Skip to main content
Log in

Does Time-on-Market Measurement Matter?

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Time-on-market is one of the most commonly analyzed outcomes in the residential literature. However, existing research provides no consensus agreement on the actual definition of “time-on-market” and its calculation. Very little discussion of the numerous reasonable alternative definitions exists. To address this ambiguity, alternative definitions and related calculations of time-on-market are assessed. First, using multiple listing service data from a medium-sized United States city, five measures of time-on-market are modeled and across-model differences are evaluated. Second, using multiple listing service data from a large United States city, the importance of relisted properties in defining and assessing time-on-market is investigated. Results indicate that both time-on-market definition and the handling of relisted properties substantially influence model outcomes and the statistical significance of dependent variables. Results also suggest that much of the existing literature incorporating time-on-market warrants reevaluation using a consistent definition of marketing time and an adjustment for relisted properties.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Time-on-market is an important measure in residential real estate transaction and brokerage studies, such as Genesove and Mayer (1997), Glower et al. (1998), Knight (2002), Anglin et al. (2003), Rutherford et al.(2005), Turnbull et al. (2006), and Huang and Rutherford (2007).

  2. Some recent research acknowledges a disconnect between MLS-reported “time-on-market” and the fact that many listings do not actually transact under their initial listing terms and period.

  3. “Time-on-market” is used in this situation since it is the typical term used in a MLS.

  4. In practice, agents often say that “time-on-market” is the average number of days a property is on the market. In addition to being somewhat nebulous, this definition is inherently inaccurate when all properties do not sell during their initial listing period. For example, in the present market, it is not uncommon for fewer than 50 % of listings to transact.

  5. The problem is likely more acute in older data that was actually printed and then distributed. How the property listings were classified was very important in the pre-internet dissemination of information. For example, some multiple listing services had separate books for new listings and price changes. The noise in the older data is likely even greater since it is probable that researchers simply used a MLS generated time-on-market measure and did not even have actual listing, pending, and closed dates.

  6. It is certainly possible for an existing listing to be extended or for a withdrawn listing to be placed back on the market. In practice, this is rarely the case. The MLS from which the relisting data are drawn requires that such requests be made before the expiration date of the original listing, and there are no penalties for failure to do so.

  7. See also Munneke and Yavas (2001); Rutherford et al. (2005); Turnbull and Dombrow (2006); Turnbull et al. (2006); Huang and Rutherford (2007); and Rutherford et al.(2007). Levitt and Syverson (2008) correct for this flaw in their analysis, but they define a property as relisted if it comes back on the market within 180 days. Six full months seems a bit long to count a property as relisted, given how much market conditions can change in that period of time and the substantial changes that could be made to a residential property during such a time period. Through discussions with local practitioners, the common practice of excluding particular leads was identified. This refers to identifying by name particular individuals that had expressed an interest in the property during the expiring listing period. If that individual then enters negotiations during the exclusion period, the commission is earned by the listing broker who held the listing at the time of initial viewing. Locally, the generally accepted exclusion period seems to be 30 days, with the longest exclusion period set at 45 days. Given a natural break observed in the data at 48 days between prior listing expiration and relisting, the definition of a relisted property used in this study is 48 days.

  8. In discussion with authors of several of these prior studies, it is apparent that many of the studies, especially the earliest ones when data were less extensive and less available, used time-on-market numbers without fully knowing how they were calculated because that number was the only one available.

  9. Kiefer (1988) and Greene (1997) discuss the positive aspects of using non-linear distributional forms in modeling time-on-market. These researchers point out that the hazard techniques necessitated by the use of non-linear distributional forms, especially the Weibull or Exponential distributions, address issues with independent variables whose values vary over time and have non-normal error terms.

  10. The attributes associated with the NOMKT variable have been shown to be important in the literature so we include discussion here and use the NOMKT variable in the analysis. The empirical results are robust to the use or non-use of this factor.

  11. The sub-market data are available for review. A history of all listings for a specific property is required to create the relisting dataset. This data is normally not requested by, and therefore not provided to, academic researchers. The required data was available for the Miami-Dade MSA, so the focus of this section of the study turns to South Florida out of necessity.

  12. A property is considered to be relisted if it is placed back on the market within 48 days of the end of the prior listing. As noted earlier, Levitt and Syverson (2008) use 180 days in a similar definition. Please refer to footnote 6 for a more complete explanation of the choice of 48 days. Results were qualitatively unchanged when obtained for periods of 30 days and 60 days; these are available from the authors upon request.

  13. The DOP control differs from the control suggested by Anglin et al. (2003). Instead of hedonically suggested listing prices, the sales price is used to compute the overpricing control as 1–SP/ORIG_LP. This is the measure investigated by Allen and Dare (2006). It is also a control variable used by Herrin et al. (2004) and Turnbull and Dombrow (2006) in the same manner as in Eq. (2).

  14. The goal of this research is not to critique early researchers, but to highlight limitations in the data to which they had access and which may have limited empirical results. Data limitations are a fact of life for all real estate researchers, and in the present case, such limitations are merely referenced as a potential weakness in prior research that limited researchers’ ability to tie empirical results to theoretical constructs. Few of the early studies mention definitions and TOM is ambiguous as applied.

  15. The interested reader is referred to Johnson et al. (2007) for additional information on the probability of sale transaction metric.

References

  • Allen, M. T., & Dare, W. H. (2006). Charm pricing as a signal of listing price precision. Journal of Housing Research, 15(2), 113–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anglin, P. M., Rutherford, R. C., & Springer, T. M. (2003). The trade-off between selling price of residential properties and time-on-the-market: the impact of price setting. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 26(1), 95–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bajic, V. (1985). Housing-market segmentation and demand for housing attribute: some empirical findings. Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 13(1), 58–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benefield, J. D., Cain, C. L., Johnson, K. H. (2013). A critical review of literature utilizing simultaneous modeling techniques for property price and time-on-market, Auburn University Working Paper, 2013.

  • Benson, E. D., Hansen, J. L., Schwartz, A. L., Jr., & Smersh, G. T. (1998). Pricing residential amenities: the value of a view. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 16(1), 55–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Butler, R. V. (1980). Cross-sectional variation in the hedonic relationship for urban housing markets. Journal of Regional Science, 20(4), 439–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doss, C. R., & Taft, S. J. (1996). The influence of wetland type and wetland proximity on residential property values. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 21(1), 120–129.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genesove, D., & Mayer, C. J. (1997). Equity and time to sale in the real estate market. American Economic Review, 87(3), 255–269.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glower, M., Haurin, D. R., & Hendershott, P. H. (1998). Selling time and selling price: the influence of seller motivation. Real Estate Economics, 26(4), 719–740.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. (1997). Econometric analysis (3rd ed.). Upper Saddle River: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrin, W. E., Knight, J. R., & Sirmans, C. F. (2004). Price cutting behavior in residential markets. Journal of Housing Economics, 13(3), 195–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, J., & Rutherford, R. C. (2007). Who you going to call? Performance of realtors and non-realtors in a MLS setting. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(1), 77–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, K. H., Springer, T. M., & Brockman, C. M. (2005). Price effects of non-traditionally broker-marketed properties. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 31(3), 331–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, K. H., Benefield, J. D., & Wiley, J. A. (2007). The probability of sale for residential real estate. Journal of Housing Research, 16(2), 131–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalra, R., & Chan, K. (1994). Censored sample bias, macroeconomic factors, and time on market of residential housing. Journal of Real Estate Research, 9(2), 253–262.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiefer, N. M. (1988). Economic duration data and hazard functions. Journal of Economic Literature, 26(2), 646–679.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, J. R. (2002). Listing price, time on market, and ultimate selling price: causes and effects of listing price changes. Real Estate Economics, 30(2), 213–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kulshreshtha, S. N., & Gillies, J. A. (1993). Economic evaluation of aesthetic amenities: a case study of river view. Water Resources Bulletin, 29(2), 257–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, T. (1990). The econometric analysis of transition data. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., & Syverson, C. (2008). Market distortions when agents are better informed: the value of information in real estate transactions. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 90(4), 599–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacGreal, S., Adair, A., Brown, L., & Webb, J. R. (2009). Pricing and time on the market for residential properties in a major U.K. city. Journal of Real Estate Research, 31(2), 209–233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahan, B. L., Polasky, S., & Adams, R. M. (2000). Valuing urban wetlands: a property price approach. Land Economics, 76(1), 100–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mooney, S. P., & Eisgruber, L. M. (2001). The influence of riparian protection measures on residential property values: the case of the Oregon plan for salmon and watersheds. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 22(2/3), 273–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munneke, H. J., & Yavas, A. (2001). Incentives and performance in real estate brokerage. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 22(1), 5–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Netusil, N. R. (2005). The effect of environmental zoning and amenities on property values: Portland, Oregon. Land Economics, 81(2), 227–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poor, J. P., Boyle, K. J., Taylor, L., & Bouchard, R. (2001). Objective versus subjective measures of water clarity in hedonic property value models. Land Economics, 77(4), 482–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford, R. C., Springer, T. M., & Yavas, A. (2005). Conflicts between principals and agents: evidence from residential brokerage. Journal of Financial Economics, 76(3), 627–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford, R. C., Springer, T. M., & Yavas, A. (2007). Evidence of information asymmetries in the market for residential condominiums. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 35(1), 23–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seiler, M. J., Bond, M. T., & Seiler, V. L. (2001). The impact of world class Great Lakes water views on residential property values. The Appraisal Journal, 69(3), 287–295.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sirmans, C. F., Turnbull, G. K., & Dombrow, J. (1995). Quick house sales: seller mistake or luck? Journal of Housing Economics, 4(3), 230–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sirmans, G. S., MacDonald, L., & Macpherson, D. A. (2010). A meta-analysis of selling price and time-on-the-market. Journal of Housing Research, 19(2), 139–152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, G. K., & Dombrow, J. (2006). Spatial competition and shopping externalities: evidence from the housing market. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 32(4), 391–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, G. K., Dombrow, J., & Sirmans, C. F. (2006). Big house, little house: relative size and value. Real Estate Economics, 34(3), 439–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zuehlke, T. W. (1987). Duration dependence in the housing market. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 69(4), 701–709.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This representation is based in whole or in part on data supplied by the Charleston Trident Multiple Listing Service, Inc., courtesy of the Charleston Trident Association of REALTORS® Inc. Neither the Association nor its MLS guarantees or is in any way responsible for its accuracy. Data maintained by the Association or its MLS may not reflect all real estate activity in the market.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Justin D. Benefield.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Benefield, J.D., Hardin, W.G. Does Time-on-Market Measurement Matter?. J Real Estate Finan Econ 50, 52–73 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-013-9450-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-013-9450-z

Keywords

Navigation