Skip to main content
Log in

Altruism from the house: the impact of home equity on charitable giving

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper exploits the dramatic increase in house prices in early 2000 and the panel nature of the data to investigate the effect of home equity on charitable giving. Using the Panel Study of Income Dynamics from 2001 to 2007, we find that a 10% increase in home equity increases a household’s contributions to charity by almost 1%. This is in contrast to the effect of non-housing wealth, which we estimate to be one tenth the magnitude. Our results are consistent with the consumption literature that reports a distinct effect of housing wealth that is significantly larger than that of financial wealth.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. http://www.givingusa.org/press_releases/gusa/GivingReaches300billion.pdf.

  2. http://www.nonprofitquarterly.org/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1462:unraveling-development-giving-usa-2009-the-annual-report-on-philanthropy&catid=145:simone-p-joyaux-acfre&Itemid=119.

  3. http://www.nccsdataweb.urban.org/kbfiles/680/CharGiv_06.pdf.

  4. http://www.foxnews.com/us/2010/06/09/report-americans-struggle-recession-charitable-giving-falls-percent/.

  5. The authors rule out such uses of the extracted money as purchasing new real estate or paying down higher interest debt, which suggests that the funds likely go towards consumption. However, many surveys of how capital gains, housing wealth loans and lines, and cash taken out at the time of refinancing are spent suggest that large fractions are consumed or spent on residential investment in the form of remodeling.

  6. Several studies address the question of joint determination of charitable giving and volunteering time. They test the interdependence of time and money devoted to charity (Duncan 1999; Brown and Lankford 1992; Apinunmahakul and Devlin 2008) and whether specific charitable donations act as complements or substitutes for one another (Clain and Zech 1999). While some studies find that monetary and time donations are substitutes (Gruber 2004), others find that they may be complements Andreoni et al. (1996).

  7. The other data that Wilhelm compare the PSID to are: Giving and Volunteering in the United States, General Social Survey, Giving and Volunteering In California, National Survey of Giving in Canada, Volunteering and Participating, and National Study of Philanthropy.

  8. Because the study asked the amount of donations for each specific type of charity, we sum the total amount donated for each of the types of organizations.

  9. The wealth variables are constructed as the sum of values of seven asset types (net business/farm profits, checking/savings, other real estate, stocks and mutual funds, vehicles, and other savings/assets not mentioned, net of any credit card debt.

  10. As a robustness check, we also perform our analysis including non-itemizers.

  11. Excluding owners that have non-positive equity drops 105 observations.

  12. The price of charity is defined as the marginal tax rate of income assuming no charitable contributions.

  13. Defined as log(y+ ((y^2+1)^1/2)).

  14. There were 495 observations that had negative values.

  15. Donations are recorded only if the total amount is greater than $25.

  16. Income is defined as taxable income, income from assets, earnings, and net profit from farm or business.

  17. Because there does not exist a sufficient statistic allowing the fixed effects to be conditioned out of the likelihood, we use a random effects model. We also model the data based on an OLS random effects specification for comparability. See “Appendix”.

  18. Since 94% of households report donating to charity in each year.

  19. Our elasticity estimate based on an ordinary least squares regression with random effects, however, is 1.68, which is more aligned with previous literature.

  20. This is somewhat lower than estimates found in other studies, although Bakija and Heim (2008), for example, do find a persistent income elasticity of 0.10 in their sample of households whose income is under $200,000—a sample comparable to most of the households in our study.

  21. The net wealth elasticity estimate is similar to estimates found by Dye (1978) and Feldstein and Clotfelter (1976).

  22. There is no general measure of fit for a Tobit random effects model.

  23. Because the PSID does not have a question that specifically asks whether the household took a cash-out refinance loan, we assume that a household took out a cash-out refinance loan if it has refinanced its loan and the mortgage balance subsequently increased.

  24. We thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion.

  25. These specifications exclude up to 10% of the original sample.

  26. These types of organizations were: other, international aid/peace, environment, neighborhood/community, culture/arts, and youth/family.

  27. Giving USA 2005, p. 137.

  28. http://www.online.wsj.com/article/SB108258738087189894.html.

  29. http://www.sfgate.com/cgi-bin/article.cgi?f=/c/a/2009/02/28/MN0K165OA5.DTL&tsp=1.

  30. Assuming average charitable giving of $2849.

References

  • Andreoni, J., Gale, W., & Scholz J. K. (1996). Charitable contributions of time and money. Working Paper, University of Wisconsin.

  • Apinunmahakul, A., & Devlin, R. A. (2008). Social networks and private philanthropy. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 309–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio, O., Blow, L., Hamilton, R., & Leicester, A. (2009). Booms and busts: Consumption, house prices and expectations. Economica, 76, 20–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakija, J., & Heim, B. (2008) How does charitable giving respond to incentives and income? Dynamic Panel Estimates Accounting for Predictable Changes in Taxation”, NBER Working Paper 14237.

  • Benjamin, J. D., Chinloy, P., & Jud, G. D. (2004). Real estate versus financial wealth in consumption. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 29, 341–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bostic, R., Gabriel, S., & Painter, G. (2009). Housing wealth, financial wealth, and consumption: New evidence from micro data. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 39, 79–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, E., & Lankford, H. (1992). Gifts of money and gifts of time: Estimating the effects of tax prices and available time. Journal of Public Economics, 47, 321–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J., & Cocco, J. (2007). How do house prices affect consumption? Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 591–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, C., Otsuka, M., & Slacalek, J. (2006) How large is the housing wealth effect? A new approach. NBER Working Paper 12746.

  • Case, K., Quigley, J., & Shiller, R. (2005). Comparing wealth effects: The stock market versus the housing market. Advances in Macroeconomics, 5, 1–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case, K., & Shiller, R. (2003). Is there a bubble in the housing market? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 299–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clain, S. H., & Zech, C. E. (1999). A household production analysis of religious and charitable giving. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 58, 923–946.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clotfelter, C. (1980). Tax incentives and charitable giving: Evidence from a panel of taxpayers. Journal of Public Economics, 13, 319–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Disney, R., Henley, A., & Jevons, D. (2002). House price shocks, negative equity and household consumption in the UK in the 1990s. Mimeo, University of Nottingham.

  • Duncan, B. (1999). Modeling charitable contributions of time and money. Journal of Public Economics, 72, 213–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dvornak, N., & Kohler, M. (2007). Housing wealth, stock market wealth and consumption: A panel analysis for Australia. The Economic Record, 83, 117–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dye, R. (1978). Personal charitable contributions: Tax effects and other motives. 1977 Proceedings of the 70th Annual Conference on Taxation, 311–317.

  • Feenberg, D. (1987). Are tax price models really identified: The case of charitable giving. National Tax Journal, 40, 629–633.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M., & Clotfelter, C. (1976). Tax incentives and charitable contributions in the United States. Journal of Public Economics, 5, 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girouard, N., & Blöndal, S. (2001). House prices and economic activity. OECD Economics Department Working Paper 279.

  • Greenspan, A., & Kennedy, J. (2005). Estimates of home mortgage originations, repayments, and debt on one to four family residences. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2005-41, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington DC.

  • Greenwood, D. T. (1988). Price and income elasticities of charitable giving: The effects of specification. Yale University Institute for Social and Policy Studies, No. 2134.

  • Gruber, J. (2004). Pay or pray? The impact of charitable subsidies on religious attendance. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2635–2655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, N. L. (1949). Systems of frequency curves generated by methods of translation. Biometrika, 36, 149–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, L. (1998). Are assets fungible? Testing the behavioral theory of life-cycle savings. Journal of Economic Organization and Behavior, 36, 59–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ludwig, A., & Sløk, T. (2004). The relationship between stock prices, house prices and consumption in OECD countries. Topics in Macroeconomics, 4, 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCarthy, J., & Steindel, C. (2006). Housing activity, home values, and consumer spending. In Proceedings of conference on bank structure and competition. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

  • Mian, A. R., & Sufi, A. (2009). House prices, housing wealth-based borrowing, and the U.S. household leverage crisis. Chicago Booth Research Paper No. 09-20.

  • Pharoah, C., & Tanner, S. (1997). Trends in charitable giving. Fiscal Studies, 18, 427–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Randolph, W. (1995). Dynamic income, progressive taxes, and the timing of charitable contributions. Journal of Political Economy, 103(4), 709–738.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skinner, J. (1989). Housing wealth and aggregate saving. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 19, 305–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steuerle, E. (1987). Charitable giving patterns of the wealthy. In T. Odendahl (Ed.), America’s wealthy and the future of foundations (pp. 203–221). New York NY: The Foundation Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilhelm, M. (2007). The quality and comparability of survey data on charitable giving. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 36, 65–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chau Do.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 7.

Table 7 Effect of house wealth on charitable donations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Do, C., Paley, I. Altruism from the house: the impact of home equity on charitable giving. Rev Econ Household 10, 375–393 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-011-9123-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-011-9123-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation