Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Dirty money: Is there a wage premium for working in a pollution intensive industry?

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Within a compensating wage differential framework we investigate whether there is a wage premium for working in a pollution intensive industry. Our results for the economy as a whole suggest a small wage premium of approximately one quarter of one percent associated with the risk of working in a dirty job. This premium rises to over fifteen percent for those individuals who work in one of the five dirtiest industries. We also find evidence of a fatal risk wage premium, providing estimates of the value of a statistical life of between £12 million and £19 million (2000 prices).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A lively debate on the existence of wage compensation continues. See Dorman (1996) for a broader discussion of these assumptions and theoretical reasons for doubting their applicability. Most value of statistical life (VSL) studies centre on one basic premise: that the VSL should roughly correspond to the value that people place on their lives in private decisions. See Viscusi (1993), Dorman and Hagstrom (1998) and Viscusi and Aldy (2003) for a review of the existing literature and Mrozek and Taylor (1999) for the results of an often cited meta-analysis on the determinants of the value of life. Mrozek and Taylor (1999) offer a best practice estimate of VSL of $2 million (1998 prices). Note that their estimates are considerably less than the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) VSL value of $6 million (1998 dollars). Burtraw et al. (1998), Hagler-Bailly (1995) and US EPA (1997) all show that the benefits far outweigh the abatement costs even if VSL figures were to be reduced by two thirds. See Viscusi (2007) for an overview of the regulation of health, safety and environmental risks.

  2. UK estimates of VSL have often been notably different to those estimated for the US (see Viscusi and Aldy 2003).

  3. There are a small number of studies that have examined the impact of environmental regulations on employment although they generally find little effect. For the US, studies by Morgenstern et al. (2002) and Berman and Bui (2001) find no evidence to suggest that regulations have adversely affected industrial employment with the former actually finding weak evidence that regulations may result in a small net increase in employment. Cole and Elliott (2007) find a similar result for the UK. However, studies by Henderson (1996), Kahn (1997) and Greenstone (2002), again for the US, indicate that industries located in counties with stringent regulations have experienced job losses, or at the very least, lower employment growth rates, relative to industries in less regulated counties.

  4. Ozone pollution stems mainly from emissions of Nox and VOCs with concentration levels depending on the amount and location of emitted pollutants, geographical characteristics, meteorological conditions, and atmospheric chemistry and transport. Ozone formation is complicated and non-linear; for example, under certain conditions an increase in Nox can reduce ozone concentrations. PM10 pollution stems mainly from direct emissions of particles, and from reactions of NOX and SO2 with other substances in the atmosphere. Potential emission sources are building and construction, diesel trucks and buses, forest fires, refuse burning and some manufacturing industries. See Cesar et al. (2002) for details.

  5. In a study for the US Viscusi (2003) reveals that blacks do face a higher fatality risk and nonfatal injury-risk but that the differences are not great. He also shows that black employees receive significant premia for nonfatal risks. The problem, however, is that although black employees undertake greater risk than whites, they also receive lower annual pay. Viscusi (2003) states that “…there must be fundamental differences in labor market opportunities for blacks and whites as well as the structure of their offers for risky jobs” (p. 254). For non-fatal injury both men and women earn a wage differential but this figure is three times larger for women. Leeth and Ruser (2003) also show that white women earn the highest wage compensation for non-fatal risk. Black, Hispanic and other minorities also receive higher pay for bearing nonfatal injury risk but the premia were smaller than for white women.

  6. A related issue is the controversy surrounding unobservable worker heterogeneity and VSL estimates. One recognised problem with all wage-risk studies is the issue of endogeneity, as raised by Garen (1988). It is possible that those workers with the greatest earnings capacity are likely to choose safer and less pollution intensive working environments (assuming safety and pollution-free working conditions are normal goods). After attempting to control for endogeneity issues, Garen (1988) finds generally larger VSL estimates. However, as Kostiuk (1990) points out, Garen’s (1988) methodology removes unobserved worker heterogeneity as an influence on the estimates. This is fine if the unobserved heterogeneity is the behaviour of workers in the face of risk alone. However, differing risk parameters across workers are a necessary condition for the market to generate compensating wage differentials unless we assume individuals’ indifference curves are identical. The Garen technique therefore removes too much. Nevertheless, we utilise the Garen methodology to control for the possible endogeneity of our fatal, nonfatal and pollution risk variables. The coefficient on nonfatal risk did not alter significantly and remained insignificant and had little impact on the pollution risk coefficient. We are unable to instrument for possible endogeneity between wages and pollution intensity as no suitable instrument is available. Results when fatal and nonfatal risk are instrumented are available from the authors upon request.

  7. Dickens and Katz (1987) find that roughly a quarter of individual level wage variation is explained by industry level wage premia casting doubt on the ability of unmeasured worker heterogeneity to account for industry wage differentials.

  8. The UK Environmental Accounts (EA) use a combination of 2, 3 and 4-digit SIC codes. See http://www.statistics.gov.uk/.

  9. In unreported results we also use a fourth exposure measure, namely pollution per worker. Results were broadly similar to those for the other exposure measures but are omitted for reasons of space. They are available upon request.

  10. The QLFS is a rotating panel that follows the same individuals for five consecutive quarters. It currently includes a representative sample of approximately 60,000 households made up of five “waves”, each of approximately 12,000 households. A systematic random sample design is used for the survey and it is therefore representative of the whole of Great Britain. All estimates based on the LFS are subject to sampling error. Our sample excludes the self-employed. Care is taken to ensure that individuals are not replicated.

  11. The difference between weekly pay and hourly pay is that the former includes usual hours of paid overtime.

  12. Bellman (1994) uses occupational risk variables for blue-collar workers for Germany and finds a significant positive effect for non-fatal occupational illness of male employees, controlling for schooling, experience and change of industry. However, for nonfatal injuries at work the coefficient was significant and negative. He concluded that for Germany there was no explicit evidence for the existence of compensating wage differentials, especially for non-fatal risk. In contrast, Grund (2000) finds evidence of compensating wage differentials for increased accidents for blue-collar workers in West Germany.

  13. The majority of studies are US based and merge industry-average risk measures (BLS at 2 or 3-digit) or the NIOSH’s National Traumatic Occupational Fatality project which reports fatalities by 1-digit industry. Seven of the eight studies summarised in Dorman and Hagstrom (1998) use these data sets.

  14. Import and export variables are not included as our sample has both tradable and non-tradable sectors.

  15. Appendix contains the sample means of all of the variables used in Table 1.

  16. None of these UK studies use our richer LFS dataset.

References

  • Arabsheibani, G. R., & Marin, A. (2000). Stability of estimates of the compensation for danger. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 20(3), 247–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellman, L. (1994). Entohnung als Risikokompensation. Mitteilungen aus der Arbeitmarkt- und Berufsforschung, 4, 351–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berman, E., & Bui, L. T. M. (2001). Environmental regulation and labor demand: evidence from the South Coast Air Basin. Journal of Public Economics, 79, 265–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackburn, M., & Neumark, D. (1992). Unobserved ability, efficiency wages, and inter-industry wage differentials. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(4), 1421–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (1994). The wage curve. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, N., Sethi, R. (1997). The distribution of pollution: Community characteristics and exposure to air toxics. Journal of Environmental Economics and Managements, 32(2), 233–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, M. S. (1987). Communicating information about workplace hazards: Effects on worker attitudes toward risks. In B. B. Johnson & V. T. Corello (Eds.), The social and cultural construction of risk. Boston: D. Reidel Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, C., & Medoff, J. (1989). The employer size-wage effect. Journal of Political Economy, 97(5), 1027–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burtraw, D., Krupnick, A., Austin, D., Mansur, E., & Farrell, D. (1998). The costs and benefits of reducing air pollutants related to acid rain. Contemporary Economic Policy, 16, 379–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cesar, H., Borja-Aburto, V. H., Cicero-Fernandez, P., Dorland, K., Munoz Cruz, R., Brander, L., et al. (2002). Improving air quality in Metropolitan Mexico City: An economic valuation, policy research paper 2785. Washington, D.C: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cole, M. A. & Elliott, R. J. R. (2007). Do Environmental regulations cost jobs? An industry-level analysis of the UK, The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 7.1.

  • Costa, D. L., & Kahn, M. E. (2004). Changes in the value of life, 1940–1980. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 29(2), 159–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickens, W. T., & Katz, L. (1987). Inter-Industry Wage Differentials and Industry Characteristics. In K. Lang & J. Leonard (Eds.), Unemployment and the structure of labor markets. London: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dillingham, A. E. (1985). The influence of risk variable definition on value of statistical life estimates. Economic Inquiry, 24(2), 277–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dockery, D., Pope, C. A., Xu, X., Spengler, J. D., Ware, J. H., Fay, M. E., et al. (1993). An association between air pollution and mortality in six U.S. cities. New England Journal of Medicine, 329(24), 1753–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorman, P. (1996). Markets and mortality: Economics, dangerous work, and the value of human life. Cambridge University Press.

  • Dorman, P., & Hagstrom, P. (1998). Wage compensation for dangerous work revisited. Industrial & Labor Relations Review, 52(1), 116–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncan, G. J., & Stafford, F. P. (1980). Do union members receive compensating differentials. American Economic Review, 70, 355–371.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duncan, G. J., & Holmlund. (1983). Was Adam Smith right after all? Another test of the theory of compensating differentials. Journal of Labor Economics, 1, 367–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garen, J. (1988). Compensating wage differentials and the endogeneity of job riskiness. Review of Economics and Statistics, 9–16.

  • Gibbons, R., & Katz, L. F. (1995). Does unmeasured ability explain inter-industry wage differentials? Review of Economic Studies, 59(3), 515–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenstone, M. (2002). The impact of environmental regulations on industrial activity: evidence from 1970 and 1977 clean air act amendments and the census of manufacturers. Journal of Political Economy, 110(6), 1175–1219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grund, C. (2000). Wages and risk compensation in Germany. IZA Discussion Paper No. 221.

  • Hagler-Bailly Consulting, Inc. (1995). Human health benefits assessment of the acid rain provisions on the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments, final report for USEPA, Acid Rain Division.

  • Helwege, J. (1992). Sectoral shifts and inter-industry wage differentials. Journal of Labor Economics, 10, 55–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, V. (1996). Effects of air quality regulation. American Economic Review, 86, 789–813.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hwang, H. S., Reed, W. R., & Hubbard, C. (1990). Compensating wage differentials and unobserved productivity. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 835–858.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, M. E. (1997). Particulate pollution trends in the United States. Journal of Regional Science and Urban Economics, 27, 87–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kostiuk, P. F. (1990). Compensating differentials for shift work. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), 1054–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landrigan, P. J. (1992). Commentary: environmental disease — A preventable epidemic. American Journal of Public Health, 82(7), 933–941.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeth, J. D., & Ruser, J. (2003). Compensating wage differentials for fatal and non-fatal injury by race and gender. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 27(3), 257–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leigh, P. J. (1995). Compensating wages, value of statistical life, and inter-industry differentials. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28(1), 83–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsey, R. (1976). Comments on the Value of Saving a Life: Evidence from the Labor Market. In N. Terleckyj (Ed.), Household production and consumption. New York: NBER/Columbia University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R., & Manning, R. L. (2000). Have changing liability rules compensated workers twice for occupational hazards? Earnings Premiums and Cancer Risks, Journal of Legal Studies, 29, 99–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgenstern, R. D., Pizer, W. A., & Shih, J. S. (2002). Jobs versus the environment: an industry-level perspective. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43, 412–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulton, B. (1990). An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the effects of aggregate variables on micro units. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 72(2), 334–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mrozek, J. R., & Taylor, L. O. (1999). What determines the value-of-life: A meta-analysis. Department of Economics: Georgia State University.

  • Murphy, K. M., & Topel, R. H. (1987). Unemployment, Risk and Earnings: Testing for Equalizing Wage Differences in the Labor Market. In K. Lang & J. Leonard (Eds.), Unemployment and the structure of labor markets. London: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pope, C. A., Thun, M. J., Namboodiri, M. M., Dockery, D. W., Evans, J. S., Speizer, F. E., et al. (1995). Particulate air pollution as a predictor of mortality in a prospective study of U.S. adults. American Journal of Critical Care Medicine, 151(3), 669–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. C. (1991). Toil and toxics: Workplace struggles and political strategies for occupational safety and health. Berkley: University of California.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandy, R., Elliott, R. F., Siebert, W. S., & Wei, X. (2001). Measurement error and the effects of unions on the compensating differentials for fatal workplace risks. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 23(1), 33–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shilling, S., & Brackbill, R. M. (1987). Occupational health and safety rules and potential health consequences for U.S. workers, 1985. Public Health Reports, 102, 36–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shogren, J. F., & Stamland, T. (2002). Skill and the value of life. Journal of Political Economy, 110(5), 1168–1173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siebert, W. S., & Wei, X. (1994). Compensating wage differentials for workplace accidents: evidence for union and nonunion workers in the UK. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 9(1), 61–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, G. (1992). Workplace injury: a view from HSE’s trailer to the 1990 labour force survey. Employment Gazette, 100(12), 621–638.

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (1997). The benefits and costs of the Clean Air Act 1970–1990, Prepared for the U.S. Congress by the US EPA (October).

  • Vineis, P. & Simonato, L. (1991). The proportion of lung and bladder cancer in males resulting from occupation: a systematic approach. Archives of Environmental Health 46(6).

  • Viscusi, W. K., & O’Connor, C. (1984). Adaptive responses to chemical labeling: are workers Bayesian decision makers? American Economic Review, 74(5), 942–956.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1993). The value of risks to life and health. Journal of Economic Literature, 31, 1912–1946.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (2004). The value of life: estimates with risks by occupation and industry. Economic Inquiry, 42(1), 29–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (2003). Racial differences in labor market values of a statistical life. The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 27(3), 239–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (2007). Regulation of health, safety, and environmental risks. In A. M. Polinsky & S. Shavell (Eds.), Handbook of law and economics (Vol. 1). Amsterdam: Elsevier, North-Holland.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K., & Aldy, J. E. (2003). The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 27(1), 5–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Health Organization. (2007). World day for safety and health at work, press release, http://www.ilo.org/public/english/protection/safework/worldday/index.htm.

  • Wiggins, S. N., & Ringleb, A. H. (1992). Adverse selection and long-term hazards: the choice between contract and mandatory liability rules. Journal of Legal Studies, 21(1), 189–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

Matthew Cole and Robert Elliott are grateful for funding from the Leverhulme Trust grant F/00094/AG. We would like to thank Steve McIntosh and participants at EAERE Kyoto, The Health and Safety Executive for useful comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert J. R. Elliott.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 4 UK environment agency industry classification and SIC92 concordance
Table 5 Pollutants groupings
Table 6 Table of sample means
Table 7 OLS (log) Wage equation for all pollutants, full specification (1995–2003)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cole, M.A., Elliott, R.J.R. & Lindley, J.K. Dirty money: Is there a wage premium for working in a pollution intensive industry?. J Risk Uncertain 39, 161–180 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-009-9077-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-009-9077-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation