Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Associations versus registration as alternative strategies of small firms

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Small firms, especially those in developing countries, face several serious problems: (1) costs of regulation, including corruption, (2) contract enforcement, and (3) idiosyncratic risks that leave their owners with high costs of finance. To deal with these problems, it is recognized that firms exercise choice over their degree of formality. Little attention, however, has been given to the alternative strategies that firms may choose in gaining formality and dealing with these problems. This article examines the choice between two different strategies: (1) registering with official entities, and (2) participating in private associations. We develop hypotheses concerning factors that would favor one such choice over the other and then test these hypotheses with data taken from a large sample survey of Mexican microenterprises. The results provide support, in some cases strong support, for most of the hypotheses.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. de Soto did pay attention to private associations in his more recent book (de Soto 2000). In general, existing literature on these private associations tends to be limited to the following issues: (1) the capture of such associations by governments largely for political purposes (e.g., in Mexico, Shadlen (2002)), (2) interfirm networking and cooperation in the success of associations in certain regions, e.g., the industrial districts of Northeastern Italy or less frequently in Mexico and other Latin American countries (Rabellotti 1993; Woodruff 1998), and (3) identifying other factors affecting the success of such associations (Cronin (2004), including their role in promoting technological change or exports (Levy et al. 1998).

  2. La Porta et al. (1998) provide an empirical analysis of the degree and quality of law enforcement, investor protection, and ownership concentration using data from 49 countries around the world. They show that countries with poor investor protection indeed have significantly smaller debt and equity markets and higher levels of ownership concentration. Such protection allows firms to attract outside investors and thereby reduce idiosyncratic risk. The environment of microenterprises in Mexico, however, is one where such protections do not apply and entrepreneurs typically have no one with whom to share their idiosyncratic risks. (See also Himmelberg et al. (2002)).

  3. Likewise, in the case of firms with large suppliers or customers and/or fixed locations, the rationale would be that in such cases one party or the other would be vulnerable to holdup problems associated with investment in product specificity and would view registration with the authorities and memberships in associations as means of lowering their vulnerability to these problems.

  4. Shadlen (2002), moreover, shows that the attempts of the major political parties to organize the numerous small microentrepreneurs into their party organizations failed because the interests of such entrepreneurs were not congruent with those of other popular groups like workers or consumers.

  5. Laeven and Woodruff (2003) have also made use of these same indicators, among others, in relating the quality of the legal system to firm size and ownership in 1998.

  6. Having a fixed or semi-fixed location here is viewed as pre-determined to the choice of registration inasmuch as the location type can be viewed as part of a detailed definition of the industry or activity type.

  7. Since both registration types are binary, while both y *1 and y *2 are estimated continuous response variables, they are defined as follows: \(\left\{{\begin{array}{lll} {y_i =1} & {\hbox{if}} & {y_i^\ast > 0} \\ {y_i =0} & {\hbox{if}} & {\hbox{otherwise}} \\ \end{array}}\right.,\) i = 1,2, where the y 1(y 2) dummy variable is one if registered with the official entity (any private association) and zero otherwise.

  8. The latter’s computational algorithm is based on the Geweke, Hajivassiliou, and Keane (GHK) recursive simulator (Geweke 1989). For further reference on multivariate probit estimation, see Heckman (1978) and Greene (2003, p. 714). Our application of the method is almost identical to the example illustrated by Greene (2003, 715–719)

  9. In the second specification of the reduced form, where we use only two of the four instruments, the test results do not reject the validity of the instruments for the equation when the dependent variable is the registration with informal organizations. But, once again they fail to support their validity for the equation when the dependent variable is the registration with the authorities.

  10. The other official entities are omitted since they would be relevant primarily to firms in a single sector (such as health) rather than to all firms.

  11. To account for possible heteroscedasticity of the residuals due to the possible variation of the data at the state level, all the specifications in Tables 3 and 4 are estimated using the robust variance-covariance matrix of the estimators. We also use Veal and Zimmermann (1992) to calculate the pseudo-R 2 measure for estimations with binary dependent variables. This is essentially the normalized Aldrich and Nelson (1984) measure of pseudo-R 2, estimated using the following formula: \(\hbox{Pseudo}\_R^{2}=-\frac{2(l_{\rm M} -l_0 )}{2(l_{\rm M} -l_0 )+N}\frac{N-2l_0}{2l_0},\) where N is the number of observations, l M is the maximized likelihood value of the model, and l 0 is the maximized likelihood value when the non-intercept coefficients are restricted to zero.

  12. The importance of improving judicial efficiency for contract enforcement and firm performance in quite different contexts have also been stressed by Djankov et al. (2003) and Chemin (2004).

References

  • Aldrich, J. H., & Nelson, F. D. (1984). Linear probability, logit, & probit models. Beverly Hills: Sage University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amemiya, T. (1979). The estimation of a simultaneous-equation tobit model. International Economic Review, 20(1), 169–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A. V. (1997). A theory of misgovernance. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1289–1332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brusco, S., (1990). The idea of the industrial district: Its genesis. In Fyke, F., Becattini, G., & Sengenberger, W. (Eds.), Industrial districts and inter-firm co-operation in Italy. Geneva: International Institute for Labour Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cappellari, L., & Jenkins, S. P. (2006). Calculation of multivariate normal probabilities by simulation, with applications to maximum simulated likelihood estimation. ISER Working Paper 2006–16, Colchester: University of Essex.

  • Charmes, J. (1990). A critical review of concepts, definitions and studies in the informal sector. In Turnham, D., Salome, B., & Schwarz, A. (Eds.), The informal sector revisited. Paris: OECD Development Centre.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chemin, M. (2004). Does the Quality of the Judiciary Shape Economic Activity? Evidence from India. London: London School of Economics (unpublished working paper).

  • Chen, M. (2005). Rethinking the Informal Economy: Linkages with the Formal Economy and the Formal Regulatory Environment. Paper presented to the EGDI-WIDER conference on unlocking the potential of the informal sector, Helsinki: WIDER.

  • Cronin, P. (2004). Game theory, business associations and the promotion of small business networks in Northern Mexico. Thunderbird Working Paper.

  • de Soto, Hernando. (1989). The other path: The invisible revolution in the Third World. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: Why capitalism triumphs in the west and fails everywhere else. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). The regulation of entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. & Shleifer, A. (2003). Courts. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(2), 453–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geweke, J. (1989). Bayesian inference in econometric models using Monte Carlo integration. Econometrica, 57, 1317–1340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. (2003). Econometric analysis, 5th edn. Prentice Hall.

  • Heckman, J. J. (1978). Dummy endogenous variables in a simultaneous equation system. Econometrica 46(6), 931–959.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Himmelberg, C. P., Hubbard, G. R., & Love, I. (2002). Investor protection, ownership, and the cost of capital. working paper, Columbia University.

  • Johnson, S., McMillan, J. & Woodruff, C. (2002). Property rights and finance. American Economic Review, 92(5), 1335–1356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1998). Law and Finance. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laeven, L., & Woodruff, C. (2003). The quality of the legal system, firm ownership and firm size. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series, No. 3246.

  • Levenson, A. R., & Maloney, W. F. (1998). The informal sector, firm dynamics and institutional participation. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series, No. 1988.

  • Levy, B., Berry, A., & Nugent, J. B. (1999). Fulfilling the export potential of small and medium firms. Norwell, MA: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddala, G. S. (1983). Limited dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Econometric Society Monographs 3, Cambridge University Press.

  • Maloney, W. F. (1999). Does informality imply segmentation in urban labor markets? Evidence from sectoral transitions in Mexico. The World Bank Economic Review, 13(2), 275–302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maloney, W. F. (2002). Distortion and protection in the Mexican labor market. Stanford University, Center for Research on Economic Development and Policy Reform Working Paper 138.

  • McPherson, M. A., & Liedholm, C. (1996). Determinants of small and micro enterprise registration: Results from surveys in Niger and Swaziland. World Development, 24(3), 481–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabellotti, R. (1993). Industrial districts in Mexico–the case of the footwear industry. Small Enterprise Development, 4 (3), 26–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robaud, F. (1995). La Economia Informal en Mexico: De la Esfera Domestica a la Dinamica Macroeconomica. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Economica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shadlen, K. C. (2000). Neoliberalism, corporatism, and small business political activism in contemporary Mexico. Latin American Research Review, 35(2), 73–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shadlen, K. C. (2002). Orphaned by democracy: Small industry in contemporary Mexico. Comparative Politics, 35(1), 43–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. J., & Blundell, R. W. (1986). An exogeneity test for a simultaneous equation Tobit model with an application to labor supply. Econometrica, 54(4), 679–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sukiassyan, G. & Nugent, J. B. (2005). Efficiency of the legal system and firm strategies for obtaining credit. Paper presented at the 77th Annual Conference of the Western Economic Association International, San Francisco, July 4–7.

  • Veal, M. R., & Zimmermann, K. F. (1992). Pseudo-R2’s in the Ordinal Probit Model. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 16, 332–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodruff, C. (1998). Contract enforcement and trade liberalization in Mexico’s footwear industry. World Development, 26, 979–986.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jeffrey B. Nugent.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sukiassyan, G., Nugent, J.B. Associations versus registration as alternative strategies of small firms. Small Bus Econ 31, 147–161 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9085-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9085-7

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation