Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Federal homelessness policy: A robust political economy approach

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the wake of the financial crisis, the United States government introduced a new large-scale initiative to address homelessness. The policy mandate is marked by both an unprecedented increase in federal funding and a dramatic reallocation of resources toward Housing First, a service model emphasizing immediate housing subsidization. Although this service paradigm has received support from a sizeable literature, our knowledge of its success to date has been limited. This paper sheds light on the unobservable or unmeasured costs of this new centralized approach to ending homelessness. I argue that federal homelessness policy under the Housing First approach 1) generates resource misallocation, 2) exacerbates the Samaritan’s dilemma, and 3) invites rent seeking.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Housing First began to be adopted slightly earlier during the Bush administration; however, the model was heavily expanded to become the predominant service technology under Opening Doors.

  2. For a critique of this work, specifically the finding that rent control causes homelessness, see Quigley (1990).

  3. The linear model is still employed and practiced across the country; however, federal funding has transitioned away from these programs that have fallen out of fashion with the expert community.

  4. I use the most recent federal definition in the McKinney-Vento Act as amended by the 2009 HEARTH Act.

  5. This reflects the federal government’s reported strategy in Opening Doors. “[T]o end homelessness, we must invest in what works: evidence-based solutions like Housing First, permanent supportive housing, and rapid re-housing” (United States Interagency Council on Homelessness 2015: 65).

  6. Examples of prescient Austrian insights into the role of incentives in different contexts abound. Hayek’s The Road to Serfdom, specifically “Why the Worst Get on Top,” discusses how the incentive structure of political competition rewards those with a comparative advantage in violence, guile, and manipulation (Hayek 1944). For more examples, see Boettke and Leeson (2004b).

  7. Another reason is that the winners of political competition have concentrated interests that need not align with the stated ends of well-intentioned policy. This is discussed in section 4.

  8. The federal government has emphasized improving the measurement of homelessness in the policy initiative of the last decade (United States Interagency Council on Homelessness 2015). Despite this, current homelessness data do not even allow policymakers to reliably observe the problem they are spending over $6 billion dollars a year to address.

  9. Berk et al. (2008) report on the 2007 enumeration in Los Angeles, emphasizing its integrity and validity. They also hint at the complexity and subjectivity involved: “The imputation of counts to unsampled [sic] tracts can benefit from modeling in this context. We do not, however, believe that any specifics of the present choices carry over to other times or places. One can easily find, as we have in a related project, that what is ‘known’ in advance about the location of homeless individuals and the correlates of homelessness is inaccurate. That, in turn, will affect the details of how the imputed counts are constructed” (2008:140). Their period of interest predates the drastic reduction mentioned here. Additionally, it should be noted that HUD retroactively removed the “hidden homeless” counts from all years as of 2015.

  10. This form of misallocation could partly explain the modest relationship that Byrne et al. (2014) find between permanent supportive housing and chronic homelessness.

  11. This assumes that all n people are homeless and would remain so if not for permanent housing assistance. It is unclear that this assumption holds given the incentive structures facing both recipients and providers (see sections three and four).

  12. Even if one were to normatively assert that more common short-term homelessness is preferable to infrequent long-term homelessness, one must weigh the fact that the supply of homelessness is not exogenous to the benefits available—a fact that is typically ignored (see also DCICH 2015).

  13. Petersén and Olsson (2015) call evidence-based social programs like Housing First into question, arguing that they obscure the role of “Phronetic knowledge,” which “comes from a close understanding of practice in specific contexts” that “is difficult to teach fully, because it has a dimension that cannot be expressed verbally” (1584). This is closely akin to the Hayekian notion of tacit knowledge that Wagner asserts is necessary for welfare efforts transcending the “leveling,” tax-and-transfer paradigm (2010). Tacit knowledge is critical to determining the efficacy of homelessness policy in any given context; however, this is ignored by a policy that would push Housing First across heterogeneous communities.

  14. Even the original Pathways model (Tsemberis and Eisenberg 2000) did not yield overwhelmingly superior results to alternative models. For instance, the study does not speak to long-run costs of PSH, which are surely sizable. The superiority of Housing First in terms of addressing mental health and addiction is also entirely unclear.

  15. This confidence is reflected in the government resources available to communities. HUD’s Supportive Housing Opportunities Planner web tool, which is “designed to help communities set a path to end chronic homelessness locally,” assumes a greater than one-for-one impact of permanent supportive housing unit in the long run (United States Interagency Council on Homelessness 2016c: 1).

  16. A notable empirical study on housing prevention is Goodman et al. (2014), who study a New York City prevention program called “HomeBase.” Despite the program’s repute, the authors find no relationship between the program and average shelter spells. Their non-result echoes myriad knowledge problems of prevention: “No one knows how large the population at any moment is that could be diverted from shelter entry by Homebase-style interventions, or how much of that population could be attracted and identified” (2014: 56).

  17. For a critical assessment of this evidence base, see Corinth (2016b).

  18. HUD has been pushing for a greater proportion of permanent supportive housing units to be allocated to the chronic homeless, and this share has increased in recent years. However, a sizable fraction of permanent supportive housing units continue to be allocated to the non-chronic homeless.

  19. All values are in real 2006 dollars.

  20. A considerable literature points to related adverse effects in a host of government programs (see Wagner 2005; Lee and MacKenzie 1987, and Mathers 2012 among others).

  21. Disability in this sense is defined quite loosely—a substance abuse disorder qualifies one as disabled.

  22. In virtually all permanent supportive housing programs, supportive services and counseling are available to all users, who are free to accept or reject these support resources.

  23. In the period studied, the increase in shelter entry is smaller than the first order effect of reducing the homeless population one-for-one via subsidized housing. They therefore reject the hypothesis that increased subsidy benefits were responsible for the increase in family homelessness over this period. However, this is still consistent with a non-zero supply elasticity. Further, economic theory suggests that the supply of homelessness is more elastic in the long-term, making the net long-term effect unclear.

  24. For a critique of right to shelter laws, see Ellickson (1992).

  25. This is the Capitol’s second attempt at a right to shelter law; a similar enactment in 1984 lasted briefly until it was scaled back in 1991. A GAO report indicates that the number of families served skyrocketed during this period, attributing this to the increasing awareness that “homeless families were receiving priority in obtaining housing and rental payment assistance” (Government Accountability Office 1991: 2–3).

  26. Those in permanent supportive housing are not counted as homeless.

  27. Again, this statistic may not truly represent the prevalence of unsheltered homelessness. However, most researchers indicate that point-in-time counts employed tend to overstate the long-term homeless relative to short-term, the latter of whom are typically sheltered (Raphael 2010; Williams 2011).

  28. Again, permanent supportive housing recipients are free to engage with these services on a voluntary basis, but the services must be available.

References

  • Apicello, J. (2010). A paradigm shift in housing and homeless services: applying the population and high-risk framework to preventing homelessness. Open Health Services and Policy Journal, 3, 41–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaulier, S. A., & Subrick, J. R. (2006). Poverty traps and the robust political economy of development assistance. Review of Austrian Economics, 19(2–3), 217–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berk, R., Kriegler, B., & Ylvisaker, D. (2008). Counting the homeless in Los Angeles county. In Probability and statistics: Essays in honor of David A. Freedman, 2, 127–141. Institute of Mathematical Statistics.

  • Boettke, P. J. (1998). Economic calculation: The Austrian contribution to political economy. Advances in Austrian Economics, 5, 131–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2004a). Liberalism, socialism, and robust political economy. Journal of Markets and Morality, 7(1), 99–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2004b). An ‘Austrian’ perspective on public choice. In the encyclopedia of public choice. New York: Springer, 351–356.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The Samaritan’s dilemma. In E. Phelps (ed.), Altruism, Morality and Economic Theory. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

  • Burt, M. R., Aron, L. Y., Lee, E., & Valente, J. (2001). Helping America’s homeless: emergency housing or affordable housing? Washington, DC: The Urban Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Byrne, T., Munley, E. A., Fargo, J. D., Montgomery, A. E., & Culhane, D. P. (2014). The relationship between community investment in permanent supportive housing and chronic homelessness. Social Service Review, 88(2), 234–263.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Community Shelter Board. (2015). Examination of family homelessness in Columbus/Franklin County, OH 2010 to 2014. Bethesda, MD: Abt Associates.

  • Congressional Quarterly Almanac. (1989). Homeless Assistance Act reauthorized. CQ Almanac 1988 (44th ed.). Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly.

  • Corinth, Kevin C. (2015). Getting real with the new homelessness numbers. AEIdeas. November. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.

  • Corinth, Kevin C. (2016a). On Utah’s 91 percent decrease in chronic homelessness. March. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.

  • Corinth, Kevin C. (2016b). Pay for performance: A new solution for vulnerable homeless adults. AEI Economic Perspectives. April. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.

  • Corporation for Supportive Housing. (2016). Mission. New York: Corporation for Supportive Housing.

  • Cragg, M., & O'Flaherty, B. (1999). Do homeless shelter conditions determine shelter population? The case of the Dinkins deluge. Journal of Urban Economics, 46(3), 377–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Culhane, D. P. (1992). The quandaries of shelter reform: An appraisal of efforts to “manage” homelessness. Social Service Review, 66(3), 428–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Culhane, D. P. (2008). The cost of homelessness: A perspective from the United States. European Journal of Homelessness, 2(1), 97–117.

    Google Scholar 

  • Culhane, D. P., Metraux, S., & Hadley, T. (2002). Public service reductions associated with placement of homeless persons with severe mental illness in supportive housing. Housing Policy Debate, 13(1), 107–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunningham, M., & Henry, M. (2008). Measuring progress and tracking trends in homelessness. Homelessness in America, 1, 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • District of Columbia Interagency Council on Homelessness. (2015). Homeward DC: 2015–2020. Washington, D.C.: District of Columbia Interagency Council on Homelessness.

  • Doherty, M., & Sandor, B. (2015). Data drives results: Take down targets help communities zero in on ending homelessness. Washington, D. C.: United States Interagency Council on Homelessness.

  • Ellen, I. G. and O’Flaherty, B. (2010). Introduction. In Ingrid Gould Ellen and Brendan O’Flaherty (eds.), How to House the Homeless. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1–13.

  • Ellickson, R. C. (1992). The Untenable Case for an Unconditional Right to Shelter. Harvard Journal of Law & Public Policy, 15, 17–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goering, P. N., Streiner, D. L., Adair, C., Aubry, T., Barker, J., Distasio, J., Hwang, S. W., Komaroff, J., Latimer, E., Somers, J., & Zabkiewicz, D. M. (2011). The At Home/Chez Soi trial protocol: a pragmatic, multi-site, randomised controlled trial of a Housing First intervention for homeless individuals with mental illness in five Canadian cities. BMJ Open, 1(2), 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman, S., Messeri, P., & O’Flaherty, B. (2014). How effective homelessness prevention impacts the length of shelter spells. Journal of Housing Economics, 23, 55–62.

  • Government Accountability Office. (1991). D.C. government: Information on the homeless family program. August. GGD-91-108. Washington, D.C.

  • Gulcur, L., Stefancic, A., Shinn, M., Tsemberis, S., & Fischer, S. N. (2003). Housing, hospitalization, and cost outcomes for homeless individuals with psychiatric disabilities participating in continuum of care and housing first programmes. Journal of Community & Applied Social Psychology, 13(2), 171–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1937). Economics and knowledge. Economica, 4(13), 33–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1944). The road to serfdom. New York: Routledge.

  • Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35(4)), 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1960). The constitution of liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Hayek, F. A. (1988) (2011). The fatal conceit: The errors of socialism (vol. 1). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Ikeda, S. (2005). The dynamics of interventionism. Advances in Austrian Economics,, 8, 21–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jencks, C. (1994). The homeless. Boston: Harvard University Press.

  • Kertesz, S. G., & Weiner, S. J. (2009). Housing the chronically homeless: high hopes, complex realities. JAMA, 301(17), 1822–1824.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Larimer, M. E., Malone, D. K., Garner, M. D., Atkins, D. C., Burlingham, B., Lonczak, H. S., Tanzer, K., Ginzler, J., Clifasefi, S. L., Hobson, W. G., & Marlatt, G. A. (2009). Health care and public service use and costs before and after provision of housing for chronically homeless persons with severe alcohol problems. JAMA, 301(13), 1349–1357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D. (1985). Rivalry and central planning: the socialist calculation debate reconsidered. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Lee, D. R., & MacKenzie, R. B. (1987). Regulating government: A preface to constitutional economics. Lexington: Lexington Books.

  • Leeson, P. T., & Subrick, J. R. (2006). Robust political economy. Review of Austrian Economics, 19(2–3), 107–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mathers, R. L. (2012). The failure of state-led economic development on American Indian reservations. The Independent Review, 17(1), 65–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mises, L. (1927). Liberalism: In the Classical Tradition. Irvington-on-Hudson, New York: Foundation for Economic Education, 1985.

  • Mises, L. (1930). Selected writings of Ludwig von Mises, vol. 1: Monetary and economic problems before, during, and after the great war. Ed. Richard M. Ebeling. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 2012.

  • Mises, L. (1966). Human action: A treatise on economics. 3rd rev. ed. Chicago: Henry Regnery.

  • Moore, T. (2006). Estimated cost savings following enrollment in the community engagement program: Findings from a pilot study of homeless dually diagnosed adults. Portland, OR: Central City Concern.

  • Moulton, S. (2013). Does increased funding for homeless programs reduce chronic homelessness? Southern Economic Journal, 79(3), 600–620.

  • Mullen, J., & Leginski, W. (2010). Building the capacity of the homeless service workforce. Open Health Services and Policy Journal, 3, 101–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Alliance to End Homelessness. (2014). Annual report. Washington, D. C.: National Alliance to End Homelessness.

  • National Alliance to End Homelessness. (2016). Ten year plan. Washington, D. C.: National Alliance to End Homelessness.

  • Nicholls, C. M., & Atherton, I. (2011). Housing First: Considering components for successful resettlement of homeless people with multiple needs. Housing Studies, 26(5), 767–777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Flaherty, B. (2010). Homelessness as bad luck: Implications for research and policy. In Ingrid Gould Ellen and Brendan O’Flaherty (eds.), How to House the Homeless. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 143–82.

  • O’Flaherty, B., & Wu, T. (2006). Fewer subsidized exits and a recession: How New York City’s family homeless shelter population became immense. Journal of Housing Economics, 15(2), 99–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padgett, D. K., Stanhope, V., Henwood, B. F., & Stefancic, A. (2011). Substance use outcomes among homeless clients with serious mental illness: Comparing Housing First with treatment first programs. Community Mental Health Journal, 47(2), 227–232.

  • Paniagua, P. (2016). The robust political economy of central banking and free banking. Review of Austrian Economics, 29(1), 15–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasour Jr., E. C. (1991). The Samaritan’s dilemma and the welfare state. The Freeman, 41, 208–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pennington, M. (2010). Robust political economy: Classical liberalism and the future of public policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

  • Perlman, J., & Parvensky, J. (2006). Denver Housing First Collaborative: Cost benefit analysis and program outcomes report. Denver: Colorado Coalition for the Homeless.

  • Petersén, A. C., & Olsson, J. I. (2015). Calling evidence-based practice into question: Acknowledging phronetic knowledge in social work. British Journal of Social Work, 45(5), 1581–1597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pleace, N. (2011). The ambiguities, limits and risks of Housing First from a European perspective. European Journal of Homelessness, 5(2), 113–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Popov, I. (2016). Homeless programs and social insurance. Job market paper. Stanford, CA: Stanford.

  • Quigley, J. M. (1990). Does rent control cause homelessness? Taking the claim seriously. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 9(1), 89–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raphael, S. (2010). Housing market regulation and homelessness. In I. G. Ellen and B. O’Flaherty (eds.), How to House the Homeless. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. 110–140.

  • Rosenheck, R., Kasprow, W., Frisman, L., & Liu-Mares, W. (2003). Cost-effectiveness of supported housing for homeless persons with mental illness. Archives of General Psychiatry, 60(9), 940–951.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sacramento Steps Forward. (2016). Zero: 2016 – Ending veteran and chronic homelessness. Sacramento, CA: Sacramento Steps Forward.

  • Salter, A. W. (2016). Robust political economy and the lender of last resort. Journal of Financial Services Research, 50, 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidtchen, D. (2002). To help or not to help: The Samaritan’s dilemma revisited. In Method and Morals in Constitutional Economics (pp. 470–484). Heidelberg: Springer Berlin Heidelberg.

  • Shinn, M., Baumohl, J., & Hopper, K. (2001). The prevention of homelessness revisited. Analyses of Social Issues and Public Policy, 1(1), 95–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skarbek, E. C. (2016). Aid, ethics, and the Samaritan’s dilemma: strategic courage in constitutional entrepreneurship. Journal of Institutional Economics, 12(2), 371–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stefancic, A., & Tsemberis, S. (2007). Housing First for long-term shelter dwellers with psychiatric disabilities in a suburban county: A four-year study of housing access and retention. The Journal of Primary Prevention, 28(3–4), 265–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Troutman, W. H., Jackson, J. D., & Ekelund Jr., R. B. (1999). Public policy, perverse incentives, and the homeless problem. Public Choice,, 98(1–2), 195–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsemberis, S. (2010). Housing First: ending homelessness, promoting recovery and reducing costs. In Ingrid Gould Ellen and Brendan O’Flaherty (eds.), How to House the Homeless. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 37–56.

  • Tsemberis, S., & Eisenberg, R. F. (2000). Pathways to housing: Supported housing for street-dwelling homeless individuals with psychiatric disabilities. Psychiatric Services, 51(4), 487–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsemberis, S., Gulcur, L., & Nakae, M. (2004). Housing first, consumer choice, and harm reduction for homeless individuals with a dual diagnosis. American Journal of Public Health, 94(4), 651–656..

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tucker, W. (1990). The excluded Americans: Homelessness and housing policies. New York: Gateway Books.

  • Tucker, W. (1991). How housing regulations cause homelessness. The Public Interest, 102, 78–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • United States Department of Housing and Urban Development. (1984). A report to the Secretary on the homeless and emergency shelters. Washington, D.C.: Office of Policy Development and Research.

  • United States Department of Housing and Urban Development. (2008). A guide to counting unsheltered homeless people. Washington, D.C.: Office of Community Planning and Development.

  • United States Department of Housing and Urban Development. (2009). The 2008 annual homelessness assessment report to Congress. Washington, D.C.: Office of Community Planning and Development.

  • United States Department of Housing and Urban Development. (2010). The 2009 annual homeless assessment report to Congress. Washington, D.C.: Office of Community Planning and Development.

  • United States Department of Housing and Urban Development. (2014). Point-in-time count methodology guide. Washington, D.C.: Office of Community Planning and Development.

  • United States Department of Housing and Urban Development. (2015). The 2015 annual homeless assessment report (AHAR) to Congress: Part 1 - PIT estimates of homelessness in the U.S. Washington, D.C.: Office of Community Planning and Development.

  • United States Interagency Council on Homelessness. (2011). Developing and implementing strategic plans to end homelessness. Washington, D.C.: USICH.

  • United States Interagency Council on Homelessness. (2014). Creating effective systems to end homelessness: A guide to reallocating funds in the CoC Program. September. Washington, D.C.: USICH.

  • United States Interagency Council on Homelessness. (2015). Opening doors: The federal plan to prevent and end homelessness. June. Washington, D.C.: USICH.

  • United States Interagency Council on Homelessness. (2016a). Permanent supportive housing definition. Washington, D.C.: USICH.

  • United States Interagency Council on Homelessness. (2016b). Rapid re-housing definition. Washington, D.C.: USICH.

  • United States Interagency Council on Homelessness. (2016c). The Supportive Housing Opportunities Planner (SHOP) tool: Setting a path to end chronic homelessness locally. Washington, D.C.: USICH.

  • Voigt, S. (2006). Robust political economy: The case of antitrust. Review of Austrian Economics, 19(2–3), 203–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. E. (1989). To promote the general welfare: Market processes vs. political transfers. San Francisco: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy.

  • Wagner, R. E. 2005. Redistribution, poor relief, and the welfare state. In Handbook of public finance (pp. 385–405). New York: Springer US.

  • Williams, J. C. (2011). Stand Up and Be Counted: The Politics of a Homeless Enumeration. Poverty & Public Policy, 3(3), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank Chris Coyne, Kevin Corinth, James Bennett, an anonymous reviewer, and the participants at the F. A. Hayek Program Graduate Student Paper Workshop of the Mercatus Center at George Mason University for thoughtful comments on drafts of this paper. Remaining errors are my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to David S. Lucas.

Appendix: McKinney-Vento Act Definition of Homelessness

Definition as amended by the 2009 HEARTH Act.

Appendix: McKinney-Vento Act Definition of Homelessness

For purposes of this Act, the term ‘homeless’, ‘homeless individual’, and ‘homeless person’ means—

  1. (1)

    an individual or family who lacks a fixed, regular, and adequate nighttime residence;

  2. (2)

    an individual or family with a primary nighttime residence that is a public or private place not designed for or ordinarily used as a regular sleeping accommodation for human beings, including a car, park, abandoned building, bus or train station airport, or camping ground;

  3. (3)

    an individual or family living in a supervised publicly or privately operated shelter designated to provide temporary living arrangements (including hotels and motels paid for by Federal, State, or local government programs for low-income individuals or by charitable organizations, congregate shelters, and transitional housing);

  4. (4)

    an individual who resided in a shelter or place not meant for human habitation and who is exiting an institution where he or she temporarily resided;

  5. (5)

    an individual or family who—

    1. (A)

      will imminently lose their housing, including housing they own, rent, or live in without paying rent, are sharing with others, and rooms in hotels or motels not paid for by Federal, State, or local government programs for low-income individuals or by charitable organizations, as evidenced by—

      1. i.

        a court order resulting from an eviction action that notifies the individual or family that they must leave within 14 days;

      2. ii.

        the individual or family having a primary nighttime residence that is a room in a hotel or motel and where they lack the resources necessary to reside there for more than 14 days; or

      3. iii.

        credible evidence indicating that the owner or renter of the housing will not allow the individual or family to stay for more than 14 days, and any oral statement from an individual or family seeking homeless assistance that is found to be credible shall be considered credible evidence for purposes of this clause;

    2. (B)

      has no subsequent residence identified; and

    3. (C)

      lacks the resources or support networks needed to obtain other permanent housing; and

  6. (6)

    unaccompanied youth and homeless families with children and youth defined as homeless under other Federal statutes who—

    1. (A)

      have experienced a long term period without living independently in permanent housing;

    2. (B)

      have experienced persistent instability as measured by frequent moves over such period; and

    3. (C)

      can be expected to continue in such status for an extended period of time because of chronic disabilities, chronic physical health or mental health conditions, substance addiction, histories of domestic violence or childhood abuse, the presence of a child or youth with a disability, or multiple barriers to employment.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lucas, D.S. Federal homelessness policy: A robust political economy approach. Rev Austrian Econ 30, 277–303 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-016-0356-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-016-0356-x

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation