Skip to main content
Log in

Post-communist predation: modeling reiderstvo practices in contemporary predatory states

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While the economics of predatory states has been at the center of an emerging discussion, a rich body of literature on predation already exists in the scholarship on post-communist regimes. This paper offers a glimpse into that literature, developing (1) a typology of coercive corporate raiding (“reiderstvo”) and (2) a model for understanding the logic of contemporary predatory states. The typology starts from the original form of reiderstvo, carried out by criminal groups (“black raiding”), and introduces the concepts of “grey” and “white raiding”. We identify “centrally led corporate raiding” as a form of state predation not considered in public choice models, despite the fact that it exemplifies the functioning of contemporary authoritarian regimes. Expanding the models of Leeson (J Inst Theor Econ (JITE) 163:467–482, 2007) and Vahabi (Public Choice 168:153–175, 2016), we show how centrally led corporate raiding can be incorporated into the discussion of predatory states. We provide illustrations by offering two examples from the predatory state of contemporary Hungary, the case of an outdoor advertising company (ESMA) and the case of the banking sector.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Own construction

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Other post-communist member states of the EU are democracies and—as we will argue in the paper—centrally led reiderstvo requires an autocratic level of power concentration. That condition is present in Hungary (see Sect. 3), but not in countries like the Czech Republic, where predatory degeneration can be associated with state capture by competing private groups instead of an uncontested predatory head of the executive branch with de facto patrimonial control over the instruments of state coercion. See Klíma (2019).

  2. While we will assume the discouragement effect away for the sake of simplicity, it must be noted that, in real-world cases, it never is eliminated completely. To take an extreme case, experts estimate that at least half of Russia’s GDP is produced in the shadow economy, at least some of which can be attributed to hiding assets from predation (Yavlinsky 2013, p. 109). However, some other predatory states like Hungary manage to attract large investments by offering various benefits and guarantees to foreign direct investment (Magyar 2016, pp. 172–173; Gagyi and Gerőcs 2019).

  3. Indeed, Vahabi lists four factors that influence appropriability (state accessibility, concentration or dispersal, asset specificity and measurability), but of those, only one—asset specificity—is relevant in the case of modern predation.

  4. True, often it is not the victimized company that is damaged, but its owner (physical abuse). However, asset depreciation is an important factor that needs to be taken into account after predation, or in the long run when the company remains in operation. As a reviewer pointed out, capital depreciates over time and as economic progress proceeds, firms will need entrepreneurial activity to enable them to keep up with the market. In our model, we treat the latter as being included in the Vahabian factor of appropriability, which involves entrepreneurial skills. Indeed, the chief patron engages in predation if he is optimistic about maintaining the value of the plundered asset.

  5. Meaning both roving and stationary bandits, in the Olsonian sense. Also, see Vahabi (2015, pp. 41–89).

  6. Many examples are provided by Magyar (2016) and Magyar and Vásárhelyi (2017). More recent examples from Hungary can be observed in the ongoing case of Lake Balaton, the most popular destination for domestic tourism, where a large number of beaches, hotels and other facilities have been acquired by the adopted political family. For journalists’ reports, see Dunai (2018), Tamásné Szabó (2019), Balla (2019), Fokasz (2018), Nagy (2019) and Keller-Alánt (2018).

  7. The setup is analogous to feudal times in Scandinavia, where agriculture was barely taxed because weather conditions made average crop yields so low that the cost of the tax colleting apparatus would have been higher than the tax revenue itself. Professor Zoltán Balogh in the 1970s called that imbalance—in Marxist language—“uncollectible surplus value”, which was the reason that an independent peasantry could develop in Scandinavia in the first place.

  8. The quotation, as well as others in the following discussion, were translated by us from Hungarian.

  9. The literature also uses the term “’repeated privatization’: nationalization of the already privatized companies followed by the alternative ’fair’ privatization” (Chernykh 2011, p. 1240).

  10. The eight great banks at the time of predation were (in alphabetical order): Budapest Bank, CIB Bank, Erste Bank, K&H Bank, MKB Bank, OTP Bank, Raiffeisen Bank, UniCredit Bank (Király 2015, p. 192).

References

  • A fideszesek szerint is Orbán strómanja Mészáros Lőrinc [Lőrinc Mészáros is a front man of Orbán even according to Fidesz voters] (2018). hvg.hu.

  • Arslantaş, Y., Pietri, A., & Vahabi, M. (2019). State predation in historical perspective: The case of Ottoman müsadere practice during 1695–1839. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00700-9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balla, G. (2019). Nem kell több vendég Mészárosnak ahhoz, hogy újabb milliárdokat keressen a szállodáival [Mészáros doesn’t need guests to make billions with his hotels]. hvg.hu.

  • Bátorfy, A. (2012). Közterületi pénzosztás az Orbán-korszakban [Outdoor spending in the Orbán era]. Kreatív. Retrieved September 2, 2019, from http://kreativ.hu/outofhome/cikk/kozteruleti_penzosztas_az_orban_korszakban.

  • Bátorfy, A. (2015). How did the Orbán-Simicska media empire function? Kreatív. http://kreativ.hu/cikk/how_did_the_orban_simicska_media_empire_function. Accessed 16 Dec 2019.

  • Bátorfy, A. (2019a). Állami hirdetések 2019 – State advertising 2019). Mérték. Retrieved April 30, 2019, from https://mertek.atlatszo.hu/allamihirdetesek/.

  • Bátorfy, A. (2019b). Data visualization: See how the wealth and ranking of the richest 100 Hungarians changed over time. atlatszo.hu. Retrieved September 3, 2019, from https://english.atlatszo.hu/2019/05/23/data-visualization-see-how-the-wealth-and-ranking-of-the-richest-100-hungarians-changed-over-time/.

  • Bátorfy, A., & Urbán, Á. (2019). State advertising as an instrument of transformation of the media market in Hungary. East European Politics. https://doi.org/10.1080/21599165.2019.1662398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, A. (2017). The circulation of oligarchs. In B. Magyar & J. Vásárhelyi (Eds.), Twenty-five sides of a post-communist mafia state (pp. 111–128). Budapest-New York: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, B. L. (2019). The development and evolution of predatory-state institutions and organizations: Beliefs, violence, conquest, coercion, and rent seeking. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00667-7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Candela, R. A. (2019). Productive specialization, peaceful cooperation and the problem of the predatory state: Lessons from comparative historical political economy. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00657-9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bokros, L. (2013). Accidental occidental: Economics and culture of transition in Mitteleuropa, the Baltic and the Balkan Area. Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bozóki, A., & Hegedűs, D. (2018). An externally constrained hybrid regime: Hungary in the European Union. Democratization, 25, 1173–1189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brückner, G. (2015). Kötélbarátság – Puritán Milliárdos [Rope friendship – austere billionaire]. Figyelő.

  • Brückner, G. (2019). Takarékok végjátéka: két hónap maradt a mindent lezáró einstandig [The endgame of savings cooperatives: Two months remain until the final takeover]. Index.hu.

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The limits of liberty: Between anarchy and leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassani, A. (2014). Hybrid what? Partial consensus and persistent divergences in the analysis of hybrid regimes. International Political Science Review, 35, 542–558.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chernykh, L. (2011). Profit or politics? Understanding renationalizations in Russia. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17, 1237–1253.

    Google Scholar 

  • CRCB. (2016). Competitive intensity, overpricing, corruption risks and crony capitalism in Hungary 2009-2015. Budapest: Corruption Research Center Budapest.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crettez, B. (2019). Pareto-minimality in the jungle. Public Choice.

  • Családi lista 2019 – Forbes [Family List 2019 – Forbes] (2019). Forbes Magyarország.

  • Csurgó, D., & Szémann, T. (2017). Ő a valódi gazdasági csoda [He is the real economic miracle]. Index.hu.

  • Dávid, F. (2013). A takarékszövetkezetek Trianonja [The Trianon of savings cooperatives]. Népszabadság.

  • Dull, S. (2018). Megszűnt öt adófajta, de jön a bevándorlási különadó [Five taxes are repealed, but a special tax on immigration is introduced]. Index.hu.

  • Dunai, M. (2018). How Europe’s taxpayers will bankroll Viktor Orban’s friends and family. Reuters.

  • Epstein, R. (1985). Takings: Private property and the power of eminent domain. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erdélyi, K. (2019). The Mészáros empire won public tenders worth €826 million last year, 93 percent of which came from European Union funds. atlatszo.hu. Retrieved September 3, 2019, from https://english.atlatszo.hu/2019/01/17/the-meszaros-empire-won-public-tenders-worth-e826-million-last-year-93-percent-of-which-came-from-european-union-funds/.

  • ESMA. (2015). Cégtörténet [Company history] [WWW Document]. ESMA Reklám Zrt. Retrieved September 3, 2019, from https://esma.hu/cegtortenet.

  • Eyal, G., Szelényi, I., & Townsley, E. (1998). Making capitalism without capitalists: Class formation and elite struggles in post-communist Central Europe. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferenczi, K. (2013). Gellérthegyi lakásokban Orbán gyerekei, Garancsinál lakik Gáspár [Orbán’s children live in flats in Gellérthegy, Gáspár lives at Garancsi]. Népszabadság Online.

  • Firestone, T. (2009). Armed injustice: Abuse of the law and complex crime in post-Soviet Russia. Denver Journal of International Law and Policy, 38, 555–580.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishman, R. M. (1990). Rethinking state and regime: Southern Europe’s transition to democracy. World Politics, 42, 422–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisun, O. (2019). Neopatrimonialism in post-Soviet Eurasia. In B. Magyar (Ed.), Stubborn structures: Reconceptualizing post-communist regimes (pp. 75–96). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fokasz, O. (2018). Gyorsan kaszálna tízmilliárdokat vasútfelújítással? A receptet Mészáros Lőrinctől lesheti el [Want to make tens of billions with railroad reconstruction? Lőrinc Mészáros shows you how]. HVG.

  • Friedman, D. D. (2015). Police, courts, and laws—on the market. In The machinery of freedom: Guide to a radical capitalism. CreateSpace Independent Publishing Platform, New York (pp. 110–116).

  • Friedrichs, D. O. (2009). Trusted criminals: White collar crime in contemporary society (4th ed.). Belmont, CA: Cengage Learning.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frye, T. (2017). Property rights and property wrongs: How power, institutions, and norms shape economic conflict in Russia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frye, T., & Shleifer, A. (1997). The invisible hand and the grabbing hand. The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings of the hundred and fourth annual meeting of the American Economic Association (Vol. 87, pp. 354–358).

  • Gagyi, Á., & Gerőcs, T. (2019). The political economy of Hungary’s new “slave law.” Lefteast. Retrieved September 23, 2019, from https://www.criticatac.ro/lefteast/the-political-economy-of-hungarys-new-slave-law/.

  • Grossman, H. I. (1995). Rival kleptocrats: The mafia versus the state. In G. Fiorentini & S. Peltzman (Eds.), Economics of organised crime. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guliyev, F. (2011). Personal rule, neopatrimonialism, and regime typologies: Integrating Dahlian and Weberian approaches to regime studies. Democratization, 18, 575–601.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hale, H. E. (2015). Patronal politics: Eurasian regime dynamics in comparative perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellman, J. S., Jones, G., & Kaufmann, D. (2003). Seize the state, seize the day: State capture and influence in transition economies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31, 751–773.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2018). Political capitalism: How economic and political power is made and maintained. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2019). Progressive democracy: The ideology of the modern predatory state. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00637-z.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jávor, I., & Jancsics, D. (2012). Corrupt governmental networks. International Public Management Journal, 15, 62–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jávor, I., & Jancsics, D. (2016). The role of power in organizational corruption: An empirical study. Administration & Society, 48, 527–558.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jenei, M. (2014). Offshore cégeknél landoltak a rezsimilliárdok [Billions from utilities went to offshore companies]. Index.hu.

  • Jenei, M. (2018). Eltörlik a tranzakciós illetéket a 20 ezer alatti átutalásoknál [Tax repealed for transactions under HUF 20 thousand]. Index.hu.

  • Judah, B. (2014). Fragile empire: How Russia fell in and out of love with Vladimir Putin. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller-Alánt, Á. (2018). Az ellopott Balaton: Orbán emberei megszereznek mindent [The stolen Balaton: Orbán’s men get everything]. Magyar Narancs.

  • Király, J. (2015). A bankszektor átalakítása 2010–000 [The restructuring of the banking sector 2010-?]. In B. Magyar & J. Vásárhelyi (Eds.), Magyar Polip 3 – a posztkommunista maffiaállam (pp. 167–205). Budapest: Noran Libro.

    Google Scholar 

  • Király, J. (2016). A magyar bankrendszer tulajdonosi struktúrájának átalakulása [The changing ownership structure of the Hungarian banking system]. Közgazdasági Szemle, 63, 725–761.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klíma, M. (2019). Informal politics in post-communist Europe: Political parties, clientelism and state capture (1st ed.). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Konończuk, W. (2015). Oligarchs after the Maidan: The old system in a “new” Ukraine (Policy Paper No. 162), OSW Commentary.

  • Kornai, J. (2015). Hungary’s U-turn. Society and Economy in Central and Eastern Europe, 37, 279–329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krasztev, P., & Til, J. V. (Eds.). (2015). The Hungarian patient: Social opposition to an illiberal democracy. Budapest: Central European University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreatív.hu. (2015). Fidesz-közeli lett az ESMA, rögtön nem veszélyesek a lámpaoszlopreklámok [ESMA belongs to Fidesz, lamp-post posters are suddenly not dangerous]. Kreatív.

  • Lakner, Z. (2017). Links in the chain: Patron-client relations in the mafia state. In B. Magyar & J. Vásárhelyi (Eds.), Twenty-five sides of a post-communist mafia state (pp. 149–180). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lanskoy, M., & Myles-Primakoff, D. (2018). Power and plunder in Putin’s Russia. Journal of Democracy, 29, 76–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ledeneva, A. V. (2006). How Russia really works: The informal practices that shaped post-Soviet politics and business. New York: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T. (2007). Anarchy, monopoly, and predation. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE)/Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 163, 467–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. T., King, M. S., & Fegley, T. J. (2019). Regulating quack medicine. Public Choice.

  • Levitsky, S., & Way, L. (2010). Competitive authoritarianism: Hybrid regimes after the Cold War. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, P. (1996). From prebendalism to predation: The political economy of decline in Nigeria. The Journal of Modern African Studies, 34, 79–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (2012). Patterns of democracy: Government forms and performance in thirty-six countries (2nd ed.). New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luong, P. J. (2002). Institutional change and political continuity in post-Soviet Central Asia: Power, perceptions, and pacts. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luong, P. J. (2004). The transformation of Central Asia: States and societies from Soviet rule to independence. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magyar, B. (2016). Post-communist mafia state: The case of Hungary. Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magyar, B. (2017). The post-communist mafia state as a form of criminal state. In B. Magyar & J. Vásárhelyi (Eds.), Twenty-five sides of a post-communist mafia state (pp. 85–110). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magyar, B. (2019a). From free market corruption risk to the certainty of a state-run criminal organization (using Hungary as an example). In B. Magyar (Ed.), Stubborn structures: Reconceptualizing post-communist regimes (pp. 461–486). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magyar, B. (2019b). Towards a terminology for post-communist regimes. In B. Magyar (Ed.), Stubborn structures: Reconceptualizing post-communist regimes (pp. 97–176). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magyar, B., & Madlovics, B. (Forthcoming). The anatomy of post-communist regimes: A conceptual framework. Budapest: CEU Press.

  • Magyar, B., & Vásárhelyi, J. (Eds.). (2017). Twenty-five sides of a post-communist mafia state. Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markus, S. (2012). Secure property as a bottom-up process: Firms, stakeholders, and predators in weak states (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2143322). Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY.

  • Markus, S. (2015). Property, predation, and protection: Piranha capitalism in Russia and Ukraine. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markus, S. (2017). The Atlas that has not shrugged: Why Russia’s oligarchs are an unlikely force for change. Dædalus - Journal of the American Academy of Arts & Sciences, 146, 101–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, M. C. (2019). Trade and the predatory state: Ricardian exchange with armed competition for resources: a diagrammatic exposition. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00672-w.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, M. C., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: The invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mihályi, P. (2014). Re-nationalization in post-communist Hungary (2010-2013). In The PB Report 2013/2014. Privatization Barometer (pp. 46–50).

  • Mihályi, P. (2016). Diszkriminatív, piac- és versenyellenes állami gazdaságpolitika Magyarországon (2010–2015 [Discriminative, anti-market and anti-competition state economic policy in Hungary (2010-2015)].

  • Minakov, M. (2019). Republic of clans: The evolution of the Ukrainian political system. In B. Magyar (Ed.), Stubborn structures: Reconceptualizing post-communist regimes (pp. 217–245). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moselle, B., & Polak, B. (2001). A model of a predatory state. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 17, 1–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murtazashvili, J., & Murtazashvili, I. (2019). Wealth-destroying states. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00675-7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagy, G. M. (2019). Club Rezsim: Mészáros Lőrincék átszabják Balatonaligát [Club Regime: Lőrinc Mészáros and friends reform Balatonaliga]. Magyar Narancs.

  • North, D. C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. The American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (2000). Power and prosperity: Outgrowing communist and capitalist dictatorships. New York, NY: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orbán, V. (2014). Speech at the 25th Bálványos Summer Open University and Student Camp. http://2010-2015.miniszterelnok.hu/in_english_article/_prime_minister_viktor_orban_s_speech_at_the_25th_balvanyos_summer_free_university_and_student_camp

  • Orbán, V. (2018). Speech at the 29th Bálványos Summer Open University and Student Camp. https://www.kormany.hu/en/the-prime-minister/the-prime-minister-s-speeches/prime-minister-viktor-orban-s-speech-at-the-29th-balvanyos-summer-open-university-and-student-camp

  • Pappas, T. S. (2019). Populists in power. Journal of Democracy, 30, 70–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pethő, A. (2011). Állami milliárdok mennek Simicskáék plakátcége felé [State billions go to Simicska’s billboard company]. Origo.hu.

  • Pethő, A. (2019). Inside the fall of the oligarch who turned against Viktor Orbán. Direkt36). Retrieved September 5, 2019, from https://www.direkt36.hu/en/feltarul-simicska-bukasanak-titkos-tortenete/.

  • Petrov, N., Lipman, M., & Hale, H. E. (2014). Three dilemmas of hybrid regime governance: Russia from Putin to Putin. Post-Soviet Affairs, 30, 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rádi, A. (2018). Indebtedness of national oligarchs risk banking system, experts say. atlatszo.hu. Retrieved September 3, 2019, from https://english.atlatszo.hu/2018/02/02/indebtedness-of-national-oligarchs-risk-banking-system-experts-say/.

  • Rényi, P. D. (2014). Orbán Viktor vs. Simicska Lajos – csak egy maradhat talpon [Viktor Orbán vs. Lajos Simicska – only one can remain]. Magyar Narancs.

  • Rényi, P. D. (2019). The rise and fall of the man who created Viktor Orbán’s system. 444 - tldr. Retrieved April 30, 2019, from https://tldr.444.hu/2019/04/22/the-rise-and-fall-of-the-man-who-created-viktor-orbans-system.

  • Rojansky, M. A. (2014). Corporate raiding in Ukraine: Causes, methods and consequences. Demokratizatsiya, 22, 411–443.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ryabov, A. (2019). The institution of power and ownership in the former U.S.S.R.: Origin, diversity of forms, and influence on transformation processes. In B. Magyar (Ed.), Stubborn structures: Reconceptualizing post-communist regimes (pp. 415–435). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sajó, A. (1999). Limiting government: An introduction to constitutionalism. Budapest: Central European University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sakwa, R. (2008). Putin and the oligarchs. New Political Economy, 13, 185–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sakwa, R. (2012). Systemic stalemate: Reiderstvo and the dual state. In N. Robinson (Ed.), The political economy of Russia (pp. 69–96). Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sallai, D., & Schnyder, G. (2018). The transformation of post-socialist capitalism – from developmental state to clan state? (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 3100775). Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY.

  • Sarkadi Nagy, M. (2015). Simicska területére nyomul be az új fideszes háttérember [A new member of Fidesz’s machinery goes to Simicska’s territory]. atlatszo.hu. Retrieved September 2, 2019, from http://blog.atlatszo.hu/2015/04/simicska-teruletere-nyomul-be-az-uj-fideszes-hatterember/.

  • Sartori, G. (1962). Constitutionalism: A preliminary discussion. The American Political Science Review, 56, 853–864.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. C. (2007). Strategies of commitment. In Strategies of commitment and other essays. Harvard: Harvard University Press (pp. 1–26).

  • Scheppele, K. L. (2018). Autocratic legalism. University of Chicago Law Review, 85, 545–583.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneper, W. D., & Guillén, M. F. (2004). Stakeholder rights and corporate governance: A cross-national study of hostile takeovers. Administrative Science Quarterly, 49, 263–295.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, Z. (2017). What’s boosting the world’s best-performing stock? Bloomberg. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2017-07-25/what-s-boosting-the-world-s-best-performing-stock.

  • Soós, K. A. (2017). Tributes paid through special taxes: Populism and the displacement of “aliens”. In B. Magyar & J. Vásárhelyi (Eds.), Twenty-five sides of a post-communist mafia state (pp. 259–278). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spirk, J. (2018). Szinte ingyen adja a plakátjait a kampányban Orbán barátjának cége [The company of Orbán’s friend offers its billboards in the campaign for almost nothing]. 24.hu.

  • Spirk, J. (2019). Garancsi cége a Fideszt hagyta kalózplakátolni, most már az ellenzéket is hagynia kell [Garancsi’s company let Fidesz to place advertisements illegally, now it must let the opposition, too]. 24.hu.

  • Stefes, C. H. (2006). Understanding post-Soviet transitions: Corruption, collusion and clientelism. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stringham, E. (2006). Overlapping jurisdictions, proprietary communities, and competition in the realm of law. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE)/Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 162, 516–534.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan, E. J. (2018). A brief history of the takings clause. In J. J. Gonzalez, R. L. Kemp, & J. Rosenthal (Eds.), Eminent domain and economic growth: Perspectives on benefits, harms and new trends (pp. 14–22). Jefferson: McFarland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svendsen, G. T. (2019). Two bandits or more? The case of Viking Age England. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00707-2.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Szabó, M. I. (2012). Simicska: ha nem tudja megvenni, megfojtja [Simicska: If he can’t buy it, he strangles it]. hvg.hu.

  • Szabó, B. (2019). Tisztességtelen játék – így születnek a sokmilliárdos NER-vagyonok [Dishonest game: This is how billions of wealth of NER are made]. 168 Óra.

  • Tamásné Szabó, Z. (2019). Club Aliga: 350 milliót kasszírozhatnak Mészárosék a nagycsaládos üdülésből [Club Aliga: Mészáros can get 350 million forints from the subsidized holiday of people with large families]. 24.hu.

  • Tilly, C. (1985). War making and state making as organized crime. In P. B. Evans, D. Rueschemeyer, & T. Skocpol (Eds.), Bringing the state back in (pp. 169–191). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tóth, G. I. (2018). Orbán kötélbarátját bebetonozták az elefántfülbizniszbe [Orbán’s rope friend is cemented in the outdoor advertising business]. hvg.hu.

  • Usher, D. (1992). The welfare economics of markets, voting and predation. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2015). The political economy of predation: Manhunting and the economics of escape. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2016). A positive theory of the predatory state. Public Choice, 168, 153–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2019). Introduction: A symposium on the predatory state. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00715-2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M., Batifoulier, P., & Da Silva, N. (2019). A theory of predatory welfare state and citizen welfare: The French case. Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00660-0.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varese, F. (2001). The Russian mafia: Private protection in a new market economy (1st ed.). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Várhegyi, É. (2017). The banks of the mafia state. In B. Magyar & J. Vásárhelyi (Eds.), Twenty-five sides of a post-communist mafia state (pp. 295–309). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Várhegyi, É. (2019). A bankszektor elrablása [The raiding of the banking sector]. Mozgó Világ 3–14.

  • Vásárhelyi, M. (2017). The workings of the media: A brainwashing and money-laundering mechanism. In B. Magyar & J. Vásárhelyi (Eds.), Twenty-five sides of a post-communist mafia state (pp. 491–525). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viktorov, I. (2019). Russia’s network state and reiderstvo practices: The roots to weak property rights protection after the post-communist transition. In B. Magyar (Ed.), Stubborn structures: Reconceptualizing post-communist regimes (pp. 437–459). Budapest: CEU Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volkov, V. (2002). Violent entrepreneurs: The use of force in the making of Russian capitalism (1st ed.). Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vörös, I. (2015). Hungary’s constitutional evolution during the last 25 Years. Südosteuropa, 63, 173–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1991). Politics as a vocation. In M. Weber, H. Gerth, & C. W. Mills (Eds.), From Max Weber: Essays in sociology (pp. 77–128). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wedel, J. R. (2003). Clans, cliques and captured states: Rethinking ‘transition’ in Central and Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. Journal of International Development, 15, 427–440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yakovlev, A. (2006). The evolution of business: State interaction in Russia: From state capture to business capture? Europe-Asia Studies, 58, 1033–1056.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yakovlev, A., Sobolev, A., & Kazun, A. (2014). Means of production versus means of coercion: Can Russian business limit the violence of a predatory state? Post-Soviet Affairs, 30, 171–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yavlinsky, G. (2013). Realeconomik: The hidden cause of the great recession (and how to avert the next one). New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Bálint Magyar.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Madlovics, B., Magyar, B. Post-communist predation: modeling reiderstvo practices in contemporary predatory states. Public Choice 187, 247–273 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00772-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00772-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation