Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The resource curse literature as seen through the appropriability lens: a critical survey

  • Literature survey
  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This critical survey demonstrates for the first time that the underlying tenets of the resource curse/blessing are borrowed directly from “staple theory”. It also focuses uniquely on appropriability with two key issues in mind: (1) state appropriability of assets, and (2) the mobility of assets to thwart appropriation. In the previous resource curse literature, mobility has been framed using the concept of lootability. Appropriability is related to non-lootable assets, such as oil, that can be seized by the state or rival private oligarchs. Recent resource curse research has addressed appropriability by distinguishing between point-source resources and diffuse-source resources. This survey demonstrates that this distinction is borrowed from staple theory, and that point-source and diffuse-source resources are defined in terms of geographical concentration/dispersion rather than institutional characteristics. By establishing that political institutions, markets and incentives are the most important elements for determining appropriability, the resource curse/blessing literature could support a general positive theory of the predatory state.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for example, Bulte et al. (2005), Deacon, (2011), Frankel (2010), Humphreys et al. (2007), Le Billon (2012), Ross (2004, 2012, 2014), Van der Ploeg (2011), and Wick and Bulte (2009).

  2. While in American English, “staple” refers to foods such as rice and potatoes that are part of virtually everyone’s diet, the term was used initially to describe ‘cod fisheries’ and ‘fur trade’, and then extended to the chief commodity produced by a region. As North wrote: “It is customarily thought of as describing products of extractive industry. Since my concept of the export commodities of a region may include products of secondary or tertiary industry as well, I shall use the term ‘exportable commodities’ (or services) to denote the individual items, and the export base to denote collectively the exportable commodities (or services) of a region. In young regions, typically dependent on extractive industry, my exportable commodities and Innis’s export staples are synonymous” (North 1955, pp. 247–248). Innis’s focus (1930/1956, 1940/1954) was on cod fisheries and the fur trade to explain Canadian economic growth. Staple theory is not orthodox economic theory. Its key premise is that national economic growth can be generated by exporting a staple good (particularly export crops and minerals). It was argued that staple production is a potent force in long-term economic development by means of linkage effects (forward, backward and final demand). The theory was largely a Canadian creation (Mackintosh and Innis) that was taken up and made more general by Douglass North, Baldwin, Hirschman, Watkins and Caves after the Second World War. A pessimist version of the theory points to the possibility of a staple “trap” owing to the absence of linkage effects for some such commodities. Baldwin’s bipolar economy provides an illustration of the staple trap. The historical background and the evolution of the ‘staple theory’ are substantiated in North (1955), Baldwin (1956), Watkins (1963) and Schedvin (1990). Staple theory has been a source of inspiration for recent work in economic history (Engerman and Sokoloff 1997; Sokoloff and Engerman 2000; Nugent and Robinson 2010). Section 3 will elaborate on the theory and its relationship to the natural resource curse in greater detail.

  3. Although the theory was originally Canadian, some authors have formulated it independently in other contexts. For example, Shafer (1994, p. 2; emphasis added) developed a sectoral analysis of the developmental prospects of states according to which a state’s capacity to promote economic development depends on the “attributes of the leading sector through which it is tied to the international economy: light manufacturing, mineral extraction, peasant cash crop production, or industrial plantation crop production”. While he never explicitly referred to staple theory, he rediscovered it through his comparative political economy.

  4. Several formalized versions of the staple theory have been formulated. Caves (1963) offered an elegant model of ‘vent for surplus’, and suggested a connection with neoclassical growth theory.

  5. Kindleberger (1958) appears to have been correct in modeling three scenarios regarding the effects of foreign trade on economic development, namely leading, lagging and balancing effects.

  6. A Venezuelan energy minister and a founder of OPEC named Juan Pablo Pérez Alfonzo complained in 1975: “I call petroleum the devil's excrement. It brings trouble…. Look at this locura—waste, corruption, consumption, our public services falling apart. And debt, debt we shall have for years” (The Economist, May 22, 2003).

  7. Collier and Hoeffler (1998, 2004) claimed that primary commodity exports tend to reinforce the probability of civil war. Various other econometric tests of the relationship between civil war and natural resource endowments do not confirm that result (Fearon and Laitin 2003; Elbadawi and Sambanis 2002; Hegre 2002). However, empirical tests often find that lootable commodities such as gemstones and drugs are associated with non-separatist civil wars, whereas oil (an unlootable good) is linked to the onset of separatist civil war (for a general survey, see Ross 2004).

  8. Ross (1999, p. 301) also referred to staple theory, but only to its optimistic version in a footnote, without discussing the staple trap—“States with abundant natural resources could easily overcome these capital shortfalls, thanks to both their ability to export primary commodities and their attractiveness to foreign investors. Their governments would also find it easier to collect revenues and hence provide public goods”—thus ignoring the concept of the staple trap as the resource curse’s precursor.

  9. By ‘South’, the authors mean to include the states of the deep South as well as the mountain states of Tennessee, Kentucky and West Virginia. “The herding economy moved with the Scotch-Irish to the West—that is, to Texas and Oklahoma and the mostly southern portions of the mountain West that were settled by southerners.” (Ibid, p. 9).

  10. Nisbett and Cohen (1996, p. 8) refer to the immigration of the Scotch-Irish to North America that started in the late seventeenth century and was completed by the early nineteenth century: “Their new land, if anything, served to reinforce the herding economy practiced by the Scotch-Irish immigrants. With its mountains and wide-open spaces, America, especially the Appalachians and the South, was ideally suited to the herding life and to horticulture.”

  11. Unfortunately, the authors did not acknowledge Scott’s ‘paternity’ in this respect. While their model captures Scott’s distinction between the two types of cultivars in archaic agricultural economies, their approach to the state as provider of public goods (Mayshar et al. 2015, pp. 4, 6) is diametrically opposed to Scott’s viewpoint of the state as a predatory institution. That point is highlighted by Scott (2017, p. 268), who wrote, “While Mayshar et al. correctly associate cereal grains with state and hierarchy and root crops with nonstate, egalitarian societies, they wrongly take subsistence strategies as a primordial given and not the product of political institutions and political choice.”

  12. Humphreys et al. (2007) identified four sources of income volatility: variation in rates of extraction over time; variability in the timing of payments by corporations to states; fluctuations in the value of the natural resource produced; and international lending that follows oil ‘boom–bust’ cycles.

  13. Oil can serve as collateral, or at least as an informal guarantee, because oil earnings are easy to identify and to direct toward debt servicing (Humphreys et al. 2007).

  14. Unlike alluvial diamonds, kimberlite diamonds require skilled labor for extraction and therefore are vulnerable to state appropriation rather than to looting by rebels.

  15. Robinson et al. (2006, p. 448) criticized “the Becker-Olson approach of thinking of the state as simply an aggregator of pressure from interest groups”. However, Becker and Olson took different approaches regarding lobbying activities in the political market and must be distinguished (see Vahabi 2011).

  16. Land distribution was the central piece of the Shah’s claim for a “revolution from above” (‘White revolution’) as opposed to a “revolution from below” (Red revolution) (see Hooglund 1982; Vahabi 2018).

  17. Nugent and Robinson (2010, pp. 47, 54) explicitly referred to “the powerful set of ideas developed in the context of the ‘staple thesis’”. But they did not consider endowments to be fate, commenting, “Contrary to the nascent literature in economics attempting to explain institutional differences, our research suggests that the equilibrium institutional structure is not uniquely determined by factor endowments and depends crucially on the nature of political cleavages and competition in society.”

  18. Many other secondary factors—for example, the ‘storability’ or ‘perishability’ of assets, their ‘vulnerability to disease’, and their character as ‘labor-intensive’ or ‘capital-intensive’—affect the appropriability of assets (for an analysis of how those factors affect crops, see Scott 2009, pp. 202–204). Vahabi (2016a, b) focused on only the primary factors influencing all types of assets (physical as well as pecuniary).

  19. Conventional indicators of institutional quality are not appropriate for measuring institutional appropriability. New indicators, such as the sizes of armies, the backgrounds of elites, the types of state revenues and spending programs, and geopolitical positioning in international politics (among others), are needed to fully capture institutional appropriability.

  20. According to Snyder and Bhavani (2005, p. 571), spending on tax capacity increases the state’s “take” both from artisans and industrial firms. This form of state spending “should be considered a revenue-enhancing investment because it leads directly to an increase in future revenue”.

  21. Spending on coercive capacity means increasing the state’s ability to identify and punish tax evaders. Moreover, “spending on coercive capacity has a revenue-conserving effect, because it improves the state’s ability to deter and defeat rebellions and thereby reduces the risk of the loss of revenue as a result of societal unrest.” (Snyder and Bhavani, 2005, p. 571).

  22. Le Billon (2001, p. 573) presented a similar table with examples of countries for each case of conflict. He also acknowledged other relevant factors such as legality, transportability, obstructability and substantiates his fourfold categorization (Le Billon 2012, pp. 28–42).

  23. “Assets” includes all types of goods, such as agricultural products like cereals and famine goods, and is not limited to natural resources such as oil, narcotics, or diamonds or other gemstones.

  24. As explained earlier (see introduction and Sect. 3), staple thesis insists on the importance of staples (defined as ‘exportable commodities or services’) in enhancing national economic growth through linkage effects (forward, backward and final demand).

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (1995). Reward structures and the allocation of talent. European Economic Review, 39(1), 17–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahmadov, A. (2014). Oil, democracy, and context a meta-analysis. Comparative Political Studies, 47(9), 1238–1267.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aslaksen, S. (2010). Oil and democracy: More than a cross-country correlation? Journal of Peace Research, 47(4), 421–431.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atabaki, T. (Forthcoming). A centurial social history of labor in the Iranian oil industry. Part one: 19081951.

  • Atkinson, G., & Hamilton, K. (2003). Savings, growth and the resource curse hypothesis. World Development, 31(11), 1793–1807.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auty, R. (1993). Sustaining development in the mineral economies: The resource curse thesis. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auty, R. (1997). Natural resource endowment, the state and development strategy. Journal of International Development, 9, 651–663.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auty, R. (2001a). Resource abundance and economic development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auty, R. (2001b). The political economy of resource-driven growth. European Economic Review, 45, 839–846.

    Google Scholar 

  • Auty, R. (2004). Natural resources and civil strife: A two-stage process. Geopolitics, 9(1), 29–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baland, J. M., & Francois, P. (2000). Rent-seeking and resource booms. Journal of Development Economics, 61(2), 527–542.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. (1956). Patterns of development in newly settled regions. Manchester School of Economics and Social Studies, 24, 161–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ballentine, K., & Sherman, J. (2003). The political economy of armed conflict: Beyond greed and grievance. Boulder, CO, New York: Lynne Rienner, International Peace Academy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bazzi, S., & Blattman, Ch. (2014). Economic shocks and conflict: Evidence from commodity prices. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6(4), 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, T. (2011). Finance and oil: Is there a resource curse in financial development? European Banking Center Discussion Paper, 004.

  • Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1218–1244.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boschini, A., Pettersson, J., & Roine, J. (2007). Resource curse or not: A question of appropriability. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 109(3), 593–617.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, K. (1960). Conflict and defense, a general theory. New York, Evanston and London: Harper and Row Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bulte, E., Damania, R., & Deacon, R. (2005). Resource intensity, institutions, and development. World Development, 33(7), 1029–1044.

    Google Scholar 

  • Busse, M., & Gröning, S. (2013). The resource curse revisited: Governance and natural resources. Public Choice, 154(1), 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caselli, F., & Cunningham, T. (2009). Leader behavior and the natural resource curse. Oxford Economic Papers, 61(4), 628–650.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R. (1963). ‘Vent for surplus’ models of trade and growth. In R. Baldwin et al. (Eds.), Trade, growth and the balance of payments: Essays in honor of Gottfried Haberler (pp. 95–115). Chicago: Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R. (1971). Export-led growth and the new economic history. In J. N. Bhagwati et al. (Eds.), Trade, balance of payments and growth (pp. 404–442). Amsterdam: North-Holland Pub. Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, W., Golder, M., & Golder, S. (2013). Power and politics: Insights from an exit, voice, and loyalty game. Manuscript: University of Michigan and Penn State University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P. (2000). Doing well out of war: An economic perspective. In M. Berdal & D. Malone (Eds.), Greed and grievance: Economic agendas in civil wars. Ottawa, Boulder, Colo: Lynne Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P. (2007). The bottom billion: Why the poorest countries are failing and what can be done about it. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P. (2009). Wars, guns and votes: Democracy in dangerous places. New York: Harper Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Bannon, I. (2003). Natural resources and violent conflict: Options and actions. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (1998). On the economic causes of civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 50, 563–573.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (1999). Justice-seeking and loot-seeking in civil war. Washington DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2004). Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 56(4), 563–596.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., Hoeffler, A., & Sӧderbom, M. (2006). Post-conflict risks, centre for the study of African economies. Department of Economics, University of Oxford

  • Cooter, R., & Ulen, T. (2012). Law and economics (6th ed.). Boston: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cramer, Ch. (2002). Homo economicus goes to war: Methodological individualism, rational choice and the political economy of war. World Development, 30(11), 1845–1864.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuaresma, J., Oberhofer, H., & Raschky, P. (2011). Oil and the duration of dictatorships. Public Choice, 148(3/4), 505–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deacon, R. (2011). The political economy of the natural resource curse: A survey of theory and evidence. Foundations and Trends (R) in Microeconomics, 7(2), 111–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deacon, R., & Rode, A. (2015). Rent seeking and the resource curse. Companion to the Political Economy of Rent Seeking, 227(14), 227–247.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1964). The exchange and enforcement of property rights. Journal of Law and Economics, 7, 11–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffield, M. (2001). Global governance and the new wars: The merging of development and security. London: Zed books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, T. (2008). Crude democracy: Natural resource wealth and political regimes. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Economic Focus. (2003). The devil’s excrement. The Economist, Finance and Economic Section, May 22nd. http://www.economist.com/node/1795921.

  • Elbadawi, I., & Sambanis, N. (2002). How much war will we see? Explaining the prevalence of civil war. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(3), 307–334.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engerman, S., & Sokoloff, K. (1997). Factor endowments, institutions, and differential paths of growth among new world economics, a view from economic historians of the United States. In S. Haber (Ed.), How Latin America fell behind, essays on the economic histories of Brazil and Mexico 1800–1914 (pp. 260–297). Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. (Chapter 10).

    Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J., & Laitin, D. (1999). Weak states, rough terrain, and large-scale ethnic violence since 1943, paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, September 2–3, Atlanta, GA.

  • Fearon, J., & Laitin, D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97(1), 75–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J. (2010). The Natural Resource Curse: A Survey. Working Paper Mo. 15836. MA: National Bureau of Economic research.

  • Gelb, A. (1988). Oil windfalls: Blessing or curse?. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg, E., Wibbels, E., & Myukiyehe, E. (2008). Lessons from strange cases: Democracy, development, and the resource curse in the U.S. States. Comparative Political Studies, 41, 477–514.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haber, S., & Menaldo, V. (2011). Does oil fuel authoritarianism? A reevaluation of the resource curse. American Political Science Review, 105(1), 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harewell, E., Farah, D., & Blundell, A. (2011). Forests, fragility, and conflict: Overview and case studies. Washington D.C.: Program on Forest.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hegre, H. (2002). Some social requisites of a democratic civil peace: Democracy, development, and armed conflict, paper presented to the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston, MA, 29 August–1 September. http://econ.worldbank.org/files/18170_DDCWAPSA2002.PDF.

  • Herb, M. (2005). No representation without taxation? Rents, development, and democracy. Comparative Politics, 37(3), 297–316.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. (1958). The Strategy of economic development. New haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. (1977). A generalized linkage approach to development, with special reference to staples. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 25, 67–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodler, R. (2006). The curse of natural resources in fractionalized countries. European Economic Review, 50(6), 1367–1386.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hooglund, E. (1982). Land and revolution in Iran 1960–1980. Austin: University of Texas Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphreys, M. (2005). Natural resources, conflict and conflict resolution. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49, 508–537.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphreys, M., Sachs, J., & Stiglitz, J. (2007). Introduction: What is the problem with natural resource wealth? In M. Humphreys, J. Sachs, & J. Stiglitz (Eds.), Escaping the resource curse. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Innis, H. (1930/1956). The fur trade in Canada: An introduction to Canadian economic history (2nd ed.). Toronto.

  • Innis, H. (1940/1954). The cod fisheries: The history of an international economy (2nd ed.). Toronto.

  • Isham, J., Woolcock, M., Prichett, L., & Busby, G. (2005). The varieties of resource experience: How natural resource export structures affect the political economy of economic growth. World Bank Economic Review, 19(2), 141–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N., & Wantchekon, L. (2004). Resource wealth and political regimes in Africa. Comparative Political Studies, 37, 816–841.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karl, T. (1997). The paradox of plenty: Oil booms and petro-states. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katouzian, M. (1978). Oil versus agriculture: A case of dual resource depletion in Iran. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 5(3), 347–369.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Zoido-Lobaton, P. (2002). Governance matters II-updated indicators 2000/01. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper no. 2772. Washington, DC.

  • Keen, D. (1994). The benefits of famine: A political economy of famine and relief in Southwestern Sudan, 1983–1989. Princeton N.J.: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen, D. (1998). The economic functions of violence in civil wars. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press for the Institute for Strategic Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen, D. (2005). Conflict and collusion in Sierra Leone. Oxford: James Currey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen, D. (2012). Greed and grievance in civil war. International Affairs, 88(4), 757–777.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C. (1958). Economic development. N.Y., Toronto, London: The McGraw book.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, F., (1958/1979). Economic consequences of organized violence. In Profit from Power (pp. 50–65). New York: State University of New York.

  • Lane, P., & Tornell, A. (1996). Power, growth, and the voracity effect. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 213–241.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, P., & Tornell, A. (1999). The voracity effect. American Economic Review, 89, 22–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Le Billon, P. (2001). The political ecology of war: Natural resources and armed conflicts. Political Geography, 20(5), 561–584.

    Google Scholar 

  • Le Billon, P. (2012). Wars of plunder, conflicts, profits and the politics of resources. London: Hurst & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. (2007). Trading with bandit. Journal of Law and Economics, 50(2), 303–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leite, C., & Weidmann, J. (2002). Does mother nature corrupt?-Natural resources, corruption, and economic growth. In G. Abed & S. Gupta (Eds.), Governance, corruption, and economic performance (pp. 156–169). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackintosh, W. (1923). Economic factors in Canadian history (pp. 12–25). IV: Canadian Historical Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackintosh, W. (1936). Some aspects of a pioneer economy. The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, II, 457–463.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahdavy, H. (1970). The patterns and problems of economic development in rentier states: The case of Iran. In M. Cook (Ed.), Studies in economic history of the Middle East (pp. 428–467). London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mann, M. (2005). The dark side of democracy: Explaining ethnic cleansing. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masi, T., Savoia, A., & Sen, K. (2017). Is there a fiscal resource curse? Resource rents, fiscal capacity and political institutions. Manuscript.

  • Matsuyama, K. (1992). Agricultural productivity, comparative advantage, and economic growth. Journal of Economic Theory, 110(3), 681–712.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayshar, J., Moav O., Neeman Z., & Pascali L. (2015). Cereals, appropriability and hierarchy. Centre for Economic Policy Research, No. 10742, Development Economics, Economic History, Macroeconomic and Growth and Public Economics, August.

  • McGuirk, E. (2013). The illusory leader: Natural resources, taxation and accountability. Public Choice, 154, 285–313.

    Google Scholar 

  • McNeill, W. (2007). Frederick the great and the propagation of potatoes. In B. Hollinshead & T. Rabb (Eds.), I wish I’d been there: Twenty historians revisit key moments in history (pp. 176–189). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehlum, H., Moene, K., & Torvik, R. (2006). Institutions and the resource curse. Economic Journal, 116, 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menaldo, V. (2016). The institutions curse, natural resources, politics, and development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, T. (2011). Carbon democracy: Political power in the age of oil. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrison, K. (2007). Natural resources, aid, and democratization: A best-case scenario. Public Choice, 131(3/4), 365–386.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neary, P., & van Wijnbergen, S. (Eds.). (1986). Natural resources and macroeconomy. Cambridge, Mass, Oxford: MIT Press, Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newberry, D. (1986). Round-table discussion. In P. Neary, & S. Wijnbergen (Eds.). Natural resources and macroeconomy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press; Oxford: Blackwell.

  • Nisbett, R., & Cohen, D. (1996). Culture of honor, the psychology of violence in the South. Boulder, Colo.: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1955). Location theory and regional economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 63(3), 243–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1956). International capital flows and the development of the American West. The Journal of Economic History, 16(4), 493–505.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1958). A note on professor Rostow’s “Take-off” into self-sustained economic growth”. Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 26, 68–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1959). Agriculture in regional economic growth. Journal of Farm Economics, 41(5). In Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the American Farm Economic Association, pp. 943–951.

  • North, D. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York, London: W.W. Norton and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D., Wallis, J., Webb, S., & Weingast, B. (Eds.). (2013). In the shadow of violence, politics, economics, and the problems of development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D., Wallis, J., & Weingast, B. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nugent, J., & Robinson, J. (2010). Are factor endowments fate? Revista de Historia Economica/Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History, 28, 45–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunn, N., & Qian, N. (2011). The potato’s contribution to population and urbanization: Evidence from a historical experiment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126, 593–650.

    Google Scholar 

  • Papaioannou, E., & Gregorios, S. (2008). Economic and social factors driving the third wave of democratization. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36, 365–387.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perloff, H., & Lowdon W. (1961). Natural resource endowment and regional economic growth. In J. Spengler (Ed.). Natural resources and economic growth (pp. 191–212). Washington: Resources for the Future, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pietri, A., Tazdait, T., & Vahabi, M. (2017). Economics of empire-building: Price and predatory competitions. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 173(2), 253–278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Price, S. (2003). War and tropical forests. Binghamton, New York: Food Products Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsay, K. (2011). Revisiting the resource curse: Natural disasters, the price of oil, and democracy. International Organization, 65(3), 507–529.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reno, W. (1997). Humanitarian emergencies and warlord economies in Liberia and Sierra Leone. Helsinki: UNU World Institute for Development Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J., & Torvik, R. (2005). White elephants. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 197–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J., Torvik, R., & Verdier, T. (2006). Political foundations of the resource curse. Journal of Development Economics, 79, 447–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (1999). The political economy of the resource curse. World Politics, 51(2), 297–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2001). Does oil hinder democracy? World Politics, 53, 325–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2003). Oil, drugs, and diamonds: The varying roles of natural resources in civil war. In K. Ballentine & J. Sherman (Eds.), The political economy of armed conflict, beyond greed and grievance (pp. 47–72). Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Reinner Publishers Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2004). What do we know about natural resources and civil war? Journal of Peace Research, 41(3), 337–356.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2009). Oil and democracy revisited. Mimeo: University of California-Los Angeles.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2012). The oil curse: How petroleum wealth shapes the development of nations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2014). What have we learned about the resource curse?

  • Sachs, J., & Warner, A. (1995). Natural resource abundance and economic growth, Development Discussion Paper 517a. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Institute for International Development.

  • Sachs, J., & Warner, A. (2001). The curse of natural resources. European Economic Review, 45(4), 827–838.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salai-I-Martin, X., & Subramanian, A. (2003). Addressing the natural resource curse: An illustration from Nigeria. Working paper 9804, NBER. Cambridge.

  • Schedvin, C. (1990). Staples and regions of Pax Britannica. The Economic History Review, 43(4), 533–559.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, J. (2009). The art of not being governed, an Anarchist history of Upland Southeast Asia. New Haven, London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, J. (2017). Against the grain, a deep history of the earliest states. New Haven, London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shafer, D. (1994). Winners and losers, how sectors shape the developmental prospects of states. Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, B. (2007). Hard times in the land of plenty: Oil politics in Iran and Indonesia. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, R. (2006). Does lootable wealth breed disorder? A political economy of extraction framework. Comparative Political Studies, 39(8), 943–968.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, R., & Bhavnani, R. (2005). Diamonds, blood, and taxes: A revenue-centred framework for explaining political order. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 49(4), 563–597.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sokoloff, K., & Engerman, S. (2000). History lessons: Institutions, factors endowments, and paths of development in the New World. Journal of Economic perspectives, 14(3), 217–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sorens, J. (2011). Mineral production, territory, and ethnic rebellion: The role of rebel constituencies. Journal of Peace Research, 48(5), 571–585.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, F., Brown, G., & Langer, A. (2008). Major findings and conclusions on the relationship between horizontal inequalities and conflict. In F. Stewart (Ed.), Horizontal inequalities and conflict: Understanding group violence in multiethnic societies. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, F., & FitzGerald, V. (Eds.). (2001). War and underdevelopment: the economic and social consequences of conflict, (Vol. 1). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tornell, A., & Lane, P. R. (1999). The voracity effect. The American Economic Review, 89(1), 22–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Torvik, R. (2001). Learning by doing and the Dutch disease. European Economic Review, 45, 285–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Torvik, R. (2002). Natural resources, rent seeking and welfare. Journal of Development Economics, 67, 455–470.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2011). Appropriation, violent enforcement and transaction costs: A critical survey. Public Choice, 147(1), 227–253.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2016a). The political economy of predation: Manhunting and the economics of escape. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2016b). A positive theory of the predatory state. Public Choice, 168(3–4), 153–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2018). Coercive state, resisting society, political and economic development in contemporary Iran. Dr Sadighi lecture series. International Institute of Social History and Leiden University, Amsterdam.

  • Van der Ploeg, F. (2011). Natural resources: Curse or blessing? Journal of Economic Literature, 49(2), 366–420.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volckart, O. (2000a). The open constitution and its enemies: Competition, rent Seeking, and the rise of the modern state. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 42, 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volckart, O. (2000b). State building by bargaining for monopoly rents. Kyklos, 53(3), 265–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wantchekon, L. (2002). Why do resource dependent countries have authoritarian governments? Journal of African Finance and Economic Development, 2, 57–77.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watkins, M. (1963). A staple theory of economic growth. The Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 29(2), 141–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wick, K., & Bulte, E. (2006). Contesting resources-rent seeking, conflict and the natural resource curse. Public Choice, 128, 457–476.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wick, K., & Bulte, E. (2009). The curse of natural resources. Annual Review of Resource Economics, 1, 139–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiens, D. (2014). Natural resources and institutional development. Theoretical Politics, 26(2), 197–221.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woolcook, M., Pritchett, L., & Isham, J. (2001). The social foundations of poor economic growth in resource rich economies. In R. Auty (Ed.), Resource abundance and economic development. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, G. (2001). Resource-based growth then and now, prepared for the World Bank Project Patterns of Integration in the Global Economy. Stanford University.

Download references

Acknowledgements

I wholeheartedly thank my four anonymous referees, the associate editor Peter Kurrild-Klitgaard, and the editor-in-chief William Shughart of the Public Choice journal for their excellent and constructive comments. I would also like to present my gratitude to Bertrand Crettez, Alain Desdoigts, Antonio Savoia, Kunal Sen, Tarik Tazdait and Mandana Vahabi for their inspiring and insightful remarks on earlier versions of this paper. Obviously, all the remaining errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mehrdad Vahabi.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Vahabi, M. The resource curse literature as seen through the appropriability lens: a critical survey. Public Choice 175, 393–428 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0533-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0533-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation