Skip to main content
Log in

From contract to mental model: Constitutional culture as a fact of the social sciences

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper develops the concept of constitutional culture—the attitude, thoughts, and feelings about constitutional constraints and the nature, scope, and function of constitutionalism. Constitutional culture is approached as a complex emergent phenomenon bridging Hayekian cognitive and institutional insights. It can be studied as a mental model, a series of expectations and understandings about the constitutional order, how it is, and how it ought to be. The “map” and “model” approach from Hayek’s Sensory Order (1952) is employed to understand how individuals and (cautiously) groups of individuals at the national level approach constitutionalism. This paper goes beyond the more traditional one-size-fits-all approach where all individuals respond uniformly to incentives, as provided by the constitution qua contract. Instead, constitutionalism is tied up in the individual’s vision of the world, that is, what Hayek (1948) labels “the facts of the social sciences.” The paper concludes with four areas where constitutional culture can further the insights of constitutional political economy: comparative political economy, constitutional stickiness, constitutional maintenance, and the new development economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. One wonders why constitutional culture receives such scant attention in the literature on constitutional political economy. I suspect there exits a “measurability bias” of sorts in economics (which is, after all, the mother discipline of constitutional political economy): culture does not fit into tidy models or econometric regressions, so it is simpler to assume it away (see Jones 2006; see also Evans 2007, commenting on Boulding 1974; Chamlee-Wright 1997; Tilly 2003; and Lavoie and Chamlee-Wright 2000, 42).

  2. Voigt (1996) explains that “whereas Buchanan is clearly leading the contract notion of the constitution, Hayek [e.g., 1979[1973, 1976, 1979] and 1988) is almost as clearly leading the notion of the constitution as the result of cultural evolution”; see also Hardin (1988) and Gordon (1976).

  3. It should also be noted that the difference between formal and de facto constitutions is covered in the legal literature, if not constitutional political economy and political science. For example, Lasalle (1946[1862] in Santiago 2003) distinguishes between the “real constitution” (actual power structures) and the “juridical constitution” (constitutional parchment).

  4. Generally, see Hayek (1948, 1960, 1967, 1978); Schelling (1978); Resnick (1997); Surowiecki (2005) as well as earlier articulations in Mandeville (1998[1732]); Smith (1997[1759]); Ferguson (1767); Hume (1958[1789]).

  5. See also Rothbard (1997, 15) on the organismic fallacy.

  6. Or competing cultures, if a country is heterogeneous; on dominant beliefs, see North (1999, 2005).

  7. Generally, see North (1990) on mental models; see Pejovich (2003) and Harrison and Huntington (2000) on the importance of culture; or Greif (1994) and Haley (1995, 103) on the distinction between collectivist and individualist societies.

  8. See, e.g., La Porta et al. (1997) on trust in large organizations, Weber (1905) and Barro and McCleary (2003) on religion and economic performance; or Fukuyama (1995) and Knack and Keefer (1997) on social capital and economic performance.

  9. Constitutional culture is an element of political and civic culture (see Almond and Verba 1965; Putnam 1978, 1993, Sartori 1965; Franklin and Baum 1995) dealing specifically with constitutional attitudes; it is thus narrower and does not include related parameters such as civic participation, political cognition, partisanship, pride in institutions, time preference, tolerance, electoral participation, etc. Constitutional culture contains only the elements pertaining to meta-rules, the general organization of law and society, and willingness to be constrained. To be sure, the two (civic/political culture and constitutional culture) are related and intertwined. But I focus here exclusively on constitutional culture, leaving the details of democracy and civic involvement to an already rich literature.

  10. In a semantic confusion, Hayek’s mental “map” is the “mental model” as used by North (1981, 1990, 1999, 2005) and throughout Harrison and Huntington (2000). I use the commonly accepted “mental model” to refer to Hayekian maps.

  11. I have argued elsewhere (Wenzel 2009) that Hayek’s cognitive theory forms the very foundation of his institutional theory. My purpose here is different, as I use Hayek’s cognitive theory for its explanatory traction, rather than as an overall foundation for his institutional theory.

  12. Hayek uses a different language to express the same idea when he talks of fixed strategies and variable tactics (Hayek 1967, 56, note 39).

  13. See footnote 10.

  14. See also Butos and Koppl (1993) on the effect of accumulated knowledge on classification.

  15. To clarify, constitutional culture—generally, as a mental model—helps understand constitutionalism generally. A specific kind of constitutional culture (one that includes willingness to be bound) is a necessary condition for successful constitutionalism.

  16. Representative countries include the US, Argentina, and Japan (although the latter adopted Madisonian judicialism and constitutional entrenchment, if not US-style federalism and presidentialism).

  17. Representative countries include the United Kingdom, New Zealand, Australia, and Canada to a large extent; for details, see Gardbaum (2001).

  18. Representative countries include France, Russia, and most of Eastern Europe.

  19. Lapsing for a moment from humble pattern prediction to point prediction of the most hubristic order (see Hayek 1967), I am venturing the prediction that the Iraqi constitution will not stick because the textual idealism of Madisonian constitutionalism (combined, perhaps, with the dictates of Realpolitik and US strategic interests) has eclipsed careful study of Iraq’s constitutional culture(s).

  20. A friend in a constitutionally unstable country calls me for help. He has a can of food but no can opener. Easy. I drop a can opener into a Federal Express package. Two days later, he receives the package and opens his can. So he calls me again. This time, he says that his country’s constitution is terrible, whereas the US Constitution has worked pretty well. So I put a copy of the US Constitution in a Federal Express package and send it to him… Why aren’t constitutions like can openers? I thank Peter Boettke for this example.

  21. See Rand (1966, 322–325) on the patent philosophical absurdity of positive “rights,” which imply, ipso facto, a violation of the negative rights of those forced to provide goods or services to those for whom an alleged positive “right” is created by the state.

  22. Including constitutional success and political stability, of course, but also rule of law, transparency and predictability of legislation, limited regulation, political and economic freedom, respect for property rights and contracts, etc.

  23. And, arguably, even that freedom is relative. We need only look at the “free” US, where nearly one half of economic activity is controlled by the government (and thus confiscated from individuals), if indirectly; where laws on searches and respect for habeas corpus are becoming increasingly dodgy; and where large swaths of the economy's commanding heights are facing de facto nationalization.

References

  • Almond, G., & Verba, S. (1965). The Civic Culture. Political Attitudes and Democracy in Five Nations and Analytic Survey. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & McCleary, R. (2003). Religion and economic growth. NBER Working Paper No. 96821.

  • Baumol, W. (1990). Entrepreneurship: productive, unproductive and destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5 Part 1), 893–921.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. (1998). Is there an intellectual market niche for Austrian economics? Review of Austrian Economics, 11, 1–4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. (2008). The most important book on the most important topic of our day: a review of after war: the political economy of exporting democracy, by Christopher J. Coyne. Economic Affairs, June 2008, 70–72.

  • Boettke, P. (2009). Eric L. Jones, Cultures Merging: A Historical and Economic Critique of Culture. Book review. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 57(2), 434–437.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P., & Coyne, C. (2003). Entrepreneurship and development: cause or consequence? Advances in Austrian Economics, 6, 67–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P., & Subrick, J. R. (2002). From the philosophy of mind to the philosophy of the market. Journal of Economic Methodology, 9, 1, 53–64.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P., Coyne, C., & Leeson, P. (2008). Institutional stickiness and the new development economics. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 67(2), 331–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm, S. (1994). Hayek and knowledge: some question marks. In M. Colonna, H. Hagemann, & O. Hamouda (Eds.), Capitalism, socialism and knowledge: the economics of F.A. Hayek (vol. II). Brookfield, VT: Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, K. (1974). Toward the development of cultural economics. Social Science Quarterly, 267–284.

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1985). The reason of rules: constitutional political economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1975). The limits of liberty—between anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1979). What should economists do?. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1981). Constitutional restrictions on the power of government. In J. Buchanan, & R. D. Tollison (Eds.), The theory of public choice—II. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1990). The domain of constitutional economics. Constitutional Political Economy, 1(1), 1990

  • Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnham, W. (1982). The constitution—capitalism and the need for rationalized regulation. In R. Goldwin, & W. Schambra (Eds.), How capitalistic is the constitution (pp. 75–105). Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Butos, W., & Koppl, R. (1993). Hayekian expectations: theory and empirical applications. Constitutional Political Economy, 4(3).

  • Butos, W., & McQuade, T. (2002). Mind, market and institutions: the knowledge problem in Hayek’s Thought. In J. Birner, P. Garrouste, & T. Aimar (Eds.), F.A. Hayek as a political economist. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, B. (2004). Hayek’s challenge: an intellectual biography of F.A. Hayek. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, B. (2003). The idea trap: the political economy of growth divergence. European Journal of Political Economy, 19, 183–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamlee-Wright, E. (1997). The cultural foundations of economic development: urban female entrepreneurship in Ghana. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C. (2008). After war: the political economy of exporting democracy. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coyne, C., & Leeson, P. (2004). The plight of underdeveloped countries. Cato Journal, 24(3), Fall 2004.

  • De Soto, H. (2000). The mystery of capital: why capitalism triumphs in the west and fails everywhere else. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorn, J., Hanke, S., & Walters, A. (eds.) (1998). The revolution in development economics. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.

  • Duverger, M. (1998). Les Constitutions de la France. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elias, N. (1978[1939]). The civilizing process, volume I: the development of manners. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elias, N. (2001[1939]). The society of individuals. New York: Continuum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (2000). Ulysses unbound. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, L., Knight, J., & Shvetsova, O. (2001). The role of constitutional courts in the establishment and maintenance of democratic systems of government. Law and Society Review, 35(1), 117–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, A. (2007). Subjectivist social change: the influence of culture and ideas on economic policy. Working Paper, George Mason University.

  • Ferejohn, J., Rakove, J., & Riley, J. (2001). Constitutional culture and democratic rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, A. (1767). Essay on the history of civil society.

  • Frank, R. (1992). Melding sociology and economics: James Coleman’s foundations of social theory. Journal of Economic Literature, 30(1), 147–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Franklin, D. (1995). American political culture and constitutionalism. In Franklin and Baun (1995), pp. 43–55.

  • Franklin, D., & Baun, M. (1995). Political culture and constitutionalism: a comparative approach. Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, L. (1975). The legal system: a social science perspective. Russell Sage Foundation.

  • Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust: the social virtues and the creation of prosperity. New York: Simon and Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardbaum, S. (2001). The new commonwealth model of constitutionalism. American Journal of Comparative Law, 49(4), Fall 2001.

  • Gibson, J., Caldeira, G., & Baird, V. (1998). On the legitimacy of national high courts. American Political Science Review, 92, 343–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, S. (1976). The new contractarians. The Journal of Political Economy, 84(3), 573–590.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (1994). Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: a historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and individualist society. Journal of Political Economy.

  • Gwartney, J., & Lawson, R. (2008). Economic freedom of the world: 2008 annual report. Vancouver: Fraser Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gwyn, W. (1995). Political culture and constitutionalism in Britain. In Franklin and Baum (1995), pp. 13–42

  • Haley, J. (1995). Judicial independence in Japan revisited. Law in Japan, 25(1).

  • Hancock, G. (1992). Lords of poverty: the power, prestige, and corruption of the international aid business. New York: The Atlantic Monthly Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, R. (1988). Constitutional political economy—agreement on rules. British Journal of Political Science, 18(4), 513–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, R. (1999). Liberalism, constitutionalism and democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harper, D. (2002). Entrepreneurship and economic growth: an Austrian perspective. Lecture given at the Advanced Austrian Seminar, Foundation for Economic Education, Summer 2002.

  • Harrison, L., & Huntington, S. (2000). Culture matters: how values shape human progress. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1948). Individualism and economic order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1952). The sensory order: an inquiry into the foundations of theoretical psychology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1960). The constitution of liberty. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1967). Studies in philosophy, politics and economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1978). Dr Bernard Mandeville. In F. A. Hayek (Ed.), New Studies in philosophy, politics and economics and the history of ideas. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1979 [1952]). The Counter-revolution of science. Studies in the abuse of reason. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Hayek, F. A. (1979 [1973, 1976, 1979]). Law, legislation and liberty (vol. 1–3). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Hayek, F. A. (1988). The fatal conceit: the errors of socialism. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1992). The sensory order after 25 years. In W. Weimer, & D. Palermo (Eds.), Cognition and the symbolic processes. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. (1998). Entrepreneurship and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 1(2), 45–62. Summer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, K., Feulner, E., & O’Grady, M. (2008). Index of economic freedom, 2008. Washington, DC: Heritage Foundation and Wall Street Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horwitz, S. (2000). From the sensory order to the liberal order: Hayek’s non-rationalist liberalism. Review of Austrian Economics, 13, 23–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume, D. (1958[1789]). A treatise on human nature. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1979). Rights and production functions: an application to labor-managed firms and co-determination. Journal of Business, 52, 469–506.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, E. (2006). Cultures merging: a historical and economic critique of culture. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, P. (1999). The cultural study of law. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keating, M., Louglin, J., & Deschouwer, K. (2003). Culture, institutions and economic development. Cheltenham: Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. Chicago and London: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. (1997). Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: an Austrian approach. Journal of Economic Literature, 35(1), 60–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelsen, H. (1942). Judicial review of legislation: a comparative study of the Austrian and the American constitution. Journal of Politics, 4, 183–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country comparison. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1251–1288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. (1939). Ethics and economic reform I. The ethics of liberalism. Econometrica, New Series, 6(21), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Trust in large organizations. The American Economic Review, Vol. 87, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Fourth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, May, pp. 333–338.

  • Lal, D. (1997). The poverty of development economics (2nd ed.). London: Institute of Economic Affairs. Hobart Paperback No. 16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lasalle, F. (1946[1862]). Que es una Constitucion?. Buenos Aires: Siglo 20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie, D., & Chamlee-Wright, E. (2000). Culture and enterprise. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, D. R., & McKenzie, R. B. (1987). Regulating government: a preface to constitutional economics. Lexington: D.C. Heath and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemieux, P. (1988). L’Anarcho-Capitalisme. Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levinson, S. (1988). Constitutional faith. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lupu, I. (1990). When cultures collide. Review of Constitutional Cultures: The Mentality and Consequences of Judicial Review, by Robert F. Nagel. Harvard Law Review, 103, 951–963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandeville, B. (1998[1732]). The fable of the bees or private vices, public benefits, 2 vols. With a commentary critical, historical, and explanatory by F.B. Kaye. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

  • Mazzone, J. (2005). The creation of a constitutional culture. Tulsa Law Review, 40, 671.

    Google Scholar 

  • McQuade, T., & Butos, W. (2005). The sensory order and other adaptive classifying systems. Journal of Bioeconomics, 7, 335–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miles, M., Feulner, E., & O’Grady, M. (2005). 2005 index of economic freedom. Washington, DC: Heritage Foundation and Wall Street Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, E. (1979). The cognitive basis of Hayek’s thought. In R. Cunningham (Ed.), Liberty and the rule of law. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moore, J. (2003). A few thoughts for discussion concerning government structures/constitutionalism for Iraq. Comments at the Federalist Society, Washington DC, Summer 2003.

  • Namier, L. (1944). 1848: the revolution of the intellectuals. London: Oxford University Press.

  • North, D. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1999). Understanding the process of economic change, occasional paper 106. London: The Institute of Economic Affairs.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D., & Weingast, B. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1984). Why governments fail: an inquiry into the use of instruments of evil to do good. In J. Buchanan, & R. D. Tollison (Eds.), The theory of public choice—II. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pejovich, S. (2003). Understanding the transaction costs of transition: it’s the culture, stupid. Forum Series on the Role of Institutions in Promoting Economic Growth, Directed by the Mercatus Center at George Mason University and the IRIS Center, Washington, DC, April 4, 2003.

  • Petroni, A. (2003). A constitution for the European Union? Lecture given at the XXVIth Summer University of the New Economy, Aix-en-Provence, September 2, 2003.

  • Petroni, A. (2004). Perspectives for freedom of choice in bioethics and health care in Europe. Paper prepared for Liberty Fund, January 2004.

  • Pippin, R. (1999). Modernism as a philosophical problem: on the dissatisfactions of European high culture. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. (1978). The beliefs of politicians. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work: civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rand, A. (1966). “The rights of man” in capitalism: the unknown ideal. New York: Signet.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rand, A. (1984). “Philosophy: who needs it” in philosophy: who needs it. New York: Signet.

    Google Scholar 

  • Resnick, M. (1997). Turtles, termites and traffic jams: explorations in massively parallel microworlds. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzello, S. (1999). The economics of the mind. Cheltenham, UK: Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1960a). Capital formation in underdeveloped countries. American Economic Review, 50(4), 706–715.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1960b). Some institutional aspects of the wealth of nations. Journal of Political Economy, 68(6), 557–570.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. (1996[1973]). For a new liberty: the libertarian manifesto. New York: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. (1997). The logic of action I: method, money and the Austrian school. Lyme, US: Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santiago, A. (h) (2003). Conferencia para los 150 Años de la Constitucion Nacional. Revista de la Escuela de Sciencias Politicas de la Pontifica Universidad Catolica de Argentina, Santa Maria de los Buenos Aires, IX No. 14, 233 et seq.

  • Sartori, G. (1965). Democratic theory. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1978). Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully, G. (1988). The institutional framework and economic development. Journal of Political Economy, 96(3), 652–662.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scully, G. (1992). Constitutional environments and economic growth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegan, B. (1994). Drafting a constitution for a nation or republic emerging into freedom. Fairfax: George Mason University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skach, C. (2005). Borrowing constitutional designs: constitutional law in Weimar Germany and the French fifth republic. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations.

  • Smith, A. (1997[1759]). The theory of moral sentiments. Washington, DC: Regnery.

    Google Scholar 

  • Surowiecki, J. (2005). The wisdom of crowds. New York: Anchor Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steele, G. R. (2002). Hayek’s sensory order. Theory & Psychology, 12, 387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steele, G. R. (2004). Hayek’s sensory order. Ama-Gi (The Journal of the Hayek Society at LSE), 6(1), Lent Term 2004.

  • Tilly, C. (2003). Stories, identities and political change. Lanham, MD: Rowan & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S. (1996). Positive constitutional economics: a survey. Public Choice, 90, 11–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1996[1949]). Human action, fourth revised edition. Irvington-on-Hudson: Foundation for Economic Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (2006[1919]). Nation, state and economy: contributions to the politics and history of our time. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1905). The Protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weimer, W. (1982). Hayek’s approach to the problem of complex phenomena: an introduction to the theoretical psychology of the sensory order. In W. Weimer, & D. Palermo (Eds.), Cognition and the symbolic processes. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. (1995). The economic role of political institutions: market-preserving federalism and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 11, 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wenzel, N. (2007). Ideology, constitutional culture, and institutional change: the EU Constitution as reflection of Europe’s emergent postmodernism. Romanian Economic and Business Review, 2(3), Fall 2007.

  • Wenzel, N. (2008a). Postmodernism and its discontents: whither constitutionalism after God and reason? New Perspectives on Political Economy, 4(2).

  • Wenzel, N. (2008b). Postmodernism and religion. In P. Clarke (Ed.), Oxford handbook of sociology and religion. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wenzel, N. (2009). The sensory order and the social order: parallels between hayek’s cognitive and institutional theories. In The Social Science of Hayek’s “The Sensory Order”, W. Butos, Volume Editor; Advances in Austrian Economics, R. Koppl, Series Editor.

  • Winchester, S. (1998). The professor and the madman. a tale of murder, insanity, and the making of the Oxford English Dictionary. New York: HarperCollins.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

For the discussion and comments, many thanks to Richard Wagner, Peter Boettke, Dragos Aligica, Don Boudreaux, David Levy, Mark Patton, Jim Loveland, Eduardo Stordeur, Bill Butos, participants at the 2008 meeting of the Society for the Development of Austrian Economics, the Henry C. Simons Circle, and an anonymous referee. Thanks also to George Mount for the research assistance. Financial support from the H.B. Earhart Foundation, the Hayek Fund at the Institute for Humane Studies, and the Mercatus Center at George Mason University is gratefully acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nikolai Wenzel.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Wenzel, N. From contract to mental model: Constitutional culture as a fact of the social sciences. Rev Austrian Econ 23, 55–78 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-009-0086-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-009-0086-4

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation