1 Introduction

Climate change is widely regarded as one of the most vexing societal challenges of our time. The root cause of this challenge is the fundamental externality that arises when economic subjects do not internalize the full social cost of their greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. The continuing mismatch between the private and social costs of GHG emissions has arguably resulted in a large-scale global market failure.Footnote 1 Policymakers have begun to counteract this mismatch through a range of policy tools, such as carbon pricing and direct emissions regulations.Footnote 2 At the same time, relatively little is known about the potential impact of a disclosure mandate that merely requires firms to report their carbon footprint without any obligation to reduce these emissions over time.Footnote 3

A central axiom in management accounting, dating back to Drucker (1954), postulates that “what gets measured, also gets managed.” Inside firms, this linkage is plausible and well-documented to the extent that the variable of interest is included in the firm’s performance evaluation and incentive system.Footnote 4 The linkage between measurement and subsequent improvements becomes more tenuous in a market setting where firms disclose the variable of interest to the general public. It appears plausible that a mere requirement to report carbon emissions will “incentivize” firms to improve upon their subsequent emissions (even though such improvements are costly), provided that firms also anticipate being “rewarded” by different stakeholder groups for these improvements.

Numerous studies on Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) and Environmental, Social and Governance (ESG) activities have observed that improvements in outcome variables are often difficult to establish because there is no commonly accepted measurement framework, e.g., labor practices that are deemed sustainable.Footnote 5 The lack of a well-defined measurement framework also makes it difficult, if not practically impossible, to have subsequent outcomes verified by third parties.Footnote 6 In these respects, greenhouse gas emissions are a relative exception, as they involve physical measurements, the delineation of scope (e.g., so-called Scope 1 or Scope 2 emissions), and an aggregate score for multiple greenhouse gases in order to arrive at a measure of CO2 equivalents.

The main hypothesis examined in this paper is whether mandatory reporting entails a real GHG emission reduction effect, possibly because of stakeholder pressure on firms to subsequently “manage”—in the sense of Drucker (1954)—their carbon emissions. It seems plausible that firms will do so because multiple stakeholder groups, including customers, employees, and investors, regard corporate emissions as a negative firm attribute. In that sense, a disclosure mandate may create a “pillory” with regard to a firm’s carbon footprint.Footnote 7 As firms can point to improvements with regard to this publicly reported “bad” in the future, they will arguably improve their standing with different stakeholder groups.Footnote 8

Our study evolves around the Companies Act 2006 (Strategic Report and Directors’ Report) Regulations 2013. This act imposed a mandate on publicly listed UK-incorporated firms to report their GHG emissions as part of their annual financial reports. Prior to this mandate, companies had an obligation to gather and report the emissions of their individual installations (i.e., production sites such as power plants or steel mills) that were regulated under the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) to a publicly available register.Footnote 9 Prior to 2013, there was no obligation for publicly listed UK firms to report their overall “carbon footprint” as the aggregate of their installation-level emissions in the annual corporate report. In that sense, the regulation increased transparency, as interested parties no longer had to trace emission figures at the installation level back to the parent companies owning the installation.

To examine the impact of the UK GHG emission disclosure mandate on subsequent emissions and financial performance, we adopt a difference-in-differences (DiD) approach surrounding the implementation of the Companies Act. We compare the difference between pre- and post-mandate emission data for affected firms with emission data for a sample of control firms. In our study, this comparison is made feasible by tracing the emissions of all installations, as reported to the central EU ETS registry, back to the firms in our sample for a ten-year time window around the year 2013. The treatment group in our DiD design consists of installations that are located in the UK or another European country but are ultimately owned by UK-incorporated, publicly listed companies.Footnote 10 The control group consists of installations that are ultimately owned by companies not subject to the 2013 act—that is, publicly listed firms in other EU countries.

Our results provide evidence of a significant reduction in GHG emissions following the disclosure mandate for firms in the treatment group relative to the control group. The effect is sizable insofar as firms subject to the mandate, on average, reduce their GHG emissions by about 8% between the pre- and the post-mandate periods.

The 2013 UK mandate also requires firms to disclose a carbon intensity variable that expresses total CO2-equivalent emissions in relation to some activity measure such as output, cost, or revenues. Such a ratio measure will be more informative about actual emission improvements for firms that have experienced substantial growth or contraction over time. We estimate the effect of the disclosure mandate on firms’ carbon intensity by considering both sales and cost of goods sold (COGS) as the activity variable in the denominator. We find that the firms in the treatment group exhibit a significant incremental reduction in carbon intensity of approximately 13% (10%) when the denominator in the carbon intensity ratio is COGS (sales). Finally, we provide evidence that our results are robust to alternative empirical design choices, to reliance on a balanced rather than unbalanced sample, and to a matched-sample approach.

The magnitude of the reduction in emissions and carbon intensity may appear surprising for two reasons. First, as mentioned above, the information about Scope 1 emissions at the level of individual installations was already available prior to the 2013 mandate, albeit in dispersed form. As such, the mandate arguably only “pilloried” the treated firms to the extent that firm-level emissions became more accessible and transparent. Second, more than two-thirds of the treated firms in our sample participated in the Carbon Disclosure Project (CDP), which provides a global forum for firms and/or their subsidiaries to supply voluntary information about their GHG emissions and ongoing efforts to reduce them.Footnote 11 There are no binding reporting standards or informational requirements for disclosures submitted to the CDP. A reflection of this lack of formal requirements is that the CDP rates the participating firms with a score regarding the credibility and comprehensiveness of their voluntary disclosures. One way to interpret the UK GHG reporting mandate is that the obligation to report total corporate Scope 1 and 2 GHG emissions forced the unravelling of a partial disclosure equilibrium that was in effect prior to 2013.

With regard to the financial impact of the 2013 disclosure mandate, it would be surprising to find that the regulation had improved the financial operating performance of the treated firms. If firms had anticipated such beneficial effects, they could have pre-committed to provide information on emission reductions in their annual reports. Thus, one would expect that abnormal efforts to reduce GHG emissions are costly. Firms can reduce emissions in the short and medium run through a range of measures, including input substitutions and the outsourcing of carbon intensive activities. The well-known study by McKinsey (2009) suggests that some industries may have access to low-cost abatement options, such as installation retrofits.Footnote 12 Yet, there does not seem to be a general understanding of the abatement potential (in terms of tons of CO2 saved) of these low cost options.

Any cost increases associated with abnormal carbon reduction efforts could be partially offset by higher sales. Such revenue increases could simply reflect pricing power that allows firms to pass on the increase in their production costs. At the same time, and in line with our notion of “stakeholder pressure,” any differential increase in sales could also reflect that firms reporting significant carbon emission reductions in their annual reports attain greater loyalty from their customers.

Testing the hypothesis of a net-zero effect on revenues and cost, our DiD analysis shows that the treated firms do not experience a significant incremental impact in terms of their gross margins following the 2013 regulation. In separate explorations of the overall effect of the mandate on financial operating performance, our regression results indicate that the treated firms exhibit a small, but statistically insignificant, increase in both production costs and sales relative to the firms in the control group. The same conclusion emerges for capital expenditures that may have been undertaken to achieve the emission reductions. Taken together, our findings indicate that the disclosure requirement for publicly listed UK firms does not lead to a deterioration in their financial operating performance.

The final part of our analysis explores cross-sectional variation among the treated firms in their response to the disclosure requirement. In this part, we exploit the information available at the individual installation rather than the aggregate firm level. Specifically, we construct a complexity index that ranks firm heterogeneity in terms of the number of installations firms operate, the percentage of emissions these firms incur abroad, and the number of sectors in which firms are active. Our findings indicate that firms with a higher complexity score tend to reduce emissions at a lesser rate than their less complex counterparts.

Several other contemporaneous studies have examined the effects of mandatory reporting on corporate GHG emissions. Closest to our study are papers by Jouvenot and Krueger (2020), Grewal (2021), and Tomar (2019), the first two of which also focus on the UK disclosure mandate for GHG emissions in 2013. To quantify the impact of the mandate on subsequent emission levels, Jouvenot and Krueger (2020) rely on voluntarily disclosed information in the CDP database and on emission estimates issued by private organizations that track corporate GHG emissions. In contrast, our analysis relies on the granular, time-consistent, and verified data provided to the European Union Transaction Log (EUTL) register at the level of individual production sites, both prior to and after the mandate. Beyond the impact of the mandate on actual emissions, our study examines the impact on financial operating performance, while Jouvenot and Krueger (2020) study the consequences of the mandate on investments by large institutional investors, on media coverage, and on stock prices.

In a study complementary to ours, Grewal (2021) focuses on firms that were already reporting information about their carbon emissions to the Carbon Disclosure Project (CDP). Grewal (2021) establishes that, following the 2013 regulation, the subset of treated UK firms reports larger emission reductions than their counterparts not subject to the regulation. Furthermore, the incremental effect is more pronounced for firms with a relatively high level of pre-mandate emissions. These findings are consistent with our interpretation that the reporting mandate has an additional “pillory effect” beyond the information that firms already disclosed through channels like the CDP. In contrast to our approach, though, Grewal’s (2021) analysis considers self-reported emission levels both before and after the mandate, rather than the emission figures verified under the European ETS system.

Tomar (2019) studies the effect of a regulation that obligates large US production facilities to report their emissions to the US Environmental Protection Agency. In contrast to the UK regulation, however, there was, and still is, no requirement that US firms disclose their emissions in the aggregate as part of the annual report. Thus, the post-mandate disclosure requirement in Tomar’s study is similar to the pre-mandate setting that UK firms faced on account of the EU ETS regulations prior to the 2013 act. Regarding pre-treatment emission levels, Tomar (2019) develops an estimation technique for both the treatment and the control group. At the same time, Tomar’s main conclusions, like those of the other two studies discussed above, are broadly consistent with our first result that a disclosure mandate resulted in a significant reduction in subsequent GHG emissions.

Beyond the issue of GHG emissions, our study adds to the broader literature on the real effects of disclosure mandates regarding environmental and hazardous outcomes. Christensen et al. (2017) provide evidence that the Dodd-Frank Act provision requiring firms engaged in natural resource extraction to report on mine accidents and citations on mines in their annual reports did lead to improved worker safety in the mines of the regulated firms.Footnote 13 In another recent study, Chen et al. (2018) show that mandatory CSR reporting decreases local pollution levels, i.e., wastewater and sulfur dioxide (SO2) emissions, in Chinese cities in which firms affected by the CSR mandate are located. Chen et al. also argue that the CSR mandate was associated with a decrease in firms’ accounting rates of return.

Similar to the setting in Christensen et al. (2017) and Chen et al. (2018), our central hypothesis is that the disclosure mandate increases transparency and thereby creates pressure on management to improve the outcome variable in question. In case of mine safety or local environmental pollution, the hypothesized “pillory effect” is highly plausible because the reported information will be of interest to local media outlets and analysts. In contrast, with global pollution, the intensity of stakeholder pressure is less clear because the costs associated with GHG pollution, and therefore the benefits of reducing them, are distributed globally and thus affect local stakeholders only proportionally.Footnote 14

The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 introduces the regulatory background and develops the hypotheses to be tested. Section 3 describes the research design. Section 4 presents the results. Section 5 presents sensitivity and additional analyses. We conclude in Section 6.

2 Regulatory background and hypothesis development

2.1 Regulatory background

The Companies Act 2006 (Strategic Report and Directors’ Report) Regulations 2013 were presented to the UK Parliament by the Department for Business, Innovation and Skills (BIS) in June 11, 2013. The act was published in August 2013 and came into effect on October 1, 2013. Accordingly, “listed companies” are required to disclose their direct and indirect GHG emissions in their annual reports. Section 385 (2) of the act defines a listed company as a UK-incorporated company whose equity shares are listed on the Main Market of the London Stock Exchange, an exchange in a European Economic Area state, the New York Stock Exchange, or Nasdaq. The act applies to all fiscal years ending on or after September 30, 2013.

In particular, the 2013 act requires that companies disclose, in the Directors’ Report, their direct (Scope 1) and indirect (Scope 2) GHG emissions during the last 12 months. Direct emissions are those caused by the combustion of fuels and the operation of production facilities. Indirect emissions are those resulting from the purchase of electricity, heat, steam, or cooling. The following greenhouse gases are to be included in the report: carbon dioxide (CO2), methane (CH4), nitrous oxide (N2O), hydrofluorocarbons (HFCs), perfluorocarbons (PFCs), and sulfur hexafluoride (SF6). Companies are not required to provide individual emission figures for each of the greenhouse gases listed. Instead, they are asked to report the aggregate annual quantity of GHG emissions in tCO2eq, with the weights determined according to the weights set by the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.Footnote 15 In addition to the total Scope 1 and Scope 2 tCO2eq, companies must report a carbon intensity metric that relates emissions to some activity measure such as sales or cost of goods sold.

In addition to GHG emissions, the act imposes disclosure requirements pertaining to the diversity of directors, senior managers, and other employees as well as broader social and human rights issues. UK companies also face new obligations to report on environmental matters and developments that are likely to affect their business in the future. In Appendix A, we provide an overview of the new reporting items. While there is no indication that any of these reporting requirements confound our results, we cannot rule out that the broader environmental reporting mandate might also have influenced the propensity of the UK firms to reduce their carbon emissions.

The GHG disclosure mandate does not prescribe a specific method for calculating GHG emissions, but it requires the use of “robust and accepted methods” (DEFR 2013) and recommends a “widely recognized independent standard” (DEFR 2013). It encourages companies to “use relevant information from other domestic and international regulatory reporting processes” (DEFR 2013), such as data collected through the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS), the approach taken in this study.

The data collected under the auspices of the EU ETS is publicly available in the European Union Transaction Log (EUTL) register, which provides information at the installation level, including its identification, operator, NACE code, and the activity type it is assigned to in the EU ETS (e.g., production of bulk chemicals or combustion of fuels). We refer to the emissions reported to the EUTL as actual (Scope 1) emissions. While the actual volume of GHG in the flue gases of a particular facility is inherently difficult to track in real time, we view the detailed Monitoring, Reporting and Verification (MRV) framework adopted by the European Union as a fairly precise method for determining actual emissions. Specifically, the MRV regulations describe (i) the allowable method for calculating the emissions by different facilities given their activity levels (Monitoring), (ii) the firms’ reporting requirements (Reporting), and (iii) the external parties that national regulators can accredit as verifiers (Verification). Finally, the reported and verified emissions are subject to confirmation by an independent reviewer. These detailed regulations are intended to prevent underreporting of emissions by firms, which would allow them to purchase fewer emission allowances. This standardized measurement appears to have been unchanged in the years surrounding the UK disclosure mandate.

Since its introduction in 2005, the EU ETS has become the world’s largest multinational emissions trading system.Footnote 16 This cap-and-trade mechanism covers industries that account for about 45% of the European Union’s GHG emissions (Ellerman et al. 2016).Footnote 17 The remaining emissions not covered under the ETS system come primarily from the transportation, residential, and agricultural sectors (DECC 2016). Installations are covered by the EU ETS if they include a facility with a rated thermal input of at least 20 MW—enough to supply about 15,000 households with electricity at a given point in time—or if they fall into one or several of the following manufacturing segments: oil refineries, coke ovens, iron and steel, cement clinker, glass, lime, bricks, ceramics, pulp, paper and board, aluminum, petrochemicals, ammonia, nitric, adipic and glyoxylic acid production (European Commission 2015). Due to these rules, EU ETS coverage is concentrated in the sectors of energy supply and industrial manufacturing, covering approximately 79% of all UK emissions in 2014. Finally, note that the implementation of the act took place in the same year as the transition of the EU ETS to its third trading period, which covered the years 2013–2020.Footnote 18 The underlying scheme generating the emission data used in this paper hence spans two trading periods, and the transition to the third period took place concurrently to the introduction of the act. In Appendix B, we discuss these concurrent changes in more detail. We believe none affects our treatment and control group differentially.

Annual emissions by installations vary widely, ranging from a few thousand tons per year at small installations to several million tons at large coal power plants. The average (mean) UK installation covered by the EU ETS had emissions of about 100,000 tons of CO2 equivalents during our sample period.

From an inference perspective, there are several benefits to our approach of tracking direct (Scope 1) GHG emissions from individual installations according to the EU ETS data. Most importantly, the reported figures were measured and audited consistently both before and after the UK disclosure mandate went into effect. Unlike other studies, such as Tomar (2019), we therefore do not have to estimate a firm’s emissions prior to the reporting mandate. In the context of our disclosure study, there is an additional advantage to focusing on Scope 1 emissions as the outcome variable. As explained in more detail in Section 3.5, UK power producers were subject to sector-specific emission charges and therefore had additional financial incentives to reduce their Scope 1 emissions during our observation window. Any such improvements will therefore carry through as improvements in the Scope 2 emissions of UK based installations that purchase electricity from the grid. If emissions are measured as the total of Scope 1 and Scope 2 emissions, a reduction in a firm’s carbon emissions after the mandate could therefore be merely the result of lower Scope 1 emissions by the upstream electricity producers.

To examine changes in emissions at the firm level, we assign all installations to their respective owners and aggregate the emissions data at the installation level for each firm. As illustrated in Fig. 1, the mapping from installations to firms (mathematically, a function) is carried out for both the treated UK-headquartered firms and the control group of firms that were not subject to the mandate.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Mapping of installations to firms. This figure shows the mapping of data at the installation level (as reported in the EU ETS) to treatment and control group firms. Using information on the (ultimate) owner of each installation, we map installations to either a treatment or a control group firm. The link between the installation owner and the ultimate owner (i.e., firm in our sample) is established by the Ownership Links and Enhanced EUTL Dataset Project (OLP), which provides the name and Bureau-van-Dijk identification number of an installation’s ultimate parent company

We emphasize that in the context of our study the disclosure mandate did not make additional information publicly available, as the emissions of the treated firms were already accessible to the general public, albeit in a rather fragmented form, through the EUTL register. In essence, the informational effect of the disclosure mandate was to increase transparency, because an interested observer no longer had to carry out the mapping shown in Fig. 1 to calculate a firm’s overall Scope 1 emissions.

2.2 Hypothesis development

The hypotheses tested in this paper pertain both to changes in GHG emissions and to changes in the financial operating performance of the firms subject to the UK disclosure mandate. Broadly, our approach is consistent with the so-called targeted disclosure cycle theory (Fung et al. 2007). Accordingly, disclosures influence the behavior of receivers (stakeholders), leading to real effects in the variables to be disclosed in the future. The information providers anticipate these behavioral changes and take actions that enable more favorable disclosures.

In a recent survey article, Hombach and Sellhorn (2019) lay out a set of criteria for corporate reporting mandates to have real effects, that is, effects on the variables that are being disclosed. Aside from sufficiently precise reporting standards and compliance requirements, the reporting variables in question must generate additional public information, or at least increase transparency about the variable in question. In order for real effects to emerge from a reporting mandate, Hombach and Sellhorn (2019) also posit that the disclosed information must be broadly value relevant, possibly by illuminating potential future risks to the business. Finally, management must have both the discretion and the motivation to subsequently improve the outcome variable.

The preceding criteria all appear to be met by the UK 2013 disclosure mandate. In addition to a specific reporting standard and the prospect of enforcement, it is plausible that multiple stakeholder groups of the treated firms, including customers, employees and capital providers, view the firm’s carbon footprint as a negative. Because of the externality associated with the firm’s emissions on the world’s climate, these constituents would intrinsically prefer a lower carbon footprint, though they are likely to understand that certain emissions levels are unavoidable in the short run if the firm is to remain competitive in its product markets.

If the firms subject to the 2013 carbon disclosure mandate did indeed reduce their emissions more than the control group, the natural follow-on question is whether these efforts had a tangible impact on financial operating performance. On the benefit side, firms may anticipate that potential production cost increases can at least be partially passed on to consumers. While the possibility of pass-through generally depends on a firm’s cost structure and pricing power, a tangible reduction in publicly reported carbon emissions will arguably improve the firm’s public image. That, in turn, may lead to greater customer loyalty and thus a lower price elasticity of demand for customers who regard the firm’s carbon footprint as a negative attribute.Footnote 19 From that perspective, emission reductions in the interest of “stakeholder capitalism” would at least be partially aligned with the interests of shareholders.

Another stakeholder group that may react favorably to improvements in reported carbon emissions are the firm’s employees. For the same reasons as articulated in connection with customers, some employees will be intrinsically concerned about the climate-damaging effects of the firm’s emissions. This group will tend to identify more strongly with an organization that can publicly and credibly claim to be innovative and progressive on the issue of climate change. To the innovating firms, the potential benefit from such an improvement in public perception is that ceteris paribus less compensation may be required to retain valued employees.

Finally, management of the firms in our treatment group may anticipate penalties by the capital markets unless improvements in carbon emissions can be claimed in the time periods following a disclosure mandate. In recent years, institutional equity investors have become increasingly vocal that meaningful sustainability practices are becoming a major criterion for the inclusion of firms in their portfolios. A potential penalty for firms that are viewed as stagnant in their emission levels (or other sustainability activities) is that they may be “shunned” by some investor groups, leading to an increase in their cost of equity capital.Footnote 20 Kraus and Amir (2010) and Friedman and Heinle (2016) develop formal models wherein investors, in equilibrium, effectively exert pressure on management to improve a firm’s sustainability practices.Footnote 21 The preference structure of these institutional investors may directly reflect the intrinsic preferences of their capital providers. Some institutional investors have also explicitly stated that they view sustainability practices as an effective mitigation strategy with regard to future financial risks, specifically the risk of carbon intensive assets becoming economically impaired.Footnote 22

Arguments suggesting that the real effect of the UK mandate could be minor include the possibility that the added transparency resulting from the disclosure requirement was inconsequential insofar as concerned parties could already access the EU transaction log prior to the mandate. Furthermore, with some additional information gathering effort, interested parties could trace the emissions from individual installations back to the parent companies owning the installations (Fig. 1).

We also note that a substantial share of the treatment firms in our sample did already report information about their GHG emissions to the Carbon Disclosure Project prior to 2013. These disclosures, however, are neither subject to binding reporting standards nor verified by a third party.Footnote 23 Participation in the CDP has always been voluntary and therefore reflects self-selection by the participating firms.Footnote 24 Nonetheless, as emphasized in Grewal’s (2021) study, these disclosures may already have conveyed material firm-level information about emissions ahead of the act.Footnote 25 Finally, while the treated firms may indeed have perceived their annual emissions reports as a “pillory,” the actual reduction potential available to them in the short and medium run, i.e., over a period of five or six years in our post-mandate observation window, may have been limited. This may be especially plausible because many of the treated firms were already subject to carbon pricing under the EU ETS system and therefore already had an incentive to adjust their production processes in the direction of more energy- and carbon-efficiency.

Mindful of the preceding countervailing considerations, we nonetheless state the following hypothesis.

  • H1: Firms subject to the UK mandate for annual disclosure of GHG emissions attain a larger reduction in their Scope 1 emissions than firms not subject to the mandate.

The Companies Act 2006 (Strategic Report and Directors’ Report) Regulations 2013 also require firms to disclose a carbon intensity variable that relates raw emissions of CO2 equivalents to a meaningful indicator of production activity. Thus, the carbon intensity variable should indicate whether a reduction in emissions can be attributed to a mere reduction in production volume, or, conversely, whether an increase in emissions can be attributed to production growth. For the denominator in the carbon intensity measure, we consider both sales and cost of goods sold, noting that, for the firms in our treatment group, both of these variables were arguably affected by the disclosure mandate of 2013. In direct analogy to hypothesis H1, we hypothesize that the UK disclosure mandate of 2013 also had a real effect on the carbon intensity of the treated firms.

  • H2: Firms subject to the UK mandate for annual disclosure of GHG emissions attain a larger reduction in their carbon intensity than firms not subject to the mandate.

Our next hypothesis pertains to the financial performance of the treated firms. In order to reduce their carbon footprint, firms will presumably incur higher production costs. The magnitude and shape of the individual abatement cost curves, however, appear difficult to gauge, and are likely to vary considerably by industry. Several emission reduction measures will conceivably be available to firms in the manufacturing sector in the short and medium run. For instance, onsite fossil fuel power plants can be idled, with the requisite power and heat then procured from outside vendors. This would induce a shift from Scope 1 to Scope 2 emissions, with firms likely to care primarily about their “own” Scope 1 emissions.Footnote 26

Additional reduction measures include possible input substitutions that reduce the reliance on carbon-intensive materials like coal. For production processes requiring high operating temperatures, for instance, firms in carbon-intensive industries like steel and cement can switch from using coal or oil as a heating agent to electricity or less carbon-intensive agents like natural gas or hydrogen. Finally, holding output and production processes constant, many businesses will be in a position to reduce their fossil-fuel consumption and, thus, their emissions through investments in equipment that is more energy efficient.

The impact of alternative carbon reduction measures on overall manufacturing costs has to date not been estimated reliably at the level of individual industries. The carbon abatement curves by McKinsey (2009) suggest that, for moderate GHG reductions, firms will be able to identify considerable “low hanging fruit” with a corresponding small cost per ton of CO2 abated. Even if the cost per ton abated were to assume an extremely high value of say 100 euro per ton, the median firm in our sample, with carbon emissions of one million tons per year, would only experience a 10 million euro increase in manufacturing costs if it were to reduce emissions by 10 %. Furthermore, the impact of any such measures on a firm’s gross margin percentage (defined as sales minus cost of goods sold divided by sales) would be offset by any corresponding sales revenue increases. The usual possibilities of a cost pass-through may be enhanced for firms that demonstrate improvements in their carbon footprint in the post-mandate period on account of greater customer loyalty expressing itself in a lower price elasticity of demand.

The combination of cost increases that are likely to be minor in comparison to overall production costs and the potential for improved customer loyalty due to emission reductions leads us to the following hypothesis.

  • H3: Firms subject to the UK mandate for annual disclosure of GHG emissions exhibit no change in their gross margins compared to firms not subject to the mandate.

Since the firms in our treatment group represent a wide cross-section of UK firms, it is natural to ask whether certain subgroups did achieve carbon emission reductions that differed substantially from the group average. In this context, we differentiate among firms according to the number of installations they own, the percentage of GHG emissions they incur outside of the UK, and the number of sectors they are active in. We use these three variables as the basis of a complexity score, and hypothesize that less complex firms, on average, achieve larger GHG emission reductions following the 2013 mandate.

Our intuitive reasoning underlying the following hypothesis is that less complex firms will, all else equal, find it easier to identify emission reductions that can be achieved across the board. UK-headquartered firms with a larger conglomerate structure could arguably also find it more difficult to incentivize country managers to implement local emission reductions. Finally, such firms may perceive a lesser benefit in terms of their standing with different stakeholder groups due to an overall improvement in GHG emissions as reported by the UK parent company.

  • H4: Firms subject to the UK mandate with a higher complexity score reduce their GHG emissions by a smaller percentage than their UK counterparts with a lower complexity score.

3 Research design and data

3.1 Empirical test: Hypothesis H1

We use the following firm-level staggered difference-in-differences approach to estimate the effect of the GHG emission disclosure mandate on actual emissions following the UK Companies Act:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\ E={\alpha}_0+{\alpha}_1\cdotp Post+{\alpha}_2\cdotp Post\cdotp Treat+\sum Control\ variables\\ {}+ Fixed\ effects\ for\ firms+ Fixed\ effects\ for\ years+ Industry\ time\ trends+\varepsilon\ \end{array}} $$
(1)

All variables are defined in Table 1. Our dependent variable E indicates the natural logarithm of CO2-equivalent GHG emissions at the aggregate level of the firm owning the installation (as illustrated in Fig. 1). Emission data for one firm-year observation are based on emission data on the portfolio of installations owned by the firm in a particular year.Footnote 27

Table 1 Definition of variables

Post is a binary variable indicating periods after the mandate for GHG emission disclosure. Our study is based on observations from the years 2009–2018. The mandate for GHG emission disclosure applies to all fiscal years ending on or after September 30, 2013. If a firm’s fiscal year ends before this date, we define the emissions reported for the calendar year 2013 as a pre-treatment observation. If a firm’s financial year ends on or after September 30, 2013, we define emissions reported for the calendar year 2013 as a post-treatment observation. As a consequence, the mandate to disclose GHG emissions applies to firms as of 2013 or 2014 (staggered implementation), depending on the respective fiscal year-end date.

Treat is an indicator variable that assumes the value of one if a firm was subject to the mandate and zero otherwise. As the control group, we use firms not subject to the mandate for GHG emission disclosure. Specifically, the control group consists of listed firms headquartered in other EU15 countries. Our primary variable of interest is α2 · Post · Treat. A significant negative coefficient on α2 indicates that, on average, the treated firms achieved an incremental reduction in emissions following the disclosure mandate.

In estimating Eq. (1), we include a set of time-variant control variables at the firm level to account for differences in firm characteristics that might influence a firm’s incentives and abilities to reduce emission levels. Specifically, we control for firm size, because larger firms might have a higher willingness and ability to reduce emissions, as they are more visible to the public and might have economies of scope or scale in reducing emissions. We also include asset intensity. Firms with a larger asset base may have to invest in new technologies to reduce carbon emissions, while firms with relatively fewer assets could facilitate emission reductions in the short term through operational changes. Another control variable is the price-to-book ratio, because future growth opportunities may be related to a firm’s ability to reduce its carbon emissions. We finally include leverage, to account for outside control by creditors and the financing potential for reducing emissions.

To account for different country-level developments between firms listed in the UK and EU countries, we control for countries’ GDP and changes in producer prices as measured by the Producer Price Index. To control for time-specific and firm-specific unobserved heterogeneity, we include firm and year fixed effects for all tests.Footnote 28 Year fixed effects capture annual effects that pertain to all firms, such as changes in gasoline prices.Footnote 29 Finally, we include yearly time trends for the industry in which a firm operates, where we define industries based on the SIC 1 sector classification.Footnote 30 Industry trends capture the industry-specific developments over time, e.g., increasing prices of inputs specific to certain industries.

To reduce the influence of outliers, we winsorize all continuous variables at the 1st and 99th percentiles.Footnote 31 We draw our inferences based on standard errors that are two-way clustered by country (12 clusters) and year (10 clusters), reflecting that all installations of a UK-listed and incorporated firm are subject to the mandate, independent of the actual geographic location or industry classification of an installation.Footnote 32

3.2 Empirical test: Hypothesis H2

To estimate the effects of the GHG emission disclosure mandate on carbon intensity, we run the following regression at the firm level:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l} CI={\beta}_0+{\beta}_1\cdotp Post+{\beta}_2\cdotp Post\cdotp Treat+\sum Control\ variables\\ {}+ Fixed\ effects\ for\ firms+ Fixed\ effects\ for\ years+ Industry\ time\ trends+\varepsilon \end{array}} $$
(2)

Table 1 again lists the formal definitions of all variables. The dependent variable measures carbon intensity, which is defined as the natural logarithm of emissions to the cost of goods sold (COGS). Thus, carbon intensity expresses the tons of CO2 equivalent per euro of goods that the firm sold in a particular year. As before, we employ a staggered difference-in-differences approach with the same regressors as in Eq. (1). In a variant of Eq. (2), we use the natural logarithm of emissions to sales as our alternative carbon intensity measure.Footnote 33 We estimate our regressions for H2 only at the firm level because production costs and sales data are not available at the installation level.

3.3 Empirical test: Hypothesis H3

To test the impact of the disclosure mandate on gross margins, we estimate the following regression at the firm level:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l} GM={\gamma}_0+{\gamma}_1\cdotp Post+{\gamma}_2\cdotp Post\cdotp Treat+\sum Control\ variables\\ {}+ Fixed\ effects\ for\ firms+ Fixed\ effects\ for\ years+ Industry\ time\ tr ends+\varepsilon \end{array}} $$
(3)

Here, GM represents the gross margin, defined as sales minus cost of goods sold, scaled by sales.Footnote 34 Again, we employ a staggered difference-in-differences approach. Post and Treat are defined as before. The variable of interest is Post · Treat. According to H3, we expect no significant coefficient on Post · Treat. All control variables and fixed effect variables are as explained above.

3.4 Empirical test: Hypothesis H4

To test how a firm’s complexity influences the impact of the disclosure mandate on GHG emissions, we estimate the following regression at the firm level:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}E={\delta}_0+{\delta}_1\cdotp Post+{\delta}_2\cdotp Post\cdotp Treat+{\delta}_3\cdotp Post\cdotp Treat\cdotp Complexity\\ {}\begin{array}{l}+{\delta}_4\cdotp Post\cdotp Complexity+\sum Control\ variables+ Fixed\ effects\ for\ firms\\ {}+ Fixed\ effects\ for\ years+ Industry\ time\ trends+\varepsilon\ \end{array}\end{array}} $$
(4)

Here, Complexity is an aggregate score that relies on information regarding the firms’ installations, as recorded in the EU ETS registry data. Specifically, we compute the complexity score by conducting a principal component analysis using the following three variables: the firm’s total number of installations, percentage of emissions abroad, and the number of sectors in which it has active installations. We rely on the first principal component of the component analysis and measure the score using pre-treatment period values.Footnote 35 A higher score indicates that a firm has a more complex operating structure. To test H4, we interact the DiD coefficient Post · Treat with the complexity score.

3.5 Data

Table 2 delineates the sample selection process. Our starting sample comprises all EU ETS installations with emission data for the period 2009–2018 (14,003 installations). We first assign all installations to their ultimate owner. Figure 1 illustrates the assignment of installations to firms. In a first step, we exclude all installations where data on the ultimate owner is missing, because in these cases we are not able to assign installations to the treatment or control group. The link between the installation and the ultimate corporate owner is established by the Ownership Links and Enhanced EUTL Dataset Project (OLP).Footnote 36 The OLP provides the name and Bureau-van-Dijk identification number (BvD-ID) of an installation’s parent company. Next, we drop installations owned by firms with missing information on the fiscal year end in the BvD Orbis database. These steps lead to a sample of 6,327 installations owned by 1,994 unique firms.

Table 2 Sample selection

Next, we limit our sample to installations owned by firms from EU15 countries. As we only observe emissions regulated under the EU ETS, we focus on European firms for all tests. This step results in a sample of 5,196 installations owned by 1,486 unique firms.

We also limit the sample to listed firms, because disclosure and emission reduction effects might differ between listed and unlisted firms. By restricting our sample to listed firms, we ensure the comparability of treatment and control firms.Footnote 37 This step leads to a sample of 2,274 installations owned by 197 unique firms.Footnote 38

We further exclude firms from countries with other confounding regulations.Footnote 39 During our sample period, only Ireland implemented an emission-related regulation (InsideIreland.ie 2009). We also exclude installations for which the ultimate owner changed during the sample period because, otherwise, the assignment of the treatment group might be biased. These two restrictions lead to a sample of 2,212 installations owned by 193 unique firms.

Our sample also excludes installations in the energy supply sector based on the NACE Rev.2 sector code 35. This exclusion reflects that, for this sector, the UK government implemented an additional policy to increase the EU ETS allowance price in 2013 (the so-called “Carbon Price Floor” [CPF]). The CPF applies to electricity producers (Hirst 2018) and provides an additional emission charge beyond the EU ETS. Thus, the inclusion of these installations would likely lead to results overstating the impact of the disclosure mandate.Footnote 40 This restriction leads to a sample of 1,224 installations owned by 175 unique firms.

Next, we exclude installations in case of maintenance as well as temporary or permanent shutdowns because these emission reductions are likely unrelated to the mandate to disclose GHG emissions.Footnote 41 To identify maintenance, we exclude installations if their minimum emission level over the sample period is less than 1% of their maximal emission level. We identify temporary or permanent shutdowns based on incomplete emission data over time.Footnote 42 This step leads to a sample of 754 installations owned by 140 unique firms.

To estimate disclosure effects at the firm level, we next aggregate installation-level emissions to the firm level. At the firm level, we exclude firm-years with missing data for estimating our specified regression models. Firm-level accounting data are taken from Worldscope Datastream. This leads to a sample of 1,268 firm-years from 130 unique firms. Finally, we exclude firms without at least one observation prior to and after the passage of the Companies Act, to ensure applicability of a difference-in-differences approach. This step leads to a final firm-level sample of 1,257 firm years from 127 unique firms. The final installation-level sample consists of 7,267 installation years from 729 unique installations. In this sample, 24 firms belong to the treatment group, and 104 firms belong to the control group. An average sample firm operates 5.74 unique installations.

Table 3 presents the sample composition by country. All our treatment group firms are incorporated in the UK, whereas most of our control group firms are incorporated in France, Germany, Spain, and Sweden.

Table 3 Sample composition

Given the exclusion of energy sector installations, the firms in our sample are mostly manufacturing firms: 548 firm-year observations belong to the SIC industry 2 (i.e. SIC 2000–2999), and 366 belong to the SIC industry 3 (i.e. SIC 3000–3999).

Table 4 reports descriptive statistics (Panel A) and correlations (Panel B) for our final sample. The average treatment (control) group firm in our sample produces yearly emissions of 807,641 (1,280,441) tCO2eq. We observe that treated firms emit less GHG, on average, and have a lower carbon intensity, a higher COGS, higher sales, and a higher gross margin than control firms. Due to a skewed distribution, we use log-transformed emissions, carbon intensity, COGS, and sales in our regression analyses. We also find that firms in the treatment group are larger and more highly leveraged and have higher asset intensity and price to book ratio compared to control group firms. With regard to the Pearson and Spearman correlations, we do not observe high correlations between the continuous control variables.

Table 4 Summary statistics

4 Results

4.1 Impact of the 2013 act on GHG emissions and carbon intensity

Table 5 reports our findings regarding the impact of the GHG disclosure mandate on subsequent GHG emissions. We also test the impact of the mandate on carbon intensity using two alternative definitions: the ratio of emissions to COGS, and the ratio of emissions to sales. By taking logarithms, we can interpret a transformed value of the corresponding coefficients as additive percentage changes.

Table 5 The effect of a GHG disclosure mandate on emissions and carbon intensity

Columns (I) and (II) in Table 5 present results of our estimations using installation-level emission data. While our main interest is at the firm level, the installation-level estimates establish a baseline result that allows us to assess possible effects of aggregating installation-level data to the firm level. Columns (I) and (II) present the findings without and with firm-level control variables, respectively. In all specifications, we use installation and year fixed effects and industry time trends.

In column (I) of Table 5 the coefficient on the variable of interest Post · Treatment is significantly negative (p: <0.05). This result is also sizable in economic terms, as affected firms on average decreased their GHG emissions by about 8%, compared to companies not affected by the act. The 8% estimate reflects that 1 - exp(−0.082) = 0.078. Controlling for differences in firm characteristics (column (II)) leads to a virtually unchanged estimate of −0.082. We note that the high adjusted R2 is due to the stringent fixed effects specification, which absorbs installation-specific and year-specific unobservable heterogeneity as well as industry trends. The installation-level results provide evidence for H1 that emissions of the treated firms decreased compared to installations owned by firms in the control group.

Columns (III) and (IV) in Table 5 present results analogous to those in columns (I) and (II), but at the firm level. These and all remaining firm-level regressions control for unobserved heterogeneity by including year and owner-specific fixed effects. We also account for industry-level trends at the one-digit SIC level. Column (III) reports estimates without further firm- or country-level controls. We again find a negative and significant coefficient estimate on Post · Treat (p: <0.01), indicating a reduction in GHG emissions for treated firms by about 9%. This reduction is comparable to the emission reduction of about 8% measured using installation-level emission data (column (I)), suggesting that the reduction in emissions occurs fairly evenly across installations owned by each firm. In the richer specification including further covariates (column IV), we control for the same firm-level covariates as in column (II) as well as for country-level control variables. Column (IV) corroborates the magnitude of the emission reduction obtained in the simpler model. It reports a similar estimated effect, about 8% (p: <0.05), when controlling for the firm-level variables: size, the ratio of fixed assets to total assets, leverage, and price-to-book value (PTB). The additional controls ln(GDP) and input prices account for potential differences in aggregate demand and cost developments, respectively. The analysis of firm-level emissions thus also supports hypothesis H1.

In the final set of regressions shown in Table 5, we estimate the effect of the act on firm-level carbon intensity. This dependent variable, defined as either emissions divided by COGS or emissions divided by sales, ensures that any observed emission reductions are not merely a consequence of reductions in production volume. Columns (V) and (VI) report the estimates when including all covariates. The findings are similar to those for ln(emissions), with estimated reductions in carbon intensity of about 13% (p: <0.05) when using COGS as the denominator and of about 10% (p: <0.05) when using sales as a denominator. These results indicate that the emission reductions were not mainly driven by a decline in output or capacity utilization.Footnote 43

The main assumption underlying the difference-in-differences approach is a common trend between treatment and control group firms (Roberts and Whited 2013). To examine whether a common pre-treatment trend exists for emissions and carbon intensities, we follow common approaches in the existing literature (Bertrand and Mullainathan 2003; Serfling 2016). Specifically, we replace the interaction terms Post · Treatment with separate interaction terms for each period relative to the implementation of the GHG mandate in 2013. We adjust time periods to reflect the staggered nature of the treatment. When estimating the model, insignificant pre-treatment coefficients close to zero indicate the validity of a common pre-treatment trend.

In our tests of parallel trends we focus on firm-level emissions and emission-intensity.Footnote 44 Fig. 2 shows the results for firm-level emissions. Values on the y-axis show point estimates and 90% confidence intervals. Values on the x-axis refer to the number of years removed from the start of the post-treatment period. The benchmark period is t = −1, i.e., the last pre-treatment year. Due to the staggered nature of the treatment, t = −1 is 2012 for many installations, and 2013 for others. Each point estimate shown in Fig. 2 therefore captures the difference in the emission levels between the treatment and control groups relative to t = −1. The pre-treatment period consists of the periods t < = −4 to t = −1, while periods t = 0 to t > = 4 constitute the post-treatment period. We aggregate the coefficients for the first and last periods depicted, also due to the staggered treatment. Accordingly, the t < = −4 value represents the average of the coefficient estimates for the interactions between each Treat variable and year dummies for periods four or more years prior to treatment. Analogously, the t > = 4 value is the average of the estimates for the interactions between Treat and year dummies for periods four or more years after treatment.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Emission levels around the disclosure mandate. This figure shows the change in verified GHG emissions surrounding the disclosure mandate. Values on the y-axis show differences in the natural logarithm of emissions of treated and control group firms and 90% confidence intervals. To obtain these estimates, we replicate model (1) but replace Post · Treat with separate interaction terms for each individual period surrounding the mandate. To account for the staggered implementation of the disclosure mandate, we adjust time periods using relative time periods. Values on the x-axis indicate periods relative to the first-time application of the mandate (t = 0). For firms with fiscal year end after September 30, 2013, t = 0 refers to the year 2013. For firms with fiscal year end before September 30, 2013, t = 0 refers to the year 2014. Periods t = −2, t = −3, and t < = −4 are prior to the first-time application of the disclosure mandate. Periods t = 0, t = +1, and t > = 2 are on or after the first-time application of the disclosure mandate. We use the last year prior to the first-time application (t = −1) as the benchmark period

Regarding firm-level emissions, Fig. 2 indicates a difference in pre-treatment and post-treatment coefficients. While treated firms have somewhat higher pre-treatment emissions than the control group four years prior to the mandate, this difference is fairly stable and close to zero during the three-year pre-treatment period. Point estimates are not significantly different from zero in any year from t > −4 to t = −1.Footnote 45 Based on these results, we do not find any violation of the common trends assumption for firm-level emissions. The estimates for the period t = 0 to t > = 4 show the evolution of the treatment effect over time. We observe that emissions in the treatment group decrease immediately after the start of the post-treatment period. The treated firms decrease their emissions and maintain their reductions for the first two years until t = 1. Thereafter, emission levels converge again between the two groups.

A comparison with the findings in Grewal (2021) may be instructive. First, while Grewal’s (2021) emission measure consists of total Scope 1 and Scope 2 emissions, we focus solely on Scope 1 emissions. Second, while our estimated average emission reduction is consistent with the main finding in Grewal (2021), the results from our event study design suggest that the effect on emissions is transitory. The findings in the two studies are therefore complementary, as both the samples and the emission outcome variables differ.

Figure 3 shows the results for carbon intensity. A similar picture emerges as in Fig. 2, irrespective of whether we define carbon intensity as emissions divided by COGS (Fig. 3, Panel a) or as emissions divided by sales (Fig. 3, Panel b). Point estimates are not significantly different from zero in any year from t > −4 to t = −1, thus supporting the common trend assumption. Again, we observe a clear treatment effect, which manifests itself at the beginning of the post-treatment period. As with emissions, coefficients immediately after the start of the post-treatment period are negative and marginally significant, while point estimates converge to zero in later years.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Carbon intensity around the disclosure mandate. Panel A: ln(Emissions/COGS). Panel B: ln(Emissions/Sales). This figure shows the change in carbon intensity surrounding the disclosure mandate. Panel A shows carbon intensity defined as ln(Emissions/COGS). Panel B shows carbon intensity defined as ln(Emissions/Sales). Values on the y-axis show differences in carbon intensity reductions of treated and control group firms and 90% confidence intervals. To obtain these estimates, we replicate model (2) but replace Post · Treat with separate interaction terms for each individual year surrounding the mandate. To account for the staggered implementation of the disclosure mandate, we adjust time periods using relative time periods. Values on the x-axis indicate periods relative to the first-time application of the disclosure mandate (t = 0). For firms with fiscal year end after September 30, 2013, t = 0 refers to the year 2013. For firms with fiscal year end before September 30, 2013, t = 0 refers to the year 2014. Periods t = −2, t = −3, and t < = −4 are prior to the first-time application of the disclosure mandate. Periods t = 0, t = +1, and t > = 2 are on or after the first-time application of the disclosure mandate. We use the last year prior to the first-time application (t = −1) as the benchmark period

4.2 Effects on financial operating performance

Our next set of tests addresses the effects of the mandate on the financial operating performance. Table 6 present the results. In column (I), we show the results without including further control variables. We find a significantly negative treatment effect on the firms’ gross margins. Column (II) of Table 6 shows the results when controlling for firm size, asset intensity, leverage, and PTB, as well as for a country’s GDP and changes in input prices—the point estimate becomes statistically insignificant. This result shows that the gross margins of disclosing firms following the 2013 mandate are not statistically different from the margins of our control group of non-disclosing firms, providing support for hypothesis H3.

Table 6 The effect of a GHG disclosure mandate on financial operating performance

To further explore our findings on H3, we investigate the individual components of the gross margin, i.e., production costs and sales. The unaffected gross margins we documented before do not rule out any increases in production costs. Stable gross margins could likewise be consistent with a simultaneous increase in both costs and sales.

We first estimate the treatment effect of the UK mandate on changes in production costs and rerun our DiD estimation using the logarithm of costs of goods sold as the dependent variable. Column (III) in Table 6 presents the results without further control variables. The findings suggest that firms subject to the mandate incur, on average, a statistically significant increase in production costs of about 10% (p: <0.1). Based on this simple specification, the estimates suggest that emission reductions have been costly to firms. However, after adding the same control variables used in the other tests, the point estimate is reduced in magnitude and becomes statistically insignificant, as shown in column (IV) of Table 6. Thus, when taking account of the different firm and country characteristics, our results imply that firms were indeed able to find low-cost options when reducing their GHG emissions. In untabulated regressions, we confirm this result in a corresponding test when using capital expenditures (CAPEX) as the dependent variable instead of costs of goods sold. Hence, the observed emission reductions cannot be related to an increase in capital expenditures for, e.g., more energy-efficient machinery and appliances, either.

We also run our estimation using the logarithm of sales as the dependent variable. With stable gross margins and statistically unchanged production costs, we expect to see no changes in sales. Columns (V) and (VI) of Table 6 show the results. The findings without and with covariates validate this conjecture.

Finally, we examine the parallel pre-treatment trends in both COGS and sales for UK and EU firms. For instance, we could fail to identify cost effects for the UK-disclosing firms, if EU firms in our control group experienced an upward trend in costs for other reasons. In Fig. 4, we plot the common trend graphs for COGS and sales. As before, we compute the differences for UK and EU firms for each year by replacing the interaction term Post · Treatment with separate interaction terms for each period relative to the year of the implementation of the disclosure mandate. The differences in COGS between UK and EU firms are statistically not different from zero during the pre-treatment years. For sales, we observe largely insignificant pre-treatment differences between UK and EU firms. During the post-treatment period, the point estimates are greater than zero, yet insignificant for most periods.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Change in operating performance surrounding the disclosure mandate. Panel A: ln(COGS). Panel B: ln(Sales). This figure shows the change in a firm’s financial operating performance surrounding the disclosure mandate. Values on the y-axis show differences in the natural logarithm of emissions of treated and control group firms and 90% confidence intervals. To obtain these estimates, we replicate model (3) but replace Post · Treat with separate interaction terms for each individual period surrounding the disclosure mandate. To account for the staggered implementation of the act, we adjust time periods using relative time periods. Values on the x-axis indicate periods relative to the first-time application of the disclosure mandate (t = 0). For firms with fiscal year end after September 30, 2013, t = 0 refers to the year 2013. For firms with fiscal year end before September 30, 2013, t = 0 refers to the year 2014. Periods t = −2, t = −3, and t < = −4 are prior to the first-time application of the disclosure mandate. Periods t = 0, t = +1, and t > = 2 are on or after the first-time application of the disclosure mandate. We use the last year prior to the first-time application (t = −1) as the benchmark period.

Taken together, the results in this section show that disclosing firms do not experience significant cost or sales increases, on average, and consequently no significant effect on gross margins. As such, our findings provide no support for the concern that GHG disclosure mandates could have a deteriorating effect on financial operating performance.

Finally, we exploit information about the complexity of a firm’s installation portfolio by interacting the treatment variable with a complexity measure. Column (I) in Table 7 shows that firms with a more complex installation structure, i.e., with higher complexity scores, reduce their emissions by less than less complex firms. Columns (II) and (III) of Table 7 show that this finding is robust to using the two alternative definitions for carbon intensity. Columns (IV)–(VI) indicate that our results on operating performance are largely unaffected by including the information on firm complexity. This finding is intuitive, as firms with more complex operating structures reduce emissions to a lesser extent. We also do not expect to see any changes in gross margins, costs, or sales. In conclusion, firms with a more complex corporate structure are less successful at reducing both emissions and carbon intensity, thus providing supporting evidence for H4.

Table 7 The effect of installation portfolio complexity on emission and financial operating performance

5 Sensitivity and additional analyses

In this section, we report the findings from sensitivity tests and additional analyses. For our first sensitivity test, we construct a matched sample of treatment and control firms. Accordingly, we match each treatment firm with a control group firm within the same SIC-1 industry based on average pre-treatment emission levels, i.e., a one-to-one matching without replacement.Footnote 46 We use the same dependent variables as in our main tests. Table 8 presents the results and shows that our estimates are qualitatively similar to the ones obtained before. Furthermore, we use an industry-balanced sample, i.e., only firms from industries with treatment and control group observations. This approach leads to unchanged results.

Table 8 Results for matched sample

We acknowledge that during our sample period France mandated broad corporate disclosures regarding environmental stewardship. While we kept French installations for our main tests, we find virtually unchanged results for emission reductions and operating performance if we exclude installations owned by French firms. Our results on emission reductions and operating performance are also robust to not excluding energy sector installations or only excluding electricity installations from our sample. As discussed in our data section, electricity installations have been subject to additional climate regulations during our observation period.

We also validate the robustness of our findings to the sample period and emission data availability: (1) we exclude the entry-into-force year of the Companies Act, (2) we do not exclude installations without emissions in a single year or maintenance during the sample period, and (3) we use a balanced sample at the firm level, i.e., we only use firms with data for all sample periods. All three approaches lead to unchanged emission results.

In concluding this section, we note that, with regard to other potentially confounding regulations within the European Union, we are unable to document either a concurring regulation or another event that would explain our results. Of course, we cannot rule out that an unspecified event, which coincided with the 2013 act and differentially affected listed firms in the UK, had a confounding effect on our findings. Finally, we only investigate the effects of one GHG emission disclosure regulation on specific firms (covered by the EU ETS) in one country (UK) for a specific period (2009–2018).

6 Concluding remarks

This study contributes to the growing literature on the effects of disclosure requirements for firms’ activities in the ESG domain. While there appears to be considerable interest in having standardized reports on such activities, there does not seem to be a generally accepted measurement and verification framework for many ESG variables. Environmental pollution is an exception in this regard, because for many pollutants firms already have to demonstrate compliance with existing regulations. Our study on the effect of the 2013 mandate that required UK firms to disclose their greenhouse gas emissions in annual reports exploits the fact that most European manufacturing sites already had to have their reported emissions verified under the rules of the European Emission Trading scheme.

The introduction of the Companies Act 2006 (Strategic Report and Directors’ Report) Regulations 2013 provides a source of exogenous variation in the disclosure regime of firms located in different countries. We find that installations belonging to UK companies subject to the disclosure mandate exhibit significant reductions in GHG emissions compared to installations in the control group, after including various time-variant and time-invariant fixed effects as well as firm specific control variables. Specifically, the treated firms reduced emissions by about 8% following the disclosure mandate, relative to pre-treatment emission levels. These results obtain at both the installation level and the firm level. We observe comparable incremental reductions in the carbon intensity of the treated firms when total emissions are scaled either by sales or cost of goods sold. Additional cross-sectional tests indicate that multinational firms with more complex operations tend to reduce their emissions by a smaller percentage than their less complex counterparts.

With regard to financial consequences, we find that in the years following the mandate the treated firms experienced a small, but statistically insignificant, increase in both their production costs and their sales. The latter effect is consistent with the interpretation of firms having improved their public image with customers on account of having improved a central CSR variable. Since the small and statistically insignificant increases in both revenues and costs net out to a zero effect in the gross margins, our results indicate that the disclosure mandate did not have a deteriorating effect on the financial operating performance of the firms subject to the act.

The emissions data for the firms in our treatment group had already been publicly available prior to the UK mandate, albeit in a distributed form, so outside observers had to incur search costs in order to assign installation-level emissions to publicly listed firms. Our empirical findings are consistent with the hypothesis that the disclosure requirement made firm-specific carbon footprint information directly accessible to stakeholders and thus resulted in additional transparency, which motivated the firms’ management to achieve greater emission reductions.

In the current debate about alternative policy tools for addressing the impending climate crisis, economists generally point to pricing carbon emissions or subsidizing low-carbon energy alternatives. The findings in this paper indicate that the increased transparency associated with greenhouse gas reporting mandates, like the 2013 act in the UK, could be another policy lever for reducing corporate carbon emissions.