Skip to main content
Log in

Foreign exchange option pricing in the currency cycle with jump risks

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines regime switching behavior and the nature of jumps in foreign exchange rates, as well as their implications in currency option pricing. Considering the characteristics of long swing as well as the short term jumps in exchange rates, we adopt the regime-switching model with jump risks to capture the movement of exchange rates in the developed and emerging countries. Our results show that ‘high-variance’ and ‘low-variance’ describes most of our sample currencies’ trajectories. The regime-switching model with jump risks is proven to capture better exchange rate changes than the regime-switching model (RSM) and the Black–Scholes model (BSM). In addition, our results show that the currency option pricing model when considering regimes of high-variance or low-variance states as well as the jump nature of exchange rates, is better than the traditional BSM and RSM.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The Brazilian currency crisis occurred in 1999. On Jan. 13, 1999, the Brazilian Central Bank devalued the real by 8 % and on Jan. 15, 1999 the Cardoso government announced that the real would no longer be pegged to the US dollar. Immediately, it lost more than 30 % of its value, and the subsequent devaluation resulted in a further loss of 45 % of the original value.

  2. If regime switching is ignored, that is μ 1 = μ 2 = μ and σ 1 = σ 2 = σ, the regime-switching model degenerates into the Black–Scholes model, and the parameters, μ and σ, are also estimated by the MLE method.

  3. To save space, we did not report the full model estimation (with mean parameters) here. However, the results would be available upon request.

  4. The detailed derivation is shown in “Appendix”.

References

  • Andersen TG, Bollerslev T, Diebold FX, Labys P (2001) The distribution of exchange rate volatility. J Am Stat Assoc 96:42–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bae K, Karolyi A, Stulz R (2003) A new approach to measuring financial contagion. Rev Financ Stud 16:717–763

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baharumshah AZ, Wooi HC (2007) Exchange rate volatility and the Asian financial crisis: evidence from South Korea and ASEAN-5. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Polic 10:237–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barndorff-Nielsen OE, Shephard N (2006) Econometrics of testing for jumps in financial economics using bipower variation. J Financ Econom 4:1–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bates DS (1996a) Dollar jump fears, 1984–1992: distributional abnormalities implicit in currency futures options. J Int Money Financ 15:65–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bates DS (1996b) Jumps and stochastic volatility: exchange rate processes implicit in deutsche mark options. Rev Financ Stud 9:69–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert G, Hodrick R (1993) On biases in the management of foreign exchange risk premiums. J Int Money Financ 12:115–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergman UM, Hansson J (2005) Real exchange rates and switching regimes. J Int Money Financ 24:121–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biger N, Hull J (1983) The valuation of currency options. Financ Manag 12:24–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black F, Scholes M (1973) The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J Polit Econ 81:637–654

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollen N (1998) Valuing options in regime-switching models. J Deriv 6:38–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caporale GM, Spagnolo N (2004) Modeling East Asian exchange rates: a Markov-switching approach. Appl Financ Econ 14:233–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carr P, Wu L (2007) Stochastic skew in currency options. J Financ Econ 86:213–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaboud AP, Chernenko SV, Wright JH (2008) Trading activity and macroeconomic announcements in high-frequency exchange rate data. J Eur Econ Assoc 6:589–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costabile M, Leccadito A, Massabo’ I, Russo E (2013) A reduced lattice model for option pricing under regime-switching. Rev Quant Financ Acc. doi:10.1007/s11156-013-0357-9

  • Dahlquist M, Gray SF (2000) Regime-switching and interest rates in the European monetary system. J Int Econ 50:399–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doffou A, Hilliard J (2001) Pricing currency options under stochastic interest rates and jump-diffusion processes. J Financ Res 24:565–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duan JC, Popova I, Ritchken P (2002) Option pricing under regime switching. Quant Financ 2:116–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durland J, McCurdy T (1994) Duration-dependent transitions in a markov model of US GNP growth. J Bus Econ Stat 12:279–288

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B, Rose AK, Wyplosz C (1995) Exchange market mayhem: the antecedents and aftermath of speculative attacks. Econ Policy 10:249–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen B, Rose AK, Wyplosz C (1996) Contagious currency crises: first tests. Scand J Econ 98:463–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel C (1994) Can the Markov switching model forecast exchange rates? J Int Econ 36:151–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel C, Hakkio CS (1996) The distribution of the exchange rate in the EMS. Int J Financ Econ 1:55–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel C, Hamilton J (1990) Long swings in the dollar: are they in the data and do markets know it? Am Econ Rev 80:689–713

    Google Scholar 

  • Favero C, Giavazzi F (2002) Is the international propagation of financial shocks non-linear? Evidence from the ERM. J Int Econ 57:231–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flood R, Hodrick R (1986) Real aspects of exchange rate regime choice with collapsing fixed rates. J Int Econ 21:215–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel J (1981) Flexible exchange rates, prices, and the role of news: lessons from the 1970s. J Polit Econ 89:665–705

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Froot KA, Obstfeld M (1991) Exchange-rate dynamics under stochastic regime shifts. J Int Econ 31:203–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garman M, Kohlhagen S (1983) Foreign currency option values. J Int Money Financ 2:231–237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldfeld S, Quandt R (1973) A Markov model for switching regressions. J Econom 1:3–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grabbe J (1983) The pricing of call and put options on foreign exchange. J Int Money Financ 2:239–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray S (1996) Modeling the conditional distribution of interest rates as a regime-switching process. J Financ Econ 42:27–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton J (1989) A new approach to the economic analysis of nonstationary time series and the business cycle. Econometrica 57:357–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ichiue H, Koyama K (2011) Regime switches in exchange rate volatility and uncovered interest rate parity. J Int Money Financ 30:1436–1450

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ismail MT, Isa Z (2007) Detecting regime shifts in Malaysian exchange rates. J Fundam Sci 3:211–224

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiang GJ (1998) Jump diffusion model of exchange rate dynamics: estimation via indirect inference. Working paper. University of Groningen, The Netherlands

    Google Scholar 

  • Jorion P (1988) On jump processes in the foreign exchange and stock market. Rev Financ Stud 1:427–445

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaminsky G (1993) Is there a peso problem? Evidence from the Dollar/Peso exchange rate. Am Econ Rev 83:450–472

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirikos DG (2000) Forecasting exchange rates out of sample: random walk v.s. Markov switching regimes. Appl Econ Lett 7:133–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin SK, Shyu SD, Wang SY (2013) Option pricing under stock market cycle with jump risks: evidence from Dow Jones industrial average and S&P 500 index. Working paper

  • Lowell J, Neu CR, Tong D (1998) Financial crises and contagion in emerging market countries. RAND Working paper MR-962

  • Marsh IW (2000) High-frequency Markov switching models in the foreign exchange market. J Forecast 19:123–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meng XL, Rubin DB (1991) Using EM to obtain asymptotic variance-covariance matrices: the SEM algorithm. J Am Stat Assoc 86:899–909

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1973) An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 41:867–887

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton R (1976) The impact on option pricing of specification error in the underlying stock price returns. J Financ 31:333–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mussa M (1979) The two-sector model in terms of its dual: a geometric exposition. J Int Econ 9:513–526

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neely CJ (2011) A foreign exchange intervention in an era of restraint. Fed Reserve Bank St. Louis Rev 93:303–324

    Google Scholar 

  • Quandt R (1958) The estimation of the parameters of a linear regression system obeying two separate regimes. J Am Stat Assoc 53:873–880

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to the editor, Cheng-Few Lee and two anonymous referees for very valuable comments and suggestions. Shih-Kuei Lin acknowledges support from the NSC grant 100-2410-H-004-057 funded by the National Science Council and from Academia Sinica.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chien-Hsiu Lin.

Appendix: Change of measure in Esscher transform and currency option pricing under the RSMJ model

Appendix: Change of measure in Esscher transform and currency option pricing under the RSMJ model

Suppose the exchange rate follows the RSMJ with Eq. (19), and there is no risk premium occurring during the transition of the states, h B and h J are the parameters of the Brownian motion and the systematic jump risks in the Esscher transform, respectively. \(h_{B} = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {h_{B1} } & 0 \\ 0 & {h_{B2} } \\ \end{array} } \right]\); where h B1 and h B2 refer to the h B under the states 1 and 2, respectively. Because the jump risk is non-diversifiable, the exchange rate dynamics under the physical probability measure can be transferred to that under the risk neutral probability measure by the Esscher transform in this paper.

Let

$$A = \left\{ {\left( {\mu_{{q_{t} }} - \frac{1}{2}\sigma_{{q_{t} }}^{2} } \right)s + \sigma_{{q_{t} }} W(s)} \right\}\quad {\text{and}}\;B = \sum\limits_{m = 1}^{N(s)} {\ln Y_{m} } .$$
(27)

The Randon–Nikodym derivatives of the Brownian motion and the systematic jumps risk term, η B and η J are derived as follows:

$$\eta_{B} = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\exp \left\{ { - \frac{{h_{B1}^{2} \sigma_{1}^{2} s}}{2} + h_{B1} \sigma_{1} W(s)} \right\}} & 0 \\ 0 & {\exp \left\{ { - \frac{{h_{B2}^{2} \sigma_{2}^{2} s}}{2} + h_{B2} \sigma_{2} W(s)} \right\}} \\ \end{array} } \right],$$

where

$$\eta_{{Bq_{t} }} = \frac{{e^{{h_{{Bq_{t} }} A}} }}{{E(e^{{h_{{Bq_{t} }} A}} )}} = \frac{{\exp \left\{ {h_{{Bq_{t} }} (\mu_{{q_{t} }} - \frac{1}{2}\sigma_{{q_{t} }}^{2} )s + h_{{Bq_{t} }} \sigma_{{q_{t} }} W(s)} \right\}}}{{\exp \left\{ {h_{{Bq_{t} }} (\mu_{{q_{t} }} - \frac{1}{2}\sigma_{{q_{t} }}^{2} )s + \frac{{h_{{Bq_{t} }}^{2} \sigma_{{q_{t} }}^{2} s}}{2}} \right\}}} = \exp \left\{ { - \frac{{h_{{Bq_{t} }}^{2} \sigma_{{q_{t} }}^{2} s}}{2} + h_{{Bq_{t} }} \sigma_{{q_{t} }} W(s)} \right\}$$

and

$$\eta_{J} = \prod\limits_{m = 0}^{N(s)} {Y_{m}^{{h_{J} }} } \cdot e^{{ - \lambda s\xi^{{(h_{J} )}} }} .$$

Because the Brownian motion term and the systematic jumps risk term are independent from each other, the Brownian motion under the risk neutral measure can be transferred from that under the physical measure by change of measure:

$$dQ(W^{Q} (s)) = dP(W(s)) \cdot \eta_{{Bq_{t} }} = \frac{1}{{\sqrt {2\pi s} }}\exp \left\{ { - \frac{{\left[ {W(s) - h_{{Bq_{t} }} \sigma_{{q_{t} }} s} \right]^{2} }}{2s}} \right\}.$$
(28)

Next, we deal with the jump terms in the Esscher transform, which can be separated into two parts: jump sizes and jump frequencies. Given the number of jumps, n, the jump terms under the risk neutral measure can be rewritten from those under the physical measure by change of measure:

$$\begin{aligned} dQ(N^{Q} (s) & = n,\ln Y_{1}^{Q} , \ldots ,\ln Y_{n}^{Q} ) \\ & = dP(N^{Q} (s) = n)dP(\ln Y_{1}^{Q} , \ldots ,\ln Y_{n}^{Q} ) \cdot \prod\limits_{m = 1}^{N(s)} {Y_{m}^{{h_{J} }} } \cdot e^{{ - \lambda s\xi^{{(h_{J} )}} }} \\ & = dP(N^{Q} (s) = n)\left\{ {\prod\limits_{m = 1}^{n} {\left[ {f(\ln Y_{m} )\exp (h_{J} \ln Y_{m} )} \right]} } \right\}\left\{ {E\left[ {\exp (h_{J} \ln Y_{m} )} \right]} \right\}^{ - n} \left\{ {E\left[ {\exp (h_{J} \ln Y_{m} )} \right]} \right\}^{n} e^{{ - \lambda s\xi^{{(h_{J} )}} }} \\ \end{aligned}$$
(29)

According to the assumption of independent jump sizes, the individual jump size under the risk neutral measure is distributed as follows:

$$f^{Q} (\ln Y_{m} ) = \frac{1}{{\sqrt {2\pi \sigma_{y}^{2} } }}\exp \left\{ { - \frac{{\left[ {\ln Y_{m} - (\mu_{y} + h_{J} \sigma_{y}^{2} )} \right]^{2} }}{{2\sigma_{y}^{2} }}} \right\}.$$
(30)

Next, the probability of the number of jumps n under the risk neutral measure is evaluated as follows:

$$dQ(N^{Q} (s) = n) = \frac{{e^{{ - \lambda s\left( {\xi^{{(h_{J} )}} + 1} \right)}} \left[ {\lambda s\left( {\xi^{{(h_{J} )}} + 1} \right)} \right]^{n} }}{n!}.$$
(31)

Therefore, the jump sizes under the risk neutral measure follow a normal distribution with \(\ln Y_{m}^{Q} \sim N(\mu_{y} + h_{J} \sigma_{y}^{2} ,\sigma_{y}^{2} )\), and the number of jumps under the risk neutral measure follows a Poisson process with an arrival rate \(\lambda s\left( {\xi^{{(h_{J} )}} + 1} \right)\).

The Esscher transform parameters have to satisfy the martingale condition, which is derived under the RSMJ dynamics of the exchange rate with the risk neutral measure:

$$\mu_{{q_{t} }} - r + h_{{Bq_{t} }} \sigma_{{q_{t} }}^{2} + \lambda \left( {\xi^{{(h_{J} + 1)}} - \xi^{{(h_{J} )}} - \xi^{(1)} + \xi^{(0)} } \right) = 0.$$
(32)

From the infinite solutions of the Esscher parameters, we can find one condition to satisfy the martingale condition:

\(h_{B} = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\frac{{r - \mu_{1} }}{{\sigma_{1}^{2} }}} & 0 \\ 0 & {\frac{{r - \mu_{2} }}{{\sigma_{2}^{2} }}} \\ \end{array} } \right]\) and h J  = 0.

Given the jump size and the jump frequency under the risk neutral measure is:

\(\ln Y_{m}^{Q} \sim N(\mu_{y} ,\sigma_{y}^{2} )\) and \(N^{Q} (s)\sim Poi(\lambda s)\).

Under the risk neutral measure (also called the Merton measure, 1976), the dynamic process of exchange rates under the RSMJ can be solved in the following form:

$$\begin{aligned} S(T) & = \left( {S\left( 0 \right)\exp \left\{ {\int\limits_{0}^{T} {(r - r_{f} - \xi^{(1)} + \xi^{(0)} )dt} - \frac{1}{2}\int\limits_{0}^{T} {\sigma_{{q_{t} }}^{2} dt} + \int\limits_{0}^{T} {\sigma_{{q_{t} }} dW^{Q} \left( t \right)} + \sum\limits_{m = 1}^{n} {\ln Y_{m}^{Q} } } \right\}} \right) \\ & \mathop = \limits^{dist} S(0)\exp \left\{ {\left( {r - r_{f} - \xi^{(1)} + \xi^{(0)} } \right)T - \frac{1}{2}\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + \theta_{{k_{1} }} Z + \sum\limits_{m = 1}^{n} {\ln Y_{m}^{Q} } } \right\}, \\ \end{aligned}$$
(33)

where Z is an identically independent standard normal distribution and the weighted variance under the state q i is\(\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} = k_{1} \sigma_{1}^{2} + (T - k_{1} )\sigma_{2}^{2}\).\(\sum\nolimits_{m = 1}^{n} {\ln Y_{m}^{Q} }\) and \(\theta_{{k_{1} }} Z_{n} + \sum\nolimits_{m = 1}^{n} {\ln Y_{m}^{Q} }\) also follow normal distributions:\(\sum\nolimits_{m = 1}^{n} {\ln Y_{m}^{Q} } \sim N\left( {n\mu_{y} ,n\sigma_{y}^{2} } \right)\) and \(\theta_{{k_{1} }} Z + \sum\nolimits_{m = 1}^{n} {\ln Y_{m}^{Q} } \sim N\left( {n\mu_{y} ,\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + n\sigma_{y}^{2} } \right)\).Therefore, we can price a European-style call option, \(C_{RSMJ,T}^{{}} (0)\) with strike price K, the local and foreign risk-free interest rates, r and r f , and maturity date T as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} C_{RSMIJ} (0) & = e^{ - rT} E_{N(T)}^{Q} E_{D}^{Q} E_{{q_{0} }}^{Q} E^{Q} \left[ {\hbox{max} \left\{ {S(T) - K,0} \right\}\left| {N^{Q} (T) = n,q_{0} = i,D = k_{1} } \right.} \right] \\ & = E_{N(T)}^{Q} E_{D}^{Q} E_{{q_{0} }}^{Q} \left\{ {S(0)e^{ - rT} E^{Q} \left[ {e^{{\ln \frac{S(T)}{S(0)}}} I_{{\left\{ {\ln \frac{S(T)}{S(0)} > \ln \frac{K}{S(0)}} \right\}}} \left| {N^{Q} (T) = n,q_{0} = i,D = k_{1} } \right.} \right]} \right\} \\ & - Ke^{ - rT} E_{N(T)}^{Q} E_{D}^{Q} E_{{q_{0} }}^{Q} \left\{ {E^{Q} \left[ {I_{{\left\{ {\ln \frac{S(T)}{S(0)} > \ln \frac{K}{S(0)}} \right\}}} \left| {N^{Q} (T) = n,q_{0} = i,D = k_{1} } \right.} \right]} \right\} \\ & = E_{N(T)}^{Q} E_{D}^{Q} E_{{q_{0} }}^{Q} \left\{ {A - B} \right\}. \\ \end{aligned}$$
(34)

The term A of Eq. (34) can be represented as:

$$A = S(0)e^{ - rT} E^{Q} \left[ {e^{{\ln \frac{S(T)}{S(0)}}} I_{{\left\{ {\ln \frac{S(T)}{S(0)} > \ln \frac{K}{S(0)}} \right\}}} \left| {N^{Q} (T) = n,q_{0} = i,D = k_{1} } \right.} \right] = S(0)e^{{ - r_{f} T + n\left( {\mu_{y} + \frac{{\sigma_{y}^{2} }}{2}} \right) - \lambda (\zeta^{(1)} - 1)T}} N(d_{{1k_{1} }} )$$

where \(N( \cdot )\) is the cumulative distribution function for a standard normal random variable,

$$d_{{1k_{1} }} = \frac{{\ln \frac{S(0)}{K} + (r - r_{f} - \lambda (\zeta^{(1)} - 1))T + \frac{1}{2}\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + n(\mu_{y} + \sigma_{y}^{2} )}}{{\sqrt {\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + n\sigma_{y}^{2} } }}.$$

The term B can be shown as:

$$Ke^{ - rT} E^{Q} \left[ {I_{{\left\{ {\ln \frac{S(T)}{S(0)} > \ln \frac{K}{S(0)}} \right\}}} \left| {N^{Q} (T) = n,q_{0} = i,D = k_{1} } \right.} \right] = Ke^{ - rT} N(d_{{2k_{1} }} ),$$

where

$$d_{{2k_{1} }} = \frac{{\ln \frac{S(0)}{K} + (r - r_{f} - \lambda (\zeta^{(1)} - 1))T - \frac{1}{2}\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + n\mu_{y} }}{{\sqrt {\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + n\sigma_{y}^{2} } }} = d_{{1k_{1} }} - \sqrt {\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + n\sigma_{y}^{2} } .$$

Given the steady-state probability of the initial market state, π i ; the probability that over the T periods, k 1 periods are assigned to the state 1 conditional on the initial market state i, \(\gamma_{{T,k_{1} \left| {q_{0} = i} \right.}}\), we can further rewrite the pricing equation as:

$$C_{RSMJ,T} (0) = \sum\limits_{n = 0}^{\infty } {\sum\limits_{{k_{1} = 0}}^{T} {\sum\limits_{i = 1}^{2} {\pi_{i} \cdot \gamma_{{T,k_{1} \left| {q_{0} = i} \right.}} \frac{{e^{ - \lambda *} \left( {\lambda_{{}}^{*} } \right)^{n} }}{n!}\left[ {S(0)e^{{ - r_{f} T + n\left( {\mu_{y} + \frac{{\sigma_{y}^{2} }}{2}} \right) - \lambda (\zeta^{(1)} - 1)T}} N(d_{{1,k_{1} }} ) - Ke^{ - rT} N(d_{{2,k_{1} }} )} \right]} } } ,$$
(35)

where \(\lambda^{ * } = \lambda T\),

$$d_{{1,k_{1} }} = \frac{{\ln \frac{S(0)}{K} + (r - r_{f} - \lambda (\zeta^{(1)} - 1))T + \frac{1}{2}\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + n(\mu_{y} + \sigma_{y}^{2} )}}{{\sqrt {\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + n\sigma_{y}^{2} } }},$$

\(d_{{2,k_{1} }} = d_{{1,k_{1} }} - \sqrt {\theta_{{k_{1} }}^{2} + n\sigma_{y}^{2} }\), and N(x) is the cumulative distribution function for a standard normal random variable with upper integral limit x.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lin, CH., Lin, SK. & Wu, AC. Foreign exchange option pricing in the currency cycle with jump risks. Rev Quant Finan Acc 44, 755–789 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-013-0425-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-013-0425-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation