Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Corruption predictability and corruption voting in Asian democracies

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I examine how the structure of corrupt exchanges between voters and politicians—an important-yet-underexplored form of informal institutions—shapes voters’ electoral behavior toward corruption. I argue that when voters have a clear idea of whom to bribe to secure desired services and how much they need to offer, they are less likely to engage in corruption voting and hold corrupt incumbents electorally accountable for their malfeasance. Utilizing the World Business Environment Survey on corruption predictability and the Asian Barometer survey on voters’ electoral behaviors, I report empirical evidence that institutionalized corruption promotes greater electoral tolerance of corrupt politicians in Asian democracies. The results hold against a number of robustness checks. The paper thus furthers our understanding of the effect of informal political institutions on corruption voting as well as Asia’s corruption exceptionalism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Perhaps one of the most illustrative examples of this paradox is Tanaka Kakuei. The then-prime minister of Japan collected career-high votes from his constituency and was reelected to the Diet 15 consecutive times after the 1983 “Tanaka Verdict Election”, despite being tried in court for bribery during the infamous Lockheed scandal (Johnson 1986).

  2. Reed (2005) finds that legislators in Japan who were convicted of corruption actually enjoy post-conviction vote-share increases. Similarly, Peters and Welch (1980) and Chang et al. (2010) find that, even in light of evidence of corruption, voters in American and Italian legislative elections failed to penalize corrupt legislators. Relatedly, Karahan et al. (2006) argue that as the value of office holding increases, politicians are more likely to spend more efforts enticing citizens to vote. Using a unique dataset from an FBI investigation in a statewide corruption scandal, they find that voters in Mississippi are more likely to vote in counties with higher levels of corruption.

  3. Kurer (2001, p. 79), for instance, suggests that “…ignorance about the effects of corruption, about the alternatives available, and about the intentions of those standing for election are possible reasons for voters to support corrupt politics.” Olken (2009) examines Indonesian villagers’ knowledge and beliefs about local corruption, finding that Indonesian villagers are only vaguely aware of the existence and effects of corruption.

  4. In their study of Brazil’s municipal elections, Ferraz and Finan (2008) find that incumbents subjected to anti-corruption audits before elections did not suffer significant electoral penalties. But after accounting for the level of corruption revealed in the audit, the authors find that corruption audits strongly reduce the incumbent’s chance of reelection. Similarly, Winters and Weitz-Shapiro (2013) show that voters are less likely to support corrupt candidates after receiving credible information about such behavior. Finally, Chang et al. (2010) show that Italian voters punished corrupt politicians only in the 1992–1994 legislature after the systematic corruption in Italy had been unearthed by the Clean Hands operation in the early 1990s.

  5. The famous quote “[Y]es, but he’s our bastard” by Franklin D. Roosevelt illustrates this line of reasoning.

  6. Philp (2002), for instance, highlights several basic components of corruption: it involves a public authority, it violates the public trust, it harms the public interest, and it benefits a third party by providing access to a good or service the third party could not otherwise obtain.

  7. The other two are the frequency with which transactions recur and the condition of asset specificity.

  8. Méon and Sekkat (2005) explicitly test and refute the “grease the wheels” hypothesis and show that corruption becomes even more detrimental to growth when the quality of governance is poor. Similarly, Cooray and Schneider (2018) further corroborate Méon and Sekkat’s study and find that corruption sands the wheels of financial sector activity.

  9. The calculus of voting model takes the form of V = B*P − C, where the probability of a person voting (V) is a function of the benefits from her preferred candidate getting elected (B) and the probability of casting the decisive vote (P), minus the costs of voting (C).

  10. Illustratively, consider that for Mr. Tanaka’s supporters in Niigata City, the term BI includes a high-speed train connecting Niigata to Tokyo, a new railroad station, and an atomic power plant (Johnson 1986).

  11. Consistent with the principal-agent model, the calculus of corruption voting model assumes that voters believe that politicians desire to be corrupt. If politicians prefer corruption, then, voters have to decide if they want politicians who can coordinate competently with bureaucrats and make corruption predictable, or if they prefer politicians who cannot coordinate and consequently throw the corruption structure into chaos.

  12. Authors' interview with a Taiwanese legislator.

  13. As Levitsky (1998, p. 80) argues succinctly, “institutionalization is a process by which actors’ expectations are stabilized around rules and practices…. The entrenchment of ‘rules of the game’ tend to narrow actors’ behavioral options by raising the social, psychic, or material costs of breaking those rules.”

  14. Chang and Kerr (2017) treat corruption tolerance as citizens’ proclivity to condemn a political actor’s engagement in corruption. Other studies also have used both elites’ and citizens’ willingness to sanction corruption as an indication of the extent to which corrupt acts are tolerable (Heidenheimer 2002).

  15. Levitsky (1998, p. 88) defines value infusion as “a process in which organizational actors' goals shift from the pursuit of particular objectives through the organization to the goal of preserving or perpetuating the organization per se”.

  16. Phrase borrowed from Janda (1980, p. 19).

  17. Specifically, predictability = 7 − 0.5*(country average for Q.15 + country average for Q.16).

  18. One reasonably can expect that the levels of predictability across different types of corruption are likely to be correlated since political elites have incentives to discipline all types of public official to maintain the overarching structure of the corruption network. Indeed, as Fisman and Golden (2017) suggest, bureaucrats often are organized into corruption networks by politicians and the mutual dependence between the two groups often forms a corruption hierarchy wherein political and bureaucratic corruption are strongly intertwined. However, other scholars can counter-argue that corruption predictability varies depending on the types of corruption and the participants involved.

  19. To maximize the available information, I rely on the most current wave of ABS data and I focus on democracies that Freedom House considers free (Indonesia, Japan, Mongolia, the Philippines, South Korea and Taiwan) and partially free (Hong Kong, Malaysia, Singapore and Thailand). My results also hold if I drop the partially free countries and focus only on the free countries.

  20. Each item is scaled on a 1–4 range (one = very difficult; four = very easy).

  21. This proxy has obvious weaknesses. While one reasonably can assume that voters in predictable corruption structures will find public services accessible, the reverse might not hold, as many alternative factors might affect access to public services. Despite the potential measurement errors, the proxy remains informative as it taps into respondents’ perceptions of public services provision. At a more practical level, access to public services is the best option available for capturing the notion of corruption predictability in the ABS data. Statistically, it represents a conservative test as one would expect that a more accurate measure would yield even stronger results.

  22. The variable asks citizens to rate the overall economic condition of their country today (one = very bad, five = very good).

  23. The variable asks respondents how fair they think the distribution of income is in their country (one = very unfair, four = very fair).

  24. The variable asks respondents how well they think the government responds to citizens’ needs (one = not responsive at all; four = very responsive).

  25. The variable asks respondents whether they agree with the statement: “Between elections, the people have no way of holding the government responsible for its actions” (one = strongly agree; four = strongly disagree).

  26. The binary variable female takes the value of one if the respondent is that sex.

  27. To ease interpretation, I recode public services access into a binary variable.

  28. For instance, when bureaucrats independently raise the bribe price for passing the written driving test, they can discourage citizens from taking the subsequent road test.

  29. To facilitate interpretation, I recode the bureaucratic professionalism variable so that countries with values higher (lower) than the middle category are considered high- (low-) professionalism countries.

  30. Graf Lambsdorff (2002) uses data from the World Bank to substantiate his arguments, showing empirically that corruption predictability indeed contributes to more corruption.

  31. As Keefer (2007) notes, the fundamental challenge in governance for young democracies is political competitors' inability to make credible pre-electoral promises.

  32. Lee and Oh (2007) classify countries into four different categories: high in pervasiveness, but low in arbitrariness (Indonesia and China); low in both pervasiveness and arbitrariness (Hong Kong and Singapore); high in both pervasiveness and arbitrariness (India); and low in pervasiveness, but high in arbitrariness (Malaysia).

  33. One typical example is the exchange of legal campaign contributions for legislation favoring specific groups at the expense of general public. Dincer and Johnston (2015) show that most American citizens equate campaign donations with corruption.

  34. For instance, politicians might find it more difficult to deliver a public procurement contract as large as originally promised.

References

  • Anduiza, E., Gallego, A., & Muñoz, J. (2013). Turning a blind eye: Experimental evidence of partisan bias in attitudes toward corruption. Comparative Political Studies,46(12), 1664–1692.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Yoon, Y. T. (2000). Symmetric tragedies: Commons and anticommons. Journal of Law and Economics,43(1), 1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campos, N. F., & Giovannoni, F. (2007). Lobbying, corruption and political influence. Public Choice,131, 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campos, J. E., Lien, D., & Pradhan, S. (1999). The impact of corruption on investment: Predictability matters. World Development,27(6), 1059–1067.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E. C., Golden, M. A., & Hill, S. J. (2010). Legislative malfeasance and political accountability. World Politics,62, 177–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E. C., & Kerr, N. N. (2017). An insider–outsider theory of popular tolerance for corrupt politicians. Governance,30(1), 67–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooray, A., & Schneider, F. (2018). Does corruption throw sand into or grease the wheels of financial sector development? Public Choice,117(1–2), 111–133.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlström, C., Teorell, J., Dahlberg, S., Hartmann, F., Lindberg, A., & Nistotskaya, M. (2015). The QoG expert survey dataset II. Sweden: University of Gothenburg, The Quality of Government Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Vries, C. E., & Solaz, H. (2017). The electoral consequences of corruption. Annual Review of Political Science,20(1), 391–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • della Porta, D., & Vannucci, A. (1999). Corrupt exchanges: Actors, resources, and mechanisms of political corruption. New Jersey: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dincer, O., & Johnston, M. (2015). Measuring illegal and legal corruption in American states: Some results from the Edmond J. Safra Center for Ethics Corruption in America Survey. Edmond J. Safra Working Papers No. 58.

  • Ferraz, C., & Finan, F. (2008). Exposing corrupt politicians: The effects of Brazil’s publicly released audits on electoral outcomes. Quarterly Journals of Economics,123(2), 703–745.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, R., & Golden, M. A. (2017). Corruption: What everyone needs to know. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gardiner, J. A. (2002). Defining corruption. In A. J. Heidenheimer & M. Johnston (Eds.), Political corruption: Concepts and contexts. New Jersey: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Graf Lambsdorff, J. (2002). How confidence facilitates illegal transactions: An empirical approach. American Journal of Economic and Sociology,61(4), 829–853.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heidenheimer, A. (2002). Perspectives on the perception of corruption. In A. J. In Heidenheimer & M. Johnston (Eds.), Political corruption: Concepts and contexts. New Jersey: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heidenheimer, A. J., & Johnston, M. (2002). Political corruption: Concepts and contexts. New Jersey: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal institutions and comparative politics: A research agenda. Perspectives on Politics,2(4), 725–740.

    Google Scholar 

  • Janda, K. (1980). Political parties: A cross-national survey. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, C. (1986). Tanaka Kakuei, structural corruption, and the advent of machine politics. Japan Journal of Japanese Studies,12(1), 1–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, M. (1991). Historical conflict and the rise of standards. Journal of Democracy,2(4), 48–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, M. (2005). Syndromes of corruption: Wealth, power, and democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karahan, G., Coats, R. M., & Shughart, W. F. (2006). Corrupt political jurisdictions and voter participation. Public Choice,126(1), 87–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., & Vicente, P. (2011). Legal corruption. Economic and Politics,23, 195–219.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keefer, P. (2007). Clientelism, credibility, and the policy choices of young democracies. American Journal of Political Science,51(4), 804–821.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khan, M. (2002). Patron-client networks and the economic effects of corruption in Asia. In A. J. Heidenheimer & M. Johnston (Eds.), Political corruption: Concepts and contexts. New Jersey: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kitschelt, H., & Wilkinson, S. (2007). Patrons, clients and policies: Patterns of democratic accountability and political competition. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurer, O. (2001). Why do voters support corrupt politicians? In A. Jain (Ed.), The political economy of corruption. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, S.-H., & Oh, K. (2007). Corruption in Asia: Pervasiveness and arbitrariness. Asia Pacific Journal of Management,24(1), 97–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitsky, S. (1998). Institutionalization and Peronism: The concept, the case and the case for unpacking the concept. Party Politics,4(1), 77–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lust, E. (2009). Competitive clientelism in the Middle East. Journal of Democracy,20(3), 122–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malesky, E., & Samphantharak, K. (2008). Predictable corruption and firm investment: Evidence from a natural experiment and survey of Cambodian entrepreneurs. Quarterly Journal of Political Science,3, 227–267.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manzetti, L., & Wilson, C. J. (2007). Why do corrupt governments maintain public support? Comparative Political Studies,40, 949–970.

    Google Scholar 

  • Méon, P., & Sekkat, K. (2005). Does corruption grease or sand the wheels of growth? Public Choice,122, 69–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morris, S. (2011). Forms of corruption. CESifo DICE Report,9(2), 10–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olken, B. (2009). Corruption perceptions vs. corruption reality. Journal of Public Economics,93, 950–964.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peters, J., & Welch, S. (1980). The effects of charges of corruption on voting behavior in congressional elections. American Political Science Review,74(3), 697–708.

    Google Scholar 

  • Philp, M. (2002). Conceptualizing political corruption. In A. J. Heidenheimer & M. Johnston (Eds.), Political corruption: Concepts and contexts. New Jersey: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Philp, M., & David-Barrett, E. (2015). Realism about political corruption. Annual Review of Political Science,18, 387–402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, B. G., & Whitten, G. D. (1993). A cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context. American Journal of Political Science,37(2), 391–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramseyer, J. M., & Rosenbluth, F. M. (1993). Japan’s political marketplace. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reed, S. (2005). Japan: Haltingly toward a two-party. In M. Gallagher & P. Mitchell (Eds.), The politics of electoral systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H., & Ordeshook, P. C. (1968). A theory of the calculus of voting. American Political Science Review,62(1), 25–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999). Corruption and government: Causes, consequences, and reform. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwindt-Bayer, L. A., & Tavits, M. (2016). Clarity of responsibility, accountability and corruption. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1993). Corruption. Quarterly Journal of Economics,108(3), 599–617.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tavits, M. (2007). Clarity of responsibility and corruption. American Journal of Political Science,51(1), 218–229.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1965). The politics of bureaucracy. Washington: Public Affairs Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wedeman, A. (2002). Development and corruption: The east Asian paradox. In E. T. Gomez (Ed.), Political business in East Asia. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1981). The economics of organization: The transaction cost approach. American Journal of Sociology,87, 548–577.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winters, M. S., & Weitz-Shapiro, R. (2013). Lacking information or condoning corruption: When will voters support corrupt politicians? Journal of Comparative Politics,45(4), 418–436.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Development Report. (1997). Washington. DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research was supported by the National Research Foundation of Korea (NRF-2017S1A3A2066657). A previous version was presented in the Comparative Politics Workshop in the Department of Political Science at Michigan State University, the Department of Economics at Illinois State University, the Department of Political Science and Diplomacy at Sungkyunkwan University in South Korea, and the Institute of Political Science at Academia Sinica in Taiwan. I thank all of the participants for their helpful comments. Finally, I am indebted to Jessica A. Schoenherr for her indispensable research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eric C. C. Chang.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chang, E.C.C. Corruption predictability and corruption voting in Asian democracies. Public Choice 184, 307–326 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00760-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00760-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation