Skip to main content
Log in

Growth and entrepreneurship

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we suggest that the spillover of knowledge may not occur automatically as typically assumed in models of endogenous growth. Rather, a mechanism is required to serve as a conduit for the spillover and commercialization of knowledge from the source creating it, to the firms actually commercializing the new ideas. In this paper, entrepreneurship is identified as one such mechanism facilitating the spillover of knowledge. Using a panel of entrepreneurship data from 18 countries, we provide empirical evidence that, in addition to measures of Research & Development and human capital, entrepreneurial activity also serves to promote economic growth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Rostow (1990) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) for a survey. See also Kaldor (1961) and Denison (1967).

  2. As, for example, Grossman and Helpman (1991) have shown, the new varieties of capital goods can just as well be thought of as new varieties of goods entering consumers’ utility functions directly.

  3. A certain level of entrepreneurial activities will always be profitable (L E  > 0), while R&D may or may not be profitable, depending in a non-trivial way on a range of parameters. The degree of entrepreneurial activity, for instance, decreases in the productivity of R&D as long as R&D is profitable. Thus, R&D and entrepreneurship are to some extent substitutes.

  4. The dummy variable for one country is left out, i.e., the control country.

  5. As Storey (2003) shows in his rich review of the literature, there have been a large number of studies linking unemployment to entrepreneurship.

  6. For a more detailed description of heteroscedastic and autocorrelation consistent variance (HAC), see, for example, Cushing and McGarvey (1999) or Wooldridge (2002).

  7. This has been done with all the two-stage least squares results, with the same conclusion.

  8. Test statistics can be supplied upon request.

References

  • Acs, Z. J., Audretsch, D. B., Braunerhjelm, P., & Carlsson, B. (2004) The missing link: The knowledge filter and entrepreneurship in economic growth. CEPR working paper no. 4358. London, UK: Center for Economic and Policy Research

  • Acs, Z. J., Audretsch, D. B., Braunerhjelm, P., & Carlsson, B. (2005) Growth and entrepreneurship: an empirical assessment. CERP working paper no. 5409, London, UK.

  • Agarwal, R., Audretsch, D. B., & Sarkar, M. B. (2007). The process of creative construction: Knowledge spillovers entrepreneurship and economic growth. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 1(3–4), 263–286. doi:10.1002/sej.36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1962). The economic implication of learning by doing. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80, 155–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B. (2007). Entrepreneurship capital and economic growth. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 23(1), 63–78. doi:10.1093/oxrep/grm001.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Keilbach, M. (2007). The theory of knowledge spillover entrepreneurship. Journal of Management Studies, 44, 1242–1254. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6486.2007.00722.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B., & Keilbach, M. (2008). Resolving the knowledge paradox: Knowledge-spillover entrepreneurship and economic growth. Research Policy, 37(10), 1697–1705. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2008.08.008.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995). Economic growth. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Block, J., Thurik A. R., & Zhou, H. (2009). What turns knowledge into innovative products? The role of entrepreneurship and knowledge spillovers. Erasmus Research Institute of Management (ERIM) report series reference no. ERS-2009-049-ORG. Rotterdam: ERIM

  • Braunerhjelm, P., Acs, Z. A., Audretsch, D. B., & Carlsson, B. (2010). The missing link: Knowledge diffusion and entrepreneurship in endogenous growth. Small Business Economics, 34(2), 105–125. doi:10.1007/s11187-009-9235-1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiang, A. (1992) Elements of dynamic optimization. New York: McGraw-Hill.

  • Cushing, M. J., & McGarvey, M. G. (1999). Covariance matrix estimation. In L. Matyas (Ed.), Generalized methods of moments estimation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, R., & MacKinnon, J.G. (1993) Estimation and inference in econometrics. New York: Oxford University Press. 1993

  • De Clerq, D., Hessels, J., & Van Stel, A. (2007). Knowledge spillovers and entrepreneurs’ export orientation. ERIM report series reference no. ERS-2007-038-ORG. Rotterdam: ERIM

  • Denison, E. F. (1967). Why growth rates differ. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, Oxford and New York: University Press.

  • Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1991). Innovation and growth in the global economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1961). Capital accumulation and economic growth. In F. A. Lutz & D. C. Hague (Eds.), The theory of capital. London: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mills, D. E., & Schuman, L. (1985). Industry structure with fluctuating demand. American Economic Review, 75, 758–767.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (Organization for European Economic Co-operation) (2002). Statistical compendium on CD. Paris: OECD

  • Parker, S. (2004). The economics of entrepreneurshsip and self-employment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1986). Increasing returns and economic growth. American Economic Review, 94, 1002–1037.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1990). Endogenous technical change. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 71–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rostow, W. (1990). Socialism and democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, R. (1956). A contribution to theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70, 65–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storey, D. (2003) Entrepreneurship, small and medium sized enterprises and public policies. In Z. J. Acs & D. Audretsch (Eds.). Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research (pp. 473–514). Boston: Kluwer.

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Financial support from the Marianne and Marcus Wallenberg’s Foundation is gratefully acknowledged. Excellent research assistance has been provided by Benny Borgman, The Royal Institute of Technology.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David B. Audretsch.

Appendix

Appendix

Entrepreneurs and researchers engage in knowledge production in order to develop a new variety of a differentiated capital good that is used in final production. Different varieties of capital goods compete in a monopolistic competition fashion, meaning that they never become obsolete and earn an infinite stream of profits. As a side effect of their efforts, researchers and entrepreneurs produce new knowledge that will be publicly available for use in future capital good development. Equation A1.1 describes the production of new knowledge, i.e., the evolution of the stock of knowledge, in relation to resources channelled into R&D (L R ) and entrepreneurial activity (L E ).

$$ {\frac{{\dot{A}}}{A}} = \sigma_{R} L_{R} + \sigma_{E} Z\left( {L_{E} } \right) $$
(A1.1)

Entrepreneurial activities take the following form

$$ Z\left( {L_{E} } \right) = L_{E}^{\gamma } ,\gamma < 1 $$
(A1.2)

Production of final goods (Y) takes place using labour and different varieties of capital-goods:

$$ Y = L_{m}^{\alpha } \int\limits_{0}^{A} {x(i)^{1 - \alpha } di} $$
(A1.3)

Given the symmetry of different varieties in (A1.3), demand for all varieties in equilibrium is symmetric, i.e., \( x_{i} = \bar{x} \) for all i ≤ A. We therefore rewrite (A1.3) as

$$ Y = L_{m}^{\alpha } A\bar{x}^{1 - \alpha } $$
(A1.4)

Assume that capital goods are produced with the same technology as final goods and that it takes K units of capital goods to produce one unit of capital (see, for example, Chiang 1992). Then it can be shown that

$$ K = \kappa A\bar{x} $$
(A1.5)

(A1.4), and (A1.5) then gives

$$ Y = L_{m}^{\alpha } A^{\alpha } K^{1 - \alpha } \kappa^{\alpha - 1} $$
(A1.6)

Labour market equilibrium implies that employment in R&D, entrepreneurship and final production equal total labor supply.

$$ L = L_{m} + L_{R} + L_{E} $$
(A1.7)

Finally, we assume that consumer preferences can be described by constant elasticity utility

$$ U\left( C \right) = {\frac{{C^{1 - \theta } }}{1 - \theta }} $$
(A1.8)

We form the Hamiltonian for the representative consumer

$$ H_{C} = {\frac{{C^{1 - \theta } }}{1 - \theta }} + \lambda_{A} \left( {\sigma_{R} L_{R} A + \sigma_{E} L_{E}^{\gamma } A} \right) + \lambda_{K} \left( {\kappa^{\alpha - 1} A^{\alpha } K^{1 - \alpha } \left( {L - L_{R} - L_{E} } \right) - C} \right) $$
(A1.9)

Maximizing (A1.9) gives the first-order conditions

$$ \lambda_{K} = C^{ - \theta } \to {\frac{{\dot{\lambda }_{K} }}{{\lambda_{K} }}} = - \theta {\frac{{\dot{C}}}{C}} $$
(A1.10)
$$ \Updelta = {\frac{{\lambda_{A} \sigma_{R} A}}{{\lambda_{K} \alpha }}}\left( {L - L_{R} - L_{E} } \right) $$
(A1.11)
$$ \Updelta = {\frac{{\lambda_{A} \gamma \sigma_{E} L_{E}^{\gamma - 1} A}}{{\lambda_{K} \alpha }}}\left( {L - L_{R} - L_{E} } \right) $$
(A1.12)

where \( \Updelta = \left( {\kappa^{\alpha - 1} A^{\alpha } K^{1 - \alpha } \left( {L - L_{R} - L_{E} } \right)} \right) \). Combining (A1.11) and (A1.12) gives

$$ L_{E} = \left( {{\frac{{\sigma_{R} }}{{\gamma \sigma_{E} }}}} \right)^{{{\frac{1}{\gamma - 1}}}} $$
(A1.13)

Thus, on a balanced growth path, where both R&D and entrepreneurship is profitable, the amount of resources engaged in entrepreneurial activities is independent of consumer preferences. As γ is less than 1, entry into entrepreneurship is increasing in σ E and decreasing in σ R . The maximization of (A1.9) also gives the equations of motion for the shadow prices of knowledge and capital as

$$ {\frac{{\dot{\lambda }_{K} }}{{\lambda_{K} }}} = - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)K^{ - 1} \Updelta + \rho $$
(A1.14)
$$ {\frac{{\dot{\lambda }_{A} }}{{\lambda_{A} }}} = - \sigma_{R} L_{0} - \sigma_{E} L_{E}^{\gamma } + \sigma_{R} L_{E} + \rho $$
(A1.15)

where ρ denotes the subjective discount rate (rate of time preferences). On the balanced growth, knowledge, final production and consumption all grow at the same rate, while \( {\frac{{\dot{\lambda }_{K} }}{{\lambda_{K} }}} = {\frac{{\dot{\lambda }_{A} }}{{\lambda_{A} }}} \). Combining (A1.10) and (A1.15) gives

$$ L_{R} = {\frac{1}{{\theta \sigma_{R} }}}\left( {\sigma_{R} \left( {L_{0} - L_{E} } \right) + \left( {1 - \theta } \right)\sigma_{E} L_{E}^{\gamma } - \rho } \right) $$
(A1.16)

Combining (A1.16) with (A1.13) and (A1.1) gives

$$ g = {\frac{1}{\theta }}\left( {\left( {\sigma_{R} L - \rho } \right) - \sigma_{R}^{\gamma } \gamma^{\gamma - 1} \sigma_{{_{E} }}^{\gamma - 1} + \sigma_{{_{E} }}^{{{\frac{2\gamma - 1}{\gamma }}}} \gamma^{{{\frac{\gamma - 1}{\gamma }}}} \sigma_{{_{R} }}^{{{\frac{\gamma }{\gamma - 1}}}} } \right) $$
(A1.17)

where it can be shown that the growth rate is increasing in \( L,\sigma_{R} {\text{ and }}\sigma_{E} . \) but decreasing in ρ. It should be noted that (A1.17) only applies when both R&D and entrepreneurship is profitable. The given specification implies that some entrepreneurial activity will always be profitable as long as A > 0. This does not apply to R&D activities however. If R&D is not sufficiently profitable (following from A1.16), then we can combine (A1.10), (A1.12), (A1.14) and (A1.15) to derive the reduced-form growth rate. However, the resulting expression provides few new insights and is not shown here.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Acs, Z.J., Audretsch, D.B., Braunerhjelm, P. et al. Growth and entrepreneurship. Small Bus Econ 39, 289–300 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-010-9307-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-010-9307-2

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation