Skip to main content
Log in

How people experience and change institutions: a field guide to creative syncretism

  • Published:
Theory and Society Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article joins the debate over institutional change with two propositions. First, all institutions are syncretic, that is, they are composed of an indeterminate number of features, which are decomposable and recombinable in unpredictable ways. Second, action within institutions is always potentially creative, that is, actors draw on a wide variety of cultural and institutional resources to create novel combinations. We call this approach to institutions creative syncretism. This article is in three parts. The first shows how existing accounts of institutional change, which are rooted in structuralism, produce excess complexity and render the most important sources and results of change invisible. We argue that in order to ground the theory of creative syncretism we need a more phenomenological approach, which explains how people live institutional rules. We find that grounding in John Dewey’s pragmatist theory of habit. The second part of the article explains Dewey and shows how the theory of habit can ground an experiential account of institutional rules. The third part presents a field guide to creative syncretism. It uses an experiential approach to provide novel insights on three problems that have occupied institutionalist research: periodization in American political development, convergence among advanced capitalist democracies, and institutional change in developing countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For many working in the field, the absence of a theory of change meant new and creative explanations of institutional disorder, incremental change, and indeterminacy. Such scholarship has yielded many powerful insights with regard to: rule ambiguity and political entrepreneurship (Hall and Taylor 1996; Sikkink 1991; Blyth 2002; Parsons 2003; Scheingate 2003; Lieberman 2002); the ongoing expression of grievances by losers (Weir 2005); lost alternatives (Schneiberg 2007; Sabel and Zeitlin 1997); redundant features (Crouch and Farrell 2004; Crouch and Keune 2005); layering of old and new institutions (Thelen 2004; Orren and Skowronek 1994, 2002, 2004; Shickler 2001; Sil 2002); the coexistence of “traditional” and “modern” institutions (Dunning and Pop-Eleches 2004); change driven by “quasi-parameters” (Greif and Laitin 2004).

  2. The concept of habit has a history, which is beyond the scope of this article and fully documented in the work of Charles Camic (1986). Of particular importance for us, Camic depicts habit as part of a lost alternative in social theory, an approach that integrated, rather than dichotomized, structure and agency. By the interwar years behavioral psychologists, bearing the apparent authority of the physical sciences, narrowed the meaning of habit to neurologically determined action. In response, sociologists largely abandoned the term, turning instead to attitude and purposeful choice to conceptualize agency. In Twentieth Century social theory that internal, cognitive, individual framing of agency would evolve into rational choice theory as the main alternative to historical, cultural, and other structuralisms. By contrast, Camic shows that at the time sociology abandoned habit, Dewey was laying out an alternative that used the concept to integrate inherited structure and ongoing reflective choice. Others have picked up Dewey’s thread in various ways (Joas 1996; Bourdieu 1977; Giddens 1984). In rethinking institutions, we find it useful to go back to Dewey to recover his alternative approach and ground our theory of creative syncretism in a concept originally intended to overcome the intractable dichotomy between structure and agency.

  3. We draw on Dewey’s concept of habit, rather than Bourdieu’s (1977) closely related habitus, because we find in the former greater sensitivity to ongoing creativity and experimentation as features of action itself. Habitus tells us much about the alignment of external conditions (field), inner orientation, and behavior. In Bourdieu’s work, agency consists mainly of aligning and realigning action to a pre-existing habitus that embeds in peoples’ cognition and bodies the structural arrangements of a social field. That field of course changes and in response, the habitus will adapt, resulting in new internalizations of a new field. Many who apply Bourdieu follow his suggestions that autonomous change of habitus is also possible, and that this is the source of creativity and reinterpretation beyond adjustment to the external conditions of the field (Sewell 1992; Powell and DiMaggio 1991). We see this potential in Bourdieu, but agree with Butler (1999) that Bourdieu does more to theorize habitus as a mechanism for the ongoing internalization of adjustments in the context or field than as a site for creative action itself. The findings of our own research conform more fully with the Deweyian account presented here, in which habit is both a repertoire of prior patterns of action (a collection of parts and oddments) and the will to rearrange this repertoire to craft new action (a new arrangement of parts) in response to circumstances that are never really twice the same. Habit balances the constraints of a limited collection of parts with rummaging, cobbling and the inventiveness of action. Bourdieu’s habitus leans more to the former.

  4. See, for example, West African “joking kinship” or Obama’s March 2008 race speech (Launay 2006; Obama 2008).

  5. Dewey offers a third reason that we find somewhat unsatisfying: rigid custom can force routine and undermine experimentation. For Dewey, this is a sociological rather than a cultural or characterological condition. In “the Orient,” Dewey suggests that “thought is submerged in habit…not because of any essentially Oriental psychology, but because of a nearer background of rigid and solid customs” (61). We applaud Dewey’s effort to distinguish the sociological production of rigid custom from essentialist notions of cultural or psychological determinacy. But in the end, a legacy of rigid custom is nothing more than a history of failures to engage in deliberation, an accumulation of routinized action. As an explanation for why habit can disintegrate into routine, this is a tautology.

  6. Desirable ends and the telos of development are of course highly contested (see Escobar 1995). Sen (1988) sketches an alternative to development teleology that is close to both local experience and our own phenomenological formulation, discussed below.

  7. Although they refer to change in norms, their conceptualization of norms fits with what we consider in this paper institutions.

  8. In addition to promoting individualization of tenure, colonial officials sought to wipe out matrilineal inheritance in favor of patrilinealism (which they considered more “civilized”). The Serer had long been bilineal, inheriting different kinds of property and rights through each line. The effort to eliminate Serer matrilinealism accelerated after several infamous 1930s debtors refused to “inherit” their father’s financial debts (owed to French commercial houses for tools and seeds), insisting that by matrilineal custom, debts were passed from mother’s brother to maternal nephews, not from fathers to sons.

  9. As Berry’s seminal work (1993) notes, this is no surprise: for much of rural Africa, competing tenure systems and contradictory types of claims are more the norm than the exception.

References

  • Adams, J., Clemens, E. S., & Orloff, A. S. (eds). (2005). Remaking modernity: Politics, history and sociology. Durham: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bates, R. (1993). Modernization, ethnic competition & the rationality of politics in contemporary Africa. In D. Rothchild & V. A. Olorunsola (Eds.), State versus ethnic claims (pp. 152–171). Boulder: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, S., & Dore, R. (eds). (1996). National diversity and global capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berk, G. (2009). Louis Brandeis and the making of regulated competition, 1900–1932. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berk, G., & Schneiberg, M. (2005). Varieties in capitalism, varieties of association: collaborative learning in American industry, 1900–1925. Politics and Society, 33(1), 46–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, S. (1993). No condition is permanent: The social dynamics of agrarian change in Subsaharan Africa. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blyth, M. (2002). Great transformations: Economic ideas and institutional change in the twentieth century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1977 [1972]). Outline of a theory of practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Butler, J. (1999). Performativity’s social magic. In R. Schusterman (Ed.), Bourdieu: A critical reader (pp. 113–128). Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camic, C. (1986). The matter of habit. American Journal of Sociology, 91, 1039–1087.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, D. P. (2001). The forging of bureaucratic autonomy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

  • Clemens, E. (1997). The people’s lobby: Organizational innovation and the rise of interest group politics in the United States, 1890–1925. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clemens, E., & Cook, J. M. (1999). Politics and institutionalism: explaining durability and change. Annual Review of Sociology, 25, 441–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, R. B., & Collier, D. (1991). Shaping the political arena: Critical junctures, the labor movement, and regime dynamics in Latin America. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook, G. A. (2006). George Herbert mead. In J. R. Shook & J. Margolis (Eds.), A companion to pragmatism. Malden: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crouch, C., & Farrell, H. (2004). Breaking the path of institutional development: alternatives to the new determinism. Rationality and Society, 16(1), 5–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crouch, C., & Keune, M. (2005). Changing dominant practice: Making use of institutional diversity in Hungary and the United Kingdom. In W. Streeck & K. Thelen (Eds.), Beyond continuity. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewey, J. (2002 [1922]). Human nature and conduct. Amherst: Prometheus Books.

  • DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. W. (1991). Introduction. In W. W. Powell & P. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 1–40). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, T., & Pop-Eleches, G. (2004). From transplants to hybrids: exploring institutional pathways to growth. Studies in Comparative International Development, 38(4), 3–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ensminger, J., & Knight, J. (1997). Changing social norms: common property, bridewealth and clan exogamy. Current Anthropology, 38(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Escobar, A. (1995). Encountering development. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, P. (2004). Development as institutional change: the pitfalls of monocropping and the potentials of deliberation. Studies in Comparative International Development, 38(4), 30–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finegold, K., & Skocpol, T. (1995). State and party in America’s new deal. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fung, A., & Wright, E. O. (eds). (2003). Deepening democracy: Institutional innovations in empowered participatory governance. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galvan, D. (2004). The state must be our master of fire: How peasants craft culturally sustainable development in Senegal. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giddens, A. (1984). The constitution of society. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: evidence on the Maghribi traders. Journal of Economic History, 49(4), 857–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A., & Laitin, D. D. (2004). A theory of endogenous institutional change. American Political Science Review, 98(4), 638–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haggard, S. (2004). Institutions and growth in East Asia. Studies in Comparative International Development, 38(4), 53–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P. A., & Taylor, R. (1996). Political science and the three new institutionalisms. Political Studies, 44(4), 936–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. (2006). Informal institutions and democracy: Lessons from Latin America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrigel, G. (2005). Institutionalists at the limits of institutionalism: a constructivist critique of two volumes by Wolfgang Streeck and Kozo Yamamura. Socioeconomic Review, 3, 559–567.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrigel, G. (2008). Rules and roles: ambiguity, experimentation and new forms of Stakeholderism in Germany. Industrielle Beziehungen, 15(2), 111–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hwang, H., & Powell, W. W. (2005). Institutions and entrepreneurship. In S. Alvarez, R. Agarwal & O. Sorenson (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurship research. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joas, H. (1993). Pragmatism and social theory. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joas, H. (1996). The creativity of action. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelman, M. (1987). A guide to critical legal studies. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Launay, R. (2006). Practical joking. Cahiers d’Etudes Africaines, XLVI(3–4), 183–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levi-Strauss, C. (1966). The savage mind. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lieberman, R. C. (2002). Ideas, institutions and political order: explaining political change. American Political Science Review, 96(4), 697–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindblom, C. E. (1990). Inquiry and change. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G., & Olsen, J. O. (1989). Rediscovering institutions: The organizational basis of politics. New York: Free.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCraw, T. K. (1984). Prophets of regulation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

  • North, D. C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1991). Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 97–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (2003). Gunnar Myrdal lecture: The role of institutions in economic development. Occasional Paper No 1. Geneva: Economic Commissions for Europe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obama, B. (2008). Race speech. http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2008/03/18/obama-race-speech-read-th_n_92077.html.

  • Orloff, A. S. (1993). The politics of pensions: A comparative analysis of Britain, Canada and the United States, 1880s–1940. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orren, K., & Skowronek, S. (1994). Beyond the iconography of order. In L. C. Dodd & C. Jillson (Eds.), The dynamics of American politics: Approaches and interpretations. Boulder: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orren, K., & Skowronek, S. (2002). The study of American political development. In I. Katznelson & H. Milner (Eds.), Political science: State of the discipline. NY: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orren, K., & Skowronek, S. (2004). The search for American political development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, C. (2003). A certain idea of Europe. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierson, P. (2000). Increasing returns, path dependence, and the study of politics. American Political Science Review, 94(2), 251–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sabel, C. F. (1994). Learning by monitoring: The institutions of economic development. In N. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), Handbook of economic sociology (pp. 137–165). Princeton: Princeton University Press and Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sabel, C. F., & Zeitlin, J. (eds). (1997). World of possibilities: Flexibility and mass production in Western industrialization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheingate, A. (2003). Political entrepreneurship, institutional change and American political development. Studies in American Political Development, 17, 185–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneiberg, M. (2007). What’s on the path? Path dependence, organizational diversity and the problem of institutional change in the US economy, 1900–1950. Socioeconomic Review, 5(1), 47–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, J. C. (1985). Weapons of the weak: Everyday forms of peasant resistance. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, J. C. (1998). Seeing like a state: How certain schemes to improve the human condition have failed. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (1988). The concept of development. In H. Chenery & T. N. Srinivasan (Eds.), Handbook of development economics (Vol. 1, pp. 10–25). New York: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sewell, W. H. (1992). A theory of structure: duality, agency and transformation. American Journal of Sociology, 98, 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaw, C. (1999). Syncretism and its synonyms. Diacritics, 29(3), 40–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shickler, E. (2001). Disjointed pluralism: Institutional innovation and the development of the US congress. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sikkink, K. (1991). Ideas and institutions: Developmentalism in Brazil and Argentina. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sil, R. (2002). Managing “Modernity”: Work, community, and authority in late-industrializing Japan and Russia. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skocpol, T. (1992). Protecting soldiers and mothers: The political origins of social policy in the United States. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skocpol, T., Evans, P., & Reuschemeyer, D. (1985). Bringing the state back in. New York: Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skowronek, S. (1982). Building a new American state: The expansion of national administrative capacities, 1887–1920. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, R. (1992). If politics matters: implications for a new institutionalism. Studies in American Political Development, 6, 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Somers, M. (1994). Narrative and the constitution of identity: a relational and network approach. Theory and Society, 23(5), 605–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stark, D. (1996). Recombinant property in East European capitalism. American Journal of Sociology, 101, 993–1027.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stark, D., & Bruzst, L. (1998). Postsocialist pathways: Transforming politics and property in East Central Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, C., & Shaw, R. (1994). Syncretism/Anti-syncretism: The politics of religious synthesis. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strang, D., & Meyer, J. W. (1993). Institutional conditions for diffusion. Theory and Society, 22(4), 487–511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Streeck, W., & Thelen, K. (eds). (2005). Beyond continuity. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thelen, K. (2004). How institutions evolve: The political economy of skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thelen, K., & Kume, I. (2003). The future of nationally embedded capitalism: Industrial relations in Germany and Japan. In K. Yamamura & W. Streeck (Eds.), The end of Diversity?. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thelen, K., & Steinmo, S. (1992). Historical institutionalism in comparative politics. In S. Steinmo, K. Thelen & F. Longstreth (Eds.), Structuring politics: Historical institutionalism in comparative analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsai, K. (2002). Back-alley banking: Private entrepreneurs in China. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Unger, R. M. (1987). Social theory: Its situation and its task. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weick, K. E. (2001). Making sense of the organization. Malden: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weir, M. (2005). States, race, and the decline of new deal liberalism. Studies in American Political Development, 19(2), 157–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamamura, K., & Streeck, W. (2003). The end of diversity? Prospects for German and Japanese capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zeitlin, J., & Herrigel, G. (eds). (2000). Americanization and its limits. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to acknowledge three thoughtful and very helpful anonymous reviews from Theory and Society; the always helpful input from our colleagues and students in the Political Science Department at the University of Oregon; Richard Bensel and Gary Herrigel, who commented on earlier versions of this article; and the tireless patience of Karen, Kirsten, Jacob, Ben, Sam, and Jeep.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gerald Berk.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Berk, G., Galvan, D. How people experience and change institutions: a field guide to creative syncretism. Theor Soc 38, 543–580 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-009-9095-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11186-009-9095-3

Keywords

Navigation