\ \beta m_{1} & \beta m_{2} & {\ldots} & m_{k} \end{array} \right) \ \text{and }\\ B_{i}&=&\left( \begin{array}{ccccc} m_{1} & {\ldots} & \tilde{x}_{1}^{\ast } & {\ldots} & \beta m_{k} \\ \beta m_{1} & {\ldots} & \tilde{x}_{2}^{\ast } & {\ldots} & \beta m_{k} \\ {\vdots} & {\vdots} & {\vdots} & {\vdots} & {\vdots} \\ \beta m_{1} & {\ldots} & \tilde{x}_{k}^{\ast } & {\ldots} & m_{k} \end{array} \right) \end{array} $$

where Bi is derived from A by substituting the i-row (βmi,...,mi,...βmi)T by \(\left (\tilde {x}_{1}^{\ast },...,\tilde {x}_{i}^{\ast },...\tilde {x}_{k}^{\ast }\right )^{T}\). Induction over r = 1,…k then shows that the determinants of A and Bi are

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{det }A &=&\prod \limits_{r=1}^{k}m_{r}\cdot \left( 1-\beta \right)^{k-1}\cdot \left( 1+\left( k-1\right) \beta \right) \text{ and} \\ \text{det }B_{i} &=&\prod \limits_{r=1,r\neq i}^{k}m_{r}\cdot \left( 1-\beta \right)^{k-2}\\ &&\cdot \left[ \left( 1+\left( k-1\right) \beta \right) \tilde{x} _{i}^{\ast }-\beta \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\tilde{x}_{r}^{\ast }\right] . \end{array} $$

Using Cramer’s Rule, the solution of \(A\cdot \left (x_{1}^{\ast },x_{2}^{\ast }\right .\) \(\left .,..., x_{k}^{\ast }\right )^{T}=\left (\tilde {x}_{1}^{\ast },\tilde {x} _{2}^{\ast },...\tilde {x}_{k}^{\ast }\right )^{T}\ \)is determined by

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} x_{i}^{\ast }&=&\frac{\text{det }B_{i}}{\text{det }A}=\frac{1}{m_{i}\cdot \left( 1-\beta \right) }\\ &&\cdot \left[ \tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }-\frac{\beta }{ 1+\left( k-1\right) \cdot \beta }\cdot \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\tilde{x} _{r}^{\ast }\right] . \end{array} $$

With \(\tilde {x}_{r}^{\ast }=\tilde {x}_{i}^{\ast }\cdot \frac {\alpha _{i}}{ \alpha _{r}}\) the proposition follows. □

Proof of Proposition 3

  1. 1.

    Using the definition of \(\tilde {p}_{r}\) and γ it follows that

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \tilde{p}_{i}-\tilde{p}_{j} &=&-\frac{1}{m_{i}\cdot \left( 1-\beta \right) } \\ &&\cdot \left[ 1-\frac{\beta }{1+\left( k-1\right) \cdot \beta }\cdot \sum \limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{\alpha_{i}}{\alpha_{r}}\right] \\ &&+\frac{1}{m_{j}\cdot \left( 1-\beta \right) }\\ &&\cdot \left[ 1-\frac{\beta }{ 1+\left( k-1\right) \cdot \beta }\cdot \sum \limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{\alpha_{j}}{\alpha_{r}}\right] \\ &=&\frac{1}{\left( 1-\beta \right) }\left[ \frac{1}{m_{j}}-\frac{1}{m_{i}} \right] \\ &&+\frac{\gamma }{\left( 1-\beta \right) }\left[ \frac{\alpha_{i}}{ m_{i}}-\frac{\alpha_{j}}{m_{j}}\right] . \end{array} $$

    Since αimjαjmi = nβ (mjmi) by definition of αr = mr + β (nmr), it follows that

    $$ \tilde{p}_{i}=\tilde{p}_{j}+\frac{m_{i}-m_{j}}{m_{i}m_{j}}\cdot \frac{ 1-\gamma n\beta }{\left( 1-\beta \right) }. $$
    (A1)

    Then, mi > mj implies \(\tilde {p}_{i}>\tilde {p}_{j},\) since

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} 1 &=&\frac{kn\beta^{2}}{kn\beta^{2}}\geq \frac{n\beta^{2}}{k\beta +\left( 1-\beta \right) }\cdot \frac{k}{n\beta }\\ &=&\frac{n\beta^{2}}{1+\left( k-1\right) \beta }\cdot \sum \limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{1}{n\beta } \\ &\geq &\frac{n\beta^{2}}{1+\left( k-1\right) \beta }\!\cdot\! \sum \limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{1}{n\beta +\left( 1-\beta \right) m_{r}} = \gamma n\beta . \end{array} $$
  2. 2.

    Expected payoff is \({\Pi }_{r}^{\ast }=\tilde {p}_{r}\tilde {x}_{r}^{\ast } \) by definition. Using Eq. (2), it follows that \({\Pi }_{i}^{\ast }>{\Pi }_{j}^{\ast }\Leftrightarrow \tilde {p}_{i}\alpha _{j}>\tilde {p}_{j}\alpha _{i}\). From Eq. (A1), we can conclude that

    $$ \tilde{p}_{i}\alpha_{j}=\tilde{p}_{j}\alpha_{j}+\frac{m_{i}-m_{j}}{ m_{i}m_{j}}\cdot \frac{1-\gamma n\beta }{\left( 1-\beta \right) }\alpha_{j}. $$

    Since αj = αi −(1 − β) (mimj), it follows that

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \tilde{p}_{i}\alpha_{j}\!&>&\!\tilde{p}_{j}\alpha_{i}\Leftrightarrow \left( m_{i}-m_{j}\right)\\ &&\!\times\left[ \frac{\alpha_{j}}{m_{i}m_{j}}\cdot \frac{1-\gamma n\beta }{\left( 1-\beta \right) }-\tilde{p}_{j}\left( 1-\beta \right) \right] \!>\!0. \end{array} $$

    Since mi > mj, the proposition follows.

Proof of Corollary 1

To see the first part, note that the overall effective investments \(\tilde {X}^{^{\ast }}\)tend to zero if the external spillover rate tends to one, for

$$ \lim \limits_{\beta \rightarrow 1}\quad \left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}}{ \alpha_{r}}\right) =\left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}}{n}\right) =1. $$

In fact, the actors’ effective investments in this case are similar to a grand network (1;n).

To see the second part of the corollary, note that according to Eq. (3) and Proposition 2, the optimal effective investment \(\tilde {x}_{i}^{\ast }\) and the optimal investment \(x_{i}^{\ast }\) for β = 0 are given by

$$ \tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }=\frac{V}{m_{i}}\cdot \frac{k-1}{k^{2}}\quad \text{ and\quad }x_{i}^{\ast }=\frac{V}{{m_{i}^{2}}}\cdot \frac{k-1}{k^{2}}. $$

Hence,

$$ p_{i}^{\ast }=\frac{\tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }}{\tilde{X}^{\ast }}=\frac{\frac{V}{ m_{i}}\cdot \frac{k-1}{k^{2}}}{V\cdot \frac{k-1}{k}}=\frac{1}{m_{i}k}, $$

and expected payoff in equilibrium is

$$ {\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }=V\cdot p_{i}^{\ast }-x_{i}^{\ast }=V\cdot \frac{km_{i}-k+1}{ k^{2}{m_{i}^{2}}}. $$

Note that \(x_{i}^{\ast }\) and \(p_{i}^{\ast }\) are decreasing in the size mi of the network and in the number k of competing networks. Moreover, according to Proposition 3, a bigger network Ni is more profitable than a smaller network Nj iff

$$ m_{i}<\frac{m_{j}\cdot \left( k-1\right) }{1+k\cdot \left( m_{j}-1\right) }. $$

Proof of Proposition 4

Suppose the grand network {N} has been formed in equilibrium leading to a network structure (1;n). As we already know, an entrepreneurial actor’s payoff in equilibrium is given by

$$ {\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( 1;n\right) =\frac{1}{n}. $$

To show that (1;n) is not an equilibrium network structure, consider an entrepreneurial actor i’s payoff if it unilaterally decides not to participate in the grand network. Using the characterization of equilibrium payoffs, actor i’s payoff is

$$ {\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( 2;n-1,1\right) =\frac{n^{3}\beta +2n^{2}\beta^{2}-3n^{2}\beta +n^{2}-4n\beta^{2}+6n\beta -2n+3\beta^{2}-4\beta +1}{ \left( 2n+2\beta -2n\beta +n^{2}\beta -2\right)^{2}}. $$

Then, \({\Pi }_{i}^{\ast }\left (2;n-1,1\right ) >{\Pi }_{i}^{\ast }\left (1;n\right ) \) if

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&-\left( 1-\beta \right) \left( n-1\right) \left( \beta \left( 7n+n^{3}-5n^{2}-4\right) \right.\\ &&\left. +\left( n-1\right) \left( n-4\right) \vphantom{n^{3}}\right) <0 \end{array} $$

For n = 3, the LHS of this inequality is positive and equal to 2 (1 − β) (β + 2). For n > 3, the LHS is negative since (7n + n3 − 5n2 − 4) and increasing in n. Hence, the grand coalition is only an equilibrium structure for n = 3. If n > 3, a single actor profits from a deviation.

Consider now partition {1,...,1} in which all actors form degenerated networks and the network structure is (n;1,...,1). The equilibrium payoff of an entrepreneurial actor i is then given by

$$ {\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( n;1,...,1\right) =\frac{\beta n^{2}-\beta +1}{ n^{2}\left( n\beta -\beta +1\right) }. $$

Suppose that actor i unilaterally decides to form a network with some other actor \(j\in \mathbb {N} \). Using the characterization of equilibrium payoffs for mi = 2, mj = 1 for ji, actor i’s payoff is

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&{\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( n-1;2,1...,1\right) \\ &=&\frac{\left( n\beta -\beta +1\right) \left( n\beta -\beta +2\right) }{2\left( 2n+2\beta -2n\beta +n^{2}\beta -2\right)^{2}}\frac{A}{B}. \end{array} $$
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} && \text{with } A:=\left( \begin{array}{c} 2n^{4}\beta^{3}-10n^{3}\beta^{3}+8n^{3}\beta^{2}+21n^{2}\beta^{3}-30n^{2}\beta^{2}+9n^{2}\beta -23n\beta^{3} \\ +42n\beta^{2}-21n\beta +2n+10\beta^{3}-24\beta^{2}+14\beta \end{array} \right)\\ &&\text{and } B:=\left( n^{3}\beta^{3}-4n^{2}\beta^{3}+4n^{2}\beta^{2}+5n\beta^{3}-11n\beta^{2}+5n\beta -2\beta^{3}+7\beta^{2}-7\beta +2\right). \end{array} $$

Tedious calculations then show that

$$ {\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( n-1;2,1...,1\right) >{\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( n;1...,1\right) $$

is always satisfied. □

Proof of Corollary 2

We prove the corollary in three steps: In Step 1, we ask under which circumstances a single actor has an incentive to participate in a network of size mi. As we will see, this sets an upper bound on the maximal size of a network to be more profitable than a non-cooperating actor. In Step 2, we argue that in equilibrium there can only exist networks whose sizes differ by one member. In Step 3, we then determine the equilibrium network structure in the open membership game.

  1. 1.

    Consider an network structure (k;m1,1,m3 ,...mk) , k ≥ 2, with m1 actors in network N1 and one actor i in network N2 = {i}. Then, actor i has an incentive to join the network N1 if

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&{\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( k-1;m_{1},m_{3},...m_{k}\right)\\ &>&{\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( k;m_{1},1,m_{3},...m_{k}\right) ,\text{ that is, if} \\ &&\frac{\left( k-1\right) \left( m_{1}+1\right) -\left( k-1\right) +1}{\left( k-1\right)^{2}\left( m_{1}+1\right)^{2}}\\&>&\frac{1}{k^{2}}. \end{array} $$

    Simple calculation then shows that this inequality is satisfied as long as

    $$ m_{1}<\frac{k}{2\left( k-1\right) }\left( k+\sqrt{\left( k^{2}-4k+8\right) } \right) -1. $$

    If k = 2, this equality reduces to m1 < 3. Hence, there could only be three actors in the environment, n = 3. Since n > 3 by assumption, k > 2, the maximal size m1 which satisfies this inequality is m1 = k − 1, since

    $$ k-1\!<\!\frac{k}{2\left( k - 1\right) }\left( k + \sqrt{\left( k^{2} - 4k + 8\right) } \right) -\!1\!\iff\! 4\!<\!8 $$

    and

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} k&>&\frac{k}{2\left( k-1\right) }\left( k + \sqrt{\left( k^{2}-4k + 8\right) } \right) - 1\!\iff\! 1\\ &>&k^{2}\left( 3-k\right) \end{array} $$

    for mi = k > 2. Hence, as long as m1k − 1, a non-cooperating actor always has an incentive to join the network N1. As a consequence, an equilibrium network structure has to satisfy this property, since otherwise actors in a network with size greater than k − 1 would be better off by not participating in this network.

  2. 2.

    Consider an equilibrium network structure (k;m1, m2, m3,...mk) , k ≥ 2, with m1 actors in network N1 and m2 actors in network N2. Suppose that m2 > m1 ≥ 2. Note that a switch in membership between network N1 and N2 does not affect the total number of networks, so k remains unchanged. Since the equilibrium payoff of an entrepreneurial actor is decreasing in the size of network it is a member of,

    $$ \frac{\partial {\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }}{\partial m_{i}}<0, $$

    the members of the larger network N2 then have an incentive to switch to the smaller network N1. This is profitable as long as m1 + 1 < m2.

  3. 3.

    Steps 1 and 2 imply that there can only be equilibrium network structures for which either all networks are of identical size m > 1, or some networks have size m > 2 while the others have size m− 1. Moreover, if \(k_{1}^{\ast }\) denotes the number of networks of size m and \(k_{2}^{\ast }\) the number of networks of size m− 1. Then,

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} m^{\ast }k_{1}^{\ast }+\left( m^{\ast }-1\right) k_{2}^{\ast } &=&n\text{ and } \\ k_{1}^{\ast }+k_{2}^{\ast }-1 &\geq &m^{\ast }. \end{array} $$

Proof of Corollary 3

Let (k;m1, m2, m3,...mk) be an equilibrium network structure in the exclusive membership game for β = 0. To prove the corollary we proceed in three steps: In Step 1, we show that if all actors in network Ni have an outstanding invitation for another non-member actor jNi, the equilibrium network structure remains unchanged and, vice versa, if a non-member actor jNi asks for membership in Ni, this is not in the interest of the member actors. We can therefore restrict attention to equilibrium network structures where no actor in network Ni has an incentive to announce a list which excludes one member actor jNi. In Step 2, we ask under which circumstances a member of a network of size mi ≥ 4 has no incentives to do so. As we will see, this sets a lower bound on the maximal size of a network to be more profitable with mi instead of mi − 1 actors. In Step 3, we consider the same question for the remaining cases mi = 2 and mi = 3. In Step 4, we then determine the equilibrium network structure in the exclusive membership game.

  1. 1.

    Consider first the case in which in equilibrium all members of a network Ni with size mi have an outstanding invitation for another actor jNj. (k;m1, m2, m3,...mk) then is an equilibrium if actor jNi has no incentive to join this network. If 1 < mj < mi, the number of networks remains constant and π/m < 0 ensures that actor j indeed is not willing to switch to the bigger network. If mj = 1, the number of networks reduces to k − 1 and, according to Step 1 in the proof of Corollary 2, actor j has an incentive to join Ni if mik − 1. However, (k;m1, m2, m3,...mk) is then still an equilibrium network structure if one actor in Ni drops actor j from her list of announcements. This requires

    $$ \frac{\left( k+1\right) \left( m_{i}+1\right) -\left( k+1\right) +1}{\left( k+1\right)^{2}\left( m_{i}+1\right)^{2}}<\frac{k\left( m_{i}-1\right) +1}{ k^{2}{m_{i}^{2}}}. $$

    Since the term on the left side of this inequality is decreasing in mi,

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\frac{\left( k+1\right) \left( m_{i}+1\right) -\left( k+1\right) +1}{\left( k+1\right)^{2}\left( m_{i}+1\right)^{2}}\\ &<&\frac{\left( k+1\right) m_{i}-\left( k+1\right) +1}{\left( k+1\right)^{2}{m_{i}^{2}}}. \end{array} $$

    But

    $$ \frac{\left( k+1\right) m_{i}-\left( k+1\right) +1}{\left( k+1\right)^{2}{m_{i}^{2}}}<\frac{k\left( m_{i}-1\right) +1}{k^{2}{m_{i}^{2}}} $$

    since − k2 (m1 − 1) − k (m1 + 1) − 1 < 0.

  2. 2.

    Consider now a network structure (k;m1, m2, m3,...mk) , k ≥ 2, with m1 ≥ 4 actors in network N1. Then an entrepreneurial actor in network N1 has an incentive to exclude one member of her network if

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&{\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( k+1;1;m_{1}-1,m_{2},m_{3},...m_{k}\right) \\ &>&{\Pi}_{i}^{\ast }\left( k;m_{1},m_{2},m_{3},...m_{k}\right) , \end{array} $$

    that is, if

    $$ \frac{\left( k+1\right) \left( m_{1}-1\right) -k}{\left( k+1\right)^{2}\left( m_{1}-1\right)^{2}}\geq \frac{k\left( m_{1}-1\right) +1}{ k^{2}{m_{1}^{2}}}. $$

    Since m1 ≥ 4 by assumption, the minimal number k of networks which satisfies this inequality is k = m1 + 1, since for k = m1:

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\frac{\left( m_{1}+1\right) \left( m_{1}-1\right) -m}{\left( m_{1}+1\right)^{2}\left( m_{1}-1\right)^{2}}-\frac{m_{1}\left( m_{1}-1\right) +1}{{m_{1}^{4}}} \\ &=&-\frac{\left( m_{1}+1\right) \left( m_{1}-1\right)^{2}+{m_{1}^{3}}}{ {m_{1}^{4}}\left( {m_{1}^{2}}-1\right)^{2}}<0, \end{array} $$

    and for k = m1 + 1 it holds that

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\frac{\left( m_{1}+2\right) \left( m_{1}-1\right) -\left( m_{1}+1\right) }{ \left( m_{1}+2\right)^{2}\left( m_{1}-1\right)^{2}}\\ &&-\frac{\left( m_{1}+1\right) \left( m_{1}-1\right) +1}{\left( m_{1}+1\right)^{2}{m_{1}^{2}}} \\ &=&\frac{\left( m_{1}-1\right)^{2}-8}{\left( m_{1}-1\right)^{2}\left( m_{1}+2\right)^{2}\left( m_{1}+1\right)^{2}}>0 \end{array} $$

    for mi ≥ 4. Hence, as soon as km1 + 1, a member of network N1 has an incentive to exclude another actor in N1.Footnote 29

  3. 3.

    Consider finally the case of a network structure (k;m1, m2, m3,...mk) , with m1 ∈ {2,3} actors in network N1. Using the inequality from Step 1, an entrepreneurial actor in network N1 has an incentive to exclude a member of this network for m1 = 3, if k ≥ 6 since

    $$ \frac{2\left( k+1\right) -k}{4\left( k+1\right)^{2}}-\frac{2k+1}{9k^{2}}= \frac{k^{3}-2k^{2}-16k-4}{36k^{2}\left( k+1\right)^{2}}>0. $$

    Moreover, for m1 = 2

    $$ \frac{\left( k+1\right) -k}{\left( k+1\right)^{2}}-\frac{k+1}{4k^{2}}=- \frac{k^{3}-k^{2}+3k+1}{4k^{2}\left( k+1\right)^{2}}<0 $$

    for all k ≥ 2.

  4. 4.

    Steps 2 and 3 imply that a network structure (k;m1, m2, m3,...mk) forms in equilibrium in the exclusive membership game if for all networks k < mi + 1 if mi ≥ 4 or k ≤ 5 if mi = 3. The first condition ensures that each actor in a network Ni with mi ≥ 4 has no interest to exclude another actor if k < mi + 1 according to Step 2. The second property follows from Step 3 for the case m1 = 3.

Proof of Proposition 5

Define

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} A&=&\left( \begin{array}{cccc} m_{1} & \beta_{2}m_{2} & {\ldots} & \beta_{k}m_{k} \\ \beta_{1}m_{1} & m_{2} & {\ldots} & \beta_{k}m_{k} \\ {\vdots} & {\vdots} & {\ddots} & {\vdots} \\ \beta_{1}m_{1} & \beta_{2}m_{2} & {\ldots} & m_{k} \end{array} \right) \ \text{and }\\ B_{i}&=&\left( \begin{array}{ccccc} m_{1} & {\ldots} & \tilde{x}_{1}^{\ast } & {\ldots} & \beta_{k}m_{k} \\ \beta_{1}m_{1} & {\ldots} & \tilde{x}_{2}^{\ast } & {\ldots} & \beta_{k}m_{k} \\ {\vdots} & {\vdots} & {\vdots} & {\vdots} & {\vdots} \\ \beta_{1}m_{1} & {\ldots} & \tilde{x}_{k}^{\ast } & {\ldots} & m_{k} \end{array} \right) \end{array} $$

as in the proof of Proposition 2. Induction over r = 1,…k then shows that the determinants of A and Bi are

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \text{det }A \!&=&\!\prod \limits_{r=1}^{k}m_{r}\cdot \left( \displaystyle\sum \limits_{j=0}^{k}\left( -1\right)^{k-1-j}\left( k-1-j\right) \right.\\ &&\left. P_{k-j}\left( \beta_{1},...,\beta_{k}\right) \vphantom{\displaystyle\sum \limits_{j=0}^{k}}\right) \\ \text{det }B_{i} \!&=&\!\prod \limits_{r=1,r\neq i}^{k}m_{r}\!\cdot \left( \tilde{x }_{i}^{\ast }\left( \displaystyle\sum \limits_{j=0}^{k-1}\left( -1\right)^{k-2-j}\left( k - 2 - j\right)\right.\right.\\ && \left.\left. P_{k-1-j}\left( \beta_{1},...,\beta_{i-1},\beta_{i+1},...,\beta_{k}\right) \vphantom{\sum \limits_{j=0}^{k-1}}\right) \right. \\ &&\left. -\displaystyle\sum \limits_{j=1,j\neq i}^{k}\tilde{x}_{j}^{\ast }\beta_{j}\displaystyle\prod \limits_{r=1,r\neq i,j}^{k}\left( 1-\beta_{r}\right) \right) . \end{array} $$

Let αr = βrn + (1 − βr) mr. Since the first-order conditions for a Nash equilibrium imply that \(\tilde {x} _{j}^{\ast }\alpha _{j}=\tilde {x}_{i}^{\ast }\alpha _{i}\), the optimal investments according to Cramer’s Rule are given by

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} x_{i}^{\ast } &=&\frac{1}{m_{i}\left( \displaystyle\sum \limits_{j=0}^{k}\left( -1\right)^{k-1-j}\left( k-1-j\right) P_{k-j}\left( \beta_{1},...,\beta_{k}\right) \right) } \\ &&\cdot\left( \left( \displaystyle\sum \limits_{j=0}^{k-1}\left( -1\right)^{k-2-j}\left( k-2-j\right) P_{k-1-j}\right.\right.\\ &&\times\left.\left. \left( \beta_{1},...,\beta_{i-1},\beta_{i+1},...,\beta_{k}\right) \vphantom{\sum \limits_{j=0}^{k-1}}\right) \right. \\ &&\left. -\displaystyle\sum \limits_{j=1,j\neq i}^{k}\frac{\alpha_{i}}{\alpha_{j}} \beta_{j}\displaystyle\prod \limits_{r=1,r\neq i,j}^{k}\left( 1-\beta_{r}\right) \right) \tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }. \end{array} $$

and the proposition follows. □

Proof of Proposition 6

Similar to the argumentation in Section 4, the individual and overall effective investments are given in equilibrium by

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \tilde{X}^{\ast }&=&\alpha_{i}\tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }\cdot \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{ m_{r}}{\alpha_{r}}\text{ and }\tilde{x}_{i}^{\ast }\\ &=&\frac{V}{\alpha_{i}} \cdot \frac{\left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}}{\alpha_{r}}\right) -1}{\left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}}{\alpha_{r}}\right)^{2}} \end{array} $$

where αr = βrn + (1 − βr) mr. Using the result of Proposition 5, the equilibrium payoff of an actor in network i reads as

$$ {\Pi}_{i}=\frac{V}{\alpha_{i}\sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}}{\alpha_{r}}}\left( 1-\frac{\left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}}{\alpha_{r}}\right) -1}{\left( \sum\limits_{r=1}^{k}\frac{m_{r}}{\alpha_{r}}\right) \left( \displaystyle\sum\limits_{j=0}^{k}\left( -1\right)^{k-1-j}\left( k-1-j\right) P_{k-j}\left( \beta_{1},...,\beta_{k}\right) \right) }{\Psi}_{i}\right) $$

with

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {\Psi}_{i}&=&\displaystyle\sum \limits_{j=0}^{k-1}\left( -1\right)^{k-2-j}\left( k-2-j\right) P_{k-1-j}\\ &&\times\left( \beta_{1},...,\beta_{i-1},\beta_{i+1},...,\beta_{k}\right)\\ &&-\displaystyle\sum \limits_{j=1,j\neq i}^{k}\frac{\alpha_{i}}{\alpha_{j}}\beta_{j}\displaystyle\prod \limits_{r=1,r\neq i,j}^{k}\left( 1-\beta_{r}\right) . \end{array} $$

To show that \(\left (\beta _{1}^{\ast },...,\beta _{k}^{\ast }\right ) =\left (0,....,0\right ) \) is an equilibrium in spillover rates, consider the marginal payoff of an actor in network i, given all other networks choose βr = 0. Since Ψi = 0 for (β1,..,βi,..,βk) = (0,..,βi,..,0), it follows that

$$ \left. \frac{\partial }{\partial \beta_{i}}{\Pi}_{i}\right\vert_{\left( 0,..,\beta_{i},..,0\right) }=\frac{\partial }{\partial \beta_{i}}\left( \frac{V}{m_{i}+\alpha_{i}\left( k-1\right) }\right) <0, $$

and \(\beta _{i}^{\ast }=0\) is a best response for network i. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jost, PJ. Endogenous formation of entrepreneurial networks. Small Bus Econ 56, 39–64 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00199-w

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-019-00199-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation