Skip to main content
Log in

Dual process theories: A key for understanding the diversification bias?

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The diversification bias in repeated lotteries is the finding that a majority of participants fail to select the option offering the highest probability. This phenomenon is systematic and immune to classical manipulations (e.g. monetary rewards). We apply dual process theories and argue that the diversification bias is a consequence of System 1 (automatic, intuitive, associative) triggering a matching response, which fails to be corrected by System 2 (intentional, analytic, rational). Empirically, supporting the corrective functions of System 2 through appropriate contextual cues (describing the task as a statistical test rather than as a lottery) led to a decrease of diversification.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Even without replacement p(green) is maximal, since there are 11 green cards more than cards of any other color and only five draws. Although strict independence is not applicable to our task (which is without replacement), we will use this notion in its loose sense, of quasi-independence.

References

  • Arkes, Hal R., Robyn M. Dawes, and Caryn Christensen. (1986). “Factors Influencing the Use of a Decision Rule in a Probabilistic Task,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 37, 93–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, Jonathan, Leonardo Granato, Mark Spranca, and Eva Teubal. (1993). “Decision Making Biases in Children and Early Adolescents: Exploratory Studies,” Merril Palmer Quarterly 39, 23–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaiken, Shelly, and Yaacov Trope (eds.). (1999). Dual-Process Theories in Social Psychology. New York: Guilford.

  • Epstein, Seymour. (1994). “Integration of the Cognitive and Psychodynamic Unconscious,” American Psychologist 49, 709–724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Estes, William K., and J. H. Straughan. (1954). “Analysis of a Verbal Conditioning Situation in Terms of Statistical Learning Theory,” Journal of Experimental Psychology 47, 225–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fantino, Edmund, and Ali Esfandiari. (2002). “Probability Matching: Encouraging Optimal Responding in Humans,” Canadian Journal of Experimental Psychology 56, 58–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Wayne W., and James E. Mazur. (1997). “Basic and Applied Research on Choice Responding,” Journal of Applied Behavior Analysis 30, 387–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, Daniel, Dominic W. Massaro, Stephen Kitzis, and Michael Cohen. (1995). “A Comparison of Learning Models,” Journal of Mathematical Psychology 39, 164–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gal, Ido, and Jonathan Baron. (1996). “Understanding Repeated Simple Choices,” Thinking and Reasoning 2, 81–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallistel, Charles R. (1990). The Organization of Learning. Cambridge, MA: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, Daniel T. (1989). “Thinking Lightly About Others: Automatic Components of the Social Inference Process.” In James Uleman and John A. Bargh (eds.), Unintended Thought (pp. 189–211). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, Daniel T. (1999). “What the Mind’s Not.” In Shelly Chaiken and Yaacov Trope (eds.), Dual-process Theories in Social Psychology (pp. 3–11). New York: Guilford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goel, Vinod, and Raymond Dolan. (2003). “Explaining Modulation of Reasoning by Belief,” Cognition 87, B11–B22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Healy, Alice F., and Michael Kubovy. (1981). “Probability Matching and the Formation of Conservative Decision Rules in a Numerical Analog of Signal Detection,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Learning and Memory 7, 344–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herrnstein, R. J. (1961). “Relative and Absolute Strength of Response as a Function of Frequency of Reinforcement,” Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 4, 267–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kacelnik, Alex, and Melissa Bateson. (1997). “Risk-sensitivity: Crossroads for Theories of Decision-making,” Trends in Cognitive Sciences 1, 304–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel. (2003). “A Perspective on Judgement and Choice: Mapping Bounded Rationality,” American Psychologist 58, 697–720.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel, and Shane Frederick. (2002). “Representativeness Revisited: Attribute Substitution in Intuitive Judgement.” In Thomas Gilovich, Dale Griffin, and Daniel Kahneman (eds.), Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment (pp. 49–81). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kogler, Christoph. (2006). “How Robust is the Diversification Bias? The Role of Dual Cognitive Process-theories in Multiple Decision Problems with Objective Probabilities.” Ph.D., University of Salzburg.

  • Kogler, Christoph, and Anton Kühberger. (2006). “Dual Process Theories and the Diversification Bias.” In Bartosz Gula, Rainer Alexandrowizc, Sabine Strauß, Eva Brunner, Barbara Jenull-Schiefer, and Oliver Vitouch (eds.), Perspektiven psychologischer Forschung in Österreich (pp.62–70). Lengerich: Pabst.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loomes, Graham. (1998). “Probability vs. Money: A Test of Some Fundamental Assumptions about Rational Decision Making,” The Economic Journal 108, 477–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myers, Jerome L., Jane G. Fort, Leonard Katz, and Mary M. Suydam. (1963). “Differential Memory Gains and Losses and Event Probability in a Two-choice Situation,” Journal of Experimental Psychology 66, 521–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Read, Daniel, and George Loewenstein. (1995). “Diversification Bias: Explaining the Discrepancy in Variety Seeking Between Combined and Separate Choices,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied 1, 34–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rohde, Catrin, Leda Cosmides, Wolfgang Hell, and John Tooby. (1999). “When and Why do People Avoid Unknown Probabilities in Decisions Under Uncertainty? Testing Some Predictions from Optimal Foraging Theory,” Cognition 72, 269–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, Ariel. (2002). “Irrational Diversification in Multiple Decision Problems,” European Economic Review 46, 1369–1378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shanks, David R., Richard J. Tunney, and John D. McCarthy. (2002). “A Re-examination of Probability Matching and Rational Choice,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 15, 233–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonson, Itmar. (1990). “The Effect of Purchase Quantity and Timing on Variety Seeking Behavior,” Journal of Marketing Research 32, 150–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stanovich, Keith E., and Richard F. West. (2000). “Individual Differences in Reasoning: Implications for the Rationality Debate,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23, 645–726.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stanovich, Keith E., and Richard F. West. (2002). “Individual Differences in Reasoning: Implications for the Rationality Debate?” In Thomas Gilovich, Dale W. Griffin, and Daniel Kahneman (eds.), Heuristics and Biases: The Psychology of Intuitive Judgment (pp. 421–440). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Suppes, Patrick, and Richard C. Atkinson. (1960). Markov Learning Models for Multiperson Interactions. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vulkan, Nir. (2000). “An Economist’s Perspective on Probability Matching,” Journal of Economic Surveys 14, 101–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • West, Richard F., and Keith E. Stanovich. (2003). “Is Probability Matching Smart? Associations Between Probabilistic Choices and Cognitive Ability,” Memory & Cognition 31, 243–251.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anton Kühberger.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kogler, C., Kühberger, A. Dual process theories: A key for understanding the diversification bias?. J Risk Uncertainty 34, 145–154 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-007-9008-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-007-9008-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation