Skip to main content
Log in

Does venture opportunity variation matter? Investigating systematic process differences between innovative and imitative new ventures

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The central thesis in the article is that the venture creation process is different for innovative versus imitative ventures. This holds up; the pace of the process differs by type of venture as do, in line with theory-based hypotheses, the effects of certain human capital (HC) and social capital (SC) predictors. Importantly, and somewhat unexpectedly, the theoretically derived models using HC, SC, and certain controls are relatively successful explaining progress in the creation process for the minority of innovative ventures, but achieve very limited success for the imitative majority. This may be due to a rationalistic bias in conventional theorizing and suggests that there is need for considerable theoretical development regarding the important phenomenon of new venture creation processes. Another important result is that the building up of instrumental social capital, which we assess comprehensively and as a time variant construct, is important for making progress with both types of ventures, and increasingly, so as the process progresses. This result corroborates with stronger operationalization and more appropriate analysis method what previously published research has only been able to hint at.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The embryonic entity around which a new venture evolves is often referred to as ‘the opportunity’ in the extant literature (see, e.g., de Koning 2003; Dimov 2004; Gaglio 1997; Sarasvathy et al. 2003; Shane 2000; Shane and Venkataraman 2000). We here refrain from using that term to denote the emerging entity under study. This is in order to avoid its inherent positive bias as well as any debate as to whether ‘opportunities’ are ‘discovered’ or ‘created’. The entities we refer to are creations of individuals’ minds. They may or may not reflect favorable external conditions, and they may or may not evolve into commercially successful ventures. The labels we here favor for these entities are ‘venture idea’ and ‘(emerging) venture’.

  2. Eligible respondents were also re-interviewed after 24 and 75 months, respectively. However, most of the variation in our dependent variable occurred during the first 18 months. For this reason as well as concerns for the size of the analysable sample, we restrict the analyses in this article to the first four waves of data collection (0, 6, 12, and 18 months).

  3. These stricter criteria applied in arrears to the 622 cases interviewed are as follows. For a minimum, at least two ‘gestation activities’ had to be completed (cf. Reynolds 1997, 2000). Cases were excluded as over qualified (already up and running) if all three of the following were met: (a) money had been invested, and (b) revenues had been received, and (c) the venture was registered as a legal entity. In order to further homogenize the sample, cases that had already completed more than 15 ‘gestation activities’ at the time of the first interview were also excluded (i.e., 50% of the possible maximum number of such behaviors).

  4. The application of statistical significance testing can also be rationalized as follows. One could imagine that a census study exactly like ours had been undertaken instead, applying exactly the same researcher- and respondent-induced criteria for inclusion in the final sample. Our sample should be probabilistically representative for that sub-population of emerging new ventures in Sweden at the time of our study. We hold that making statistical inferences to this no doubt sizeable population is a theoretically and practically relevant exercise.

  5. Formally this is shown by the confidence interval for the difference in coefficient magnitude being 2.65 ± (1.96 × 0.87), i.e., not including the value zero.

  6. While the significance test as performed is not strictly valid because of statistical dependence between the estimates it should be noted that disregarding any requirements for magnitude of the difference the joint probability of a random number generator generating four monotonically increasing numbers in each of two separate series is (1 × 0.5 × 0.5 × 0.5) × (1 × 0.5 × 0.5 × 0.5) = 0.016 (<0.05), so the result is statistically significant based also on such a simple run test.

References

  • Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1997). A Schumpeterian perspective on growth and competition. In D. Kreps (Ed.), Advances in economics and econometrics, invited lecture to the 7th World Congress of the Econometrics Society.

  • Aldrich, H. E. (1999). Organizations evolving. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, H. E., & Auster, E. R. (1986). Even dwarfs started small: Liabilities of age and size and their strategic implications. In B. M. Staw & L. L. Cummings (Eds.), Research in Organizational Behavior (Vol. 8, pp. 165–198). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, H., & Fiol, M. (1994). Fools rush in: The institutional context of industry creation. Academy of Management Review, 19/4, 645–670.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, H. E., & Kenworthy, A. (1999). The accidental entrepreneur: Cambellian antinomies and organizational foundings. In J. A. Baum & B. McKelvey (Eds.), Variations in organizational science: In honor of Donald T. Campbell (pp. 19–33). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, H. E., & Martinez, M. E. (2001). Many are called but few are chosen: an evolutionary perspective for the study of entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurship Theory & Practice, 25(4, Summer), 41–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. R. (1990). Cognitive psychology and its implications. New York: Freeman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, P., & Tushman, M. (1990). Technological discontinuities and dominant designs: a cyclical model of technological change. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 604–633.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. The rate and direction of inventive activity: Economic and social factors: A conference of the Universities-National Bureau Committee for Economic Research and the Committee on Economic Growth of the Social Science Research Council (pp. 609–626). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1974). The limits of organizations. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D., & Fritsch, M. (1994). The geography of firm births in Germany. Regional Studies, 28(4), 359–365.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bandura, A. (1982). Self-efficacy mechanism in human agency. American Psychologist, 37, 122–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bamford, C. H., Dean, T. J., & McDougall, P. P. (1999). An examination of the impact on initial founding conditions and decision upon the performance of new bank start-ups. Journal of Business Venturing, 15, 253–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barney, J. B. (1997). Gaining and sustaining competitive advantage. Menlo Park: Addison Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1964). Human capital. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bedeian, A. G., & Zammuto, R. F. (1991). Organizations: Theory and design. Chicago: Dryden Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boeker, W. P. (1988). Organizational origins: Entrepreneurial and environmental imprinting at the time of founding. In G. R. Carroll & A. H. Hawley (Eds.), Ecological models of organizations. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1983). Forms of capital. In J. Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education (pp. 241–258). New York: Greenwood Press: 241–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1986). Forms of capital. In J. Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education (pp. 241–258). New York: Greenwood Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bower, J. L., & Christensen, C. M. (1996). Disruptive technologies: Catching the wave. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 13(1), 75–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brush, C. G., Greene, P. G., & Hart, M. M. (2001). From initial idea to unique advantage: the entrepreneurial challenge of constructing a resource-base. Academy of Management Executive, 15(1), 64–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, N. M., Gartner, W. B., & Reynolds, P. D. (1996). Exploring start-up event sequences. Journal of Business Venturing, 11, 151–166.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chowdhury, S. (2005). Demographic diversity for building an effective entrepreneurial team: Is it important? Journal of Business Venturing, 20(6), 727–746.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarysse, B., & Moray, N. (2004). A process study of entrepreneurial team formation: the case of a research-based spin-off. Journal of Business Venturing, 19(1), 55–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, J., & Cohen, P. (1983). Applied multiple regression/correlation analysis for the behavioral sciences (2nd ed.). Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (1990). Social capital and the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, 95–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper, A. C., Gimeno-Gascon, F. J., & Woo, C. Y. (1994). Initial human and financial capital as predictors of new venture performance. Journal of Business Venturing, 9(5), 371–395.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cosh, A., Hughes, A., & Wood, E. (1998). Innovation surveys and very small enterprises. Working paper series/ESRC Centre for Business Research, 89, Cambridge.

  • Covin, J. G., Slevin, D. P., & Heeley, M. B. (1999). Pioneers and followers: Competitive tactics, environment, and firm growth. Journal of Business Venturing, 15, 175–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlqvist, J. (2007). Assessing new economic activity: Process and performance in new ventures. Doctoral dissertation, Jönköping International Business School, Jönköping.

  • Davidsson, P. (1989). Continued entrepreneurship and small firm growth. Doctoral dissertation. Stockholm: Stockholm School of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidsson, P. (2004). Researching entrepreneurship. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidsson, P. (2006a). Method challenges and opportunities in the psychological study of entrepreneurship. In J. R. Baum, M. Frese & R. A. Baron (Eds.), The psychology of entrepreneurship (pp. 287–323). Mahway, NJ: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidsson, P. (2006b). Nascent entrepreneurship: Empirical studies and developments. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 2(1), 1–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidsson, P., & Honig, B. (2003). The role of social and human capital among nascent entrepreneurs. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(3), 301–331.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Koning, A. (2003). Opportunity development: A socio-cognitive perspective. In J. Katz & D. Shepherd (Eds.), Advances in entrepreneurship, firm emergence and growth. Cognitive approaches to entrepreneurship research (Vol. 6, pp. 265–314). Oxford, UK: Elsevier/JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delmar, F., & Shane, S. (2004). Legitimating first: Organizing activities and the survival of new ventures. Journal of Business Venturing, 19, 385–410.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewar, R. D., & Dutton, J. E. (1986). The adoption of radical and incremental Innovations: An empirical analysis. Management Science, 32(11), 1422–1433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dillon, W. R., & Goldstein, M. (1984). Multivariate analysis: Methods and applications. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(14), 147–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dimov, D. P. (2004). The individuality of opportunity recognition: A critical review and extension. In J. E. Butler (Ed.), Opportunity identification and entrepreneurial behavior (pp. 135–162). Greenwich, CT: IAP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diochon, M., Menzies, M., & Gasse, Y. (2003). Insights into the dynamics of Canadian nascent entrepreneurs’ start-up efforts and the role individual factors play in the process. Paper presented at the 20th Annual CCSBE Conference, Victoria.

  • Eisenhardt, K. M., & Schoonhoven, C. B. (1990). Organizational growth: Linking founding team, strategy, environment and growth among US semiconductor ventures, 1978–1988. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(3), 504–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiet, J. O. (1996). The informational basis of entrepreneurial discovery. Small Business Economics, 8, 419–430.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiet, J. O., Piskounov, A., & Patel, P. C. (2005). Still searching (systematically) for entrepreneurial discoveries. Small Business Economics, 25, 489–504.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foxall, G. R. (1997). Marketing psychology. Antony Rowe Ltd., Chippenham.

    Google Scholar 

  • Florin, J., Lubatkin, M., & Schulze, W. (2003). A social capital model of high-growth ventures. Academy of Management Journal, 46(3), 374–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, J. (1982). Organizational life cycles and natural selection processes. In B. Staw & L. Cummings (Eds.), Research in organizational behavior (Vol. 4, pp. 1–32) Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaglio, C. M. (1997). Opportunity identification: Review, critique and suggested research directions. In J. Katz & J. Brockhaus (Eds.), Advances in entrepreneurship, firm emergence, and growth (Vol. 3, pp. 139–202). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gartner, W. B. (1988). Who is an Entrepreneur? is the wrong question. American Small Business Journal, 12(4), 11–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gartner, W. B., Carter, N. M., & Reynolds, P. D. (2004a). Business start-up activities. In W. B. Gartner, K. G. Shaver, N. M. Carter, & P. D. Reynolds (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurial dynamics: The process of business creation (pp. 285–298). Thousand Oakes: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gartner, W. B., Shaver, K. G., Carter, N. M., & Reynolds, P. D. (2004b). Handbook of entrepreneurial dynamics: The process of business creation. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geroski, P. A. (1995). What do we know about entry?. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 13, 421–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gifford, S. (2003). Risk and Uncertainty. In Z. J. Acs & D. B. Audretsch (Eds.), Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research (pp. 37–54). Dordrecht, NL: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gimeno, J., Folta, T. B., Cooper, A. C., & Woo, C. Y. (1997). Survival of the fittest? Entrepreneurial human capital and the persistence of underperforming firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 750–783.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. (1973). The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology, 78(6), 1360–1380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91(3), 481–509.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gustafsson, V. (2004). Entrepreneurial decision-making. Doctoral dissertation. Jönköping: Jönköping International Business School.

  • Hauknes, J. (1998). Dynamic innovation systems. In M. Boden & I. Miles (Eds.), Innovation and services in the knowledge-based economy. London: Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35, 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, A. D. (1999). Firm strategy and age dependence: A contingent view of the liabilities of newness, adoloescence and obsolescence. Administrative Science Quarterly, 44, 281–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. (1993). Economics and evolution: Bringing life back into economics, Cambridge, UK and Ann Arbor (MI): Polity Press and University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibarra, H. (1997). Structural alignments, individuals strategies, and managerial actions: elements toward a network theory off getting things done. In N. Nohria & R. G. Eccles (Eds.), Network and organizations, structure, form and actions. Boston: Harvard Business Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johannisson, B. (1995). Paradigms and entrepreneurial networks—some methodological challenges. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 7, 215–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, J., & Gartner, W. B. (1988). Properties of emerging organizations. Academy of Management Review, 13(3), 429–441.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1985). Discovery and the capitalist process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. (1997). Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: An Austrian approach. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 60–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleinknecht, A. (1987). Measuring R&D in small firms: How much are we missing? Journal of Industrial Economics, 136, 253–256.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleinknecht, A. (1991). Firm size and innovation. Reply to Scheirer. Small Business Economics, 3, 157–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. H., (1921). Risk, uncertainty, and profit. New York: Houghton Mifflin.

  • Leonard-Barton, D. (1992). Core capabilities and core rigidities. Strategic Management Journal, 13(special summer issue), 111–125.

  • Lazarsfeld, P. F., & Henry, N. W. (1968). Latent structure analysis. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liao, J., & Welsch, H. (2003). Exploring the venture creation process: Evidence from tech and non-tech nascent entrepreneurs. In W. D. Bygrave et al. (Eds.), Frontiers of entrepreneurship research 2003. Wellesley, MA: Babson College.

  • Lichtenstein, B. B., Dooley, K., & Lumpkin, G. T. (2006). Measuring emergence in the dynamics of new venture creation. Journal of Business Venturing, 21(2), 153–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lieberman, M. B., & Montgomery, D. B. (1988). First-mover advantages. Strategic Management Journal, 9, 41–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lumpkin, G. T., & Dess, G. G. (1996). Clarifying the entrepreneurial orientation construct and linking it to performance. Academy of Management Review, 21(1), 135–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. V. (1949). Human action: A treatise on economics. Chicago, IL: Henry Regnery, Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, R. K., Seawright, K. W., & Morse, E. A. (2000). Cross-cultural cognition and the venture creation decision. Academy of Management Journal, 43(5), 974–993.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mosakowski, E. (2002). Overcoming resource disadvantages in entrepreneurial firms: When less is more. In M. A. Hitt, R. D. Ireland, S. M. Camp, & D. L. Sexton (Eds.), Strategic entrepreneurship: Creating a new mindset (pp. 106–126). Oxford, UK: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muthén, B. (1991). Analysis of longitudinal data using latent variable models with varying parameters. In L. Collins & J. Horn (Eds.), Best methods for the analysis of change, recent advances, unanswered questions. Washington, DC: American Psychological Association, pp. 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muthén, B. O. (2000). Methodological issues in random coefficient growth modeling using a latent variable framework: Applications to the development of heavy drinking. In J. Rose, L. Chassin, C. Presson, & J. Sherman (Eds.), Multivariate applications in substance use research (pp. 113–140). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muthén, B. O., & Curran, P. J. (1997). General longitudinal modelling of individual differences in experimental designs: A latent variable framework for analysis and power estimation. Psychological Methods, 2, 371–402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Muthén, B. O., & Khoo, S. T. (1998). Longitudinal studies of achievement growth using latent variable modeling. Learning and Individual Differences, Special issue: latent growth curve analysis, 10, 73–101.

  • Muthen, B. O., & Muthen, L., (1998). Analyzing of longitudinal data: Growth modeling using latent variables. Training session arranged by the committee for longitudinal research, the Swedish council for planning and coordination of research (FRN). Stockholm, Sweden, August, 13–18.

  • Nahapiet, J., & Ghoshal, S. (1998). Social capital, intellectual capital, and the organizational advantage. Academy of Management Review, 23(2), 242–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • The Oslo Manual; Proposed guidelines for collecting and interpreting technological innovation data: Oslo Manual 1997. (E-book PDF Format. http://oecdpublications.gfinb.com/cgi-bin/OECDBookShop.storefront/ ISBN: 9264192263.)

  • Parker, S., & Belghitar, Y. (2006). What happens to nascent entrepreneurs? And econometric analysis of the PSED. Small Business Economics, 27(1), 81–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pavitt, K. (1982). R&D patenting and innovative activities. Research Policy, 11, 33–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Podsakoff, P. M., MacKenzie, S. B., Lee, J.-Y., & Podsakoff, N. P. (2003). Common method biases in behavioral research: A critical review of the literature and recommended remedies. Journal of Applied Psychology, 88(5), 879–903.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, M. (1967). The tacit dimension. London: Routledge and Kegan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D. (2000). Bowling alone: The collapse and revival of American Community. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds, P. D. (1997). National panel studies of business start-ups: Research program status report and policy implications, working paper presented to the working party on small and medium enterprises ninth session, Seoul, Republic of Korea.

  • Reynolds, P. D. (2000). National panel study of US business start-ups. Background and methodology. In J. A. Katz (Ed.), Advances in entrepreneurship, firm emergence and growth (Vol. 4, pp. 153–227). Stamford, CT: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds, P. D., & Miller, B. (1992). New firm gestation: Conception, birth and implications for research. Journal of Business Venturing, 7, 405–417.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. (1979). Garegnani on effective demand. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 3(2), 179–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romanelli, E., (1989). Environments and strategies of organization start-up: effects on early survival. Administrative Science Quarterly, 34, 369–387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1983). Economics and entrepreneurs. In J. Ronen (Ed.), Entrepreneurship. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, pp. 301–311.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rotefoss, B., & Kolvereid, L. (2005). Aspiring, nascent and fledgling entrepreneurs: an investigation of the business start-up process. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development, 17(2), 109–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruef, M., Aldrich, H. E., & Carter, N. M. (2003). The structure of organizational founding teams: Homophily, strong ties, and isolation among U.S. entrepreneurs. American Sociological Review, 68(2), 195–222.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelsson, M. (2004). Creating new ventures: A longitudinal investigation of the nascent venturing process. Doctoral dissertation, Jönköping International Business School, Jönköping.

  • Sarasvathy, S. (2001). Causation and effectuation: towards a theoretical shift from economic inevitability to entrepreneurial contingency. Academy of Management Review, 26(2), 243–288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarasvathy, S., Dew, N., Velamuri, R., & Venkataraman, S. (2003). Three views of entrepreneurial opportunity. In Z. J. Acs & D. B. Audretsch (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurship research (pp. 141–160). Dordrecht, NL: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schotter, A. (1981). The economic theory of social institutions. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, T. (1959). Investment in man: An economist’s view. Investment in man: An economist’s view. The Social Service Review, 33(2), 69–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, T. W. (1980). Investment in entrepreneurial ability. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 82, 437–448.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1928). The instability of capitalism. The Economic Journal, 38, 361–386.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The theory of economic development. Cambridge: MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy, London.

  • Shane, S. (2000). Prior knowledge and the discovery of entrepreneurial opportunities. Organization Science, 11(4), 448–469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S., & Delmar, F. (2004). Planning for the market: business planning before marketing and the continuation of organizing efforts. Journal of Business Venturing, 19, 767–785.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S., & Eckhardt, J. (2003). The individual-opportunity nexus. In Z. J. Acs & D. B. Audretsch (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurship research (pp. 161–194). Dordrecht, NL: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S., & Venkataraman, S. (2000). The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research. Academy of Management Review, 25(1), 217–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapero, A., & Sokol, L. (1982). The social dimension of entrepreneurship. In C. A. Kent, D. L. Sexton & K. H. Vesper (Eds.), The encyclopedia of entrepreneurship (pp. 72–90). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, N. R. (1967). The entrepreneur and his firm: The relationship between type of man and type of company. East Lansing, MI: Michigan State University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stanworth, J., Blythe, S., Granger, B., & Stanworth, C. (1989). Who becomes an entrepreneur? International Small Business Journal, 8, 11–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stinchcombe, A. L. (1965). Social structure and organizations. In J. D. March (Ed.), Handbook of Organizations (pp. 142–193). Chicago, IL: Rand McNally.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storey, D. J. (1994). Understanding the small business sector. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suchman, M. C. (1995). Managing legitimacy: Strategic and institutional approaches. Academy of Management Review, 20, 571–610.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svendsen, G. L. H., & Svendsen, G. T. (2004). The Creation and Destruction of Social Capital: Entrepreneurship, Co-operative Movements and Institutions. Cheltenham, UK: Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J. (1998). The dynamics of industrial capitalism: Perspectives on Alfred Chandler's scale and scope (1990). Journal of Economic Literature, 31 (March 1993). (Reprinted in Patrick O'Brien (Ed.), Critical perspectives on the world economy (London: Routledge, 1997/1998)).

  • Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., & Shuen, A. (1997). Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, 18(7), 509–533.

    Google Scholar 

  • Utterback, J. M. (1994). Mastering the dynamics of innovation. Cambridge: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Gelderen, M., Bosma, N., & Thurik, A. R. (2001). Setting up a business in the Netherlands: who starts, who gives up, who is still trying? In W. D. Bygrave et al. (Eds.), Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research 2001. Wellesley, MA: Babson College.

  • Van Gelderen, M., Thurik, A. R., & Bosma, N. (2005). Success and risk factors in the pre-startup phase. Small Business Economics, 24, 365–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1947). The theory of social and economic organization. New York: Oxford University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Witt, U. (1992). Evolution as the theme of a new heterodoxy. Economics, 3–20.

  • Zahra, S., & Dess, G. G. (2001). Entrepreneurship as a field of research: Encouraging dialogue and debate. Academy of Management Review, 26(1), 8–10.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mikael Samuelsson.

Appendices

Appendix

Table A1 Mean, standard deviations and correlations: innovative ventures (n = 40)
Table A2 Mean, standard deviations and correlations: imitative ventures (n = 219)
Table A3 Longitudinal growth model results initial status mean variation
Table A4 Residual results

Technical appendix

The statistical development to be drawn upon in longitudinal growth modeling is termed random coefficient models. This technique goes beyond traditional equation modeling of longitudinal data and its focus on auto-regressive models (cf. Maruyama 1998). It goes further in terms of including both a mean and a covariance structure. The growth model is multilevel in that an individual’s observation over time is correlated. A second part of the model describes individual variation in growth parameters in terms of person-specific, time invariant covariates. Compared to a single regression that gives an intercept and a slope estimate of all individual units, this approach gives an intercept and slope estimate for each individual unit (Muthén and Khoo 1998). In addition, this approach accounts for similarities among individuals by stipulating that all individuals’ random effects come from a single, common population. In statistical terms, the growth model is specified as:

$$ \gamma it=\alpha i+\beta i+\zeta it $$
(1)

Here αi and βi are individual specific parameters describing initial level (intercept) and rate of growth (slope) of the entrepreneurial opportunity recognition process and \(\zeta it\) represents time varying residuals. The regression intercept and slopes are random parameters that vary over individuals. No specification of linear growth is necessary; linearity can be estimated whenever there are data on a sufficient number of time points (see Muthén and Khoo 1998 for a technical description).

It is convenient to view initial status and growth rate as latent variables. In order to understand this it is useful to consider the specification of this model into two parts. The first part includes terms contributing to the means of the observed variables and terms contributing to variances and covariances among these variables. First the mean structure, intercepts in the regression of the y’s (gestation behavior) on the two latent variables (Igestb and Ggestb) are parameters which should be held equal across time to reflect that these are measured at all time points (i.e. the same metric). The latent variable (α = initial status) is fixed at zero. The growth in the observed variable means over time is captured by the latent variable (β) (Muthén and Khoo 1998). Extending the model like this with time-invariant covariates (wi = resources and strategy), the individual variation in these parameters is specified as:

$$ \alpha i=\alpha+\gamma\alpha wi+\delta\alpha i $$
(2)
$$ \beta i=\beta+\gamma\beta wi+\delta\beta i $$
(3)

When further expanding the model by adding a time-varying covariate (vit) to the growth curve of Eq. 1, introducing time-specific deviations from the growth curve the following equation is used:

$$ Yit=\alpha i+\beta it+ ytvit +\zeta it $$
(4)

Assuming for simplicity that there is no time-varying covariate (v), the model can be seen to imply growth in means and variances as a function of time (t).

$$ \hbox{E }(yit \vert wi)=\alpha+\gamma\alpha wi+ \beta (\gamma\beta wi) t $$
(5)
$$ V (yit \vert wi)=\sigma^{2}_{\alpha}+2t\sigma_{\alpha \beta}+ t^{2}\sigma^{2}_{\beta}+\sigma^{2}_{\zeta} $$
(6)

The growth model can be viewed as a structural equation model with latent variables (cf. Maryama 1998). The αs and βs can be viewed as latent variables instead of random parameters. They are both unobserved variables varying across individuals. Another application is when (t) is not varying across individuals. In this situation, (t) in Eq. (4) can be considered as a fixed regression parameter (factor loading) for the variable βi. According to this, beta can be estimated when fixing the first two (t) values, thereby capturing also non-linear growth (Muthén and Khoo 1998).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Samuelsson, M., Davidsson, P. Does venture opportunity variation matter? Investigating systematic process differences between innovative and imitative new ventures. Small Bus Econ 33, 229–255 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9093-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9093-7

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation