Skip to main content
Log in

The political economy of the European customs classification

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Customs classification is an important element in a country's trade policy. How a good is classified can affect the rate of duty that applies, the coverage of non-tariff barriers, and the formulation and application of rules of origin. Reclassifications can occur because of the introduction of a new product, but also because of protectionist motives. This paper is the first attempt at explaining these reclassifications. Focusing on the European Union, I examine whether the number of tariff lines in an industry result from the introduction of new products or from protectionist lobbying. The analysis focuses on 90 manufacturing industries over 12 years. Results suggest that protectionist lobbying does play a role in explaining changes in the EU's customs classification.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • European Communities. (1999). Serving the European Union: A Citizen's Guide to the Institutions of the European Union. Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities.

  • Findlay, R., & Wellisz, S. (1982). Endogenous tariffs, the political economy of trade restrictions, and welfare. In: J. Bhagwati (Ed.), Import Competition and Response. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fliess, B. A., & Sauvé, P. (1998). Of Chips, Floppy Disks and Great Timing: Assessing the WTO Information Technology Agreement. Paris: Institut Franccais des Relations Internationales.

  • Gawande, K., & Krishna, P. (2003). The political economy of trade policy: Empirical approaches. In E. Kwan Choi, & J. Harrigan (Eds), Handbook of International Trade. Oxford: Basil-Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84, 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, Bronwyn H., Jaffe, A. B. & Trajtenberg, M. (2001). The NBER Patent Citations Data File: Lessons, Insights and Methodological Tools. NBER Working Paper, 8498.

  • Hanson, B. T. (1998). What happened to fortress Europe? External trade policy liberalization in the european union. International Organization, 52(1), 55–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, Arye L. (1989). The Political Economy of Protection. Chur: Harwood Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, Arye L. (1991). Protection, politics, and market structure. In: E. Helpman & A. Razin (Eds.), International Trade and Trade Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A. L., Van Long, N., & Soubeyran. A. (2001). Protection, lobbying and market structure. Journal of International Economics, 54, 383–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (1981). Intraindustry specialization and the gains from trade. Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), 959–973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marvel, H. P., & Ray, E. J. (1983). The Kennedy Round: Evidence on the Regulation of International trade in the United States. American Economic Review, 73 (1), 190–197.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, W. (1984). Endogenous Tariff Formation. American Economic Review, 74 (5), 970–085.

    Google Scholar 

  • Messerlin, P. A. (2001). Measuring the Costs of Protection in Europe: European Commercial Policy in the 2000s. Washington: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meunier, S. (2000). What single voice? European institutions and EU-U.S. trade negotiations. International Organization, 54(1), 103–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olarreaga, M., Soloaga, I. & Winters, L. A. (1999). What's behind Mercosur's common external tariff? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, 2231.

  • OECD. (1994). The Measurement of Scientific and Technological Activities: Using Patent Data as Science and Technology Indicators. Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pecorino, P. (1998). Is there a free-rider problem in lobbying? Endogenous tariffs, trigger strategies, and the number of firms. American Economic Review, 88(3), 652–660.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J., & Sloof, R. (1996). Interest groups: A survey of empirical models that try to assess their influence. European Journal of Political Economy, 12, 403–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1995). Political Economy of Trade Policy. In: G. Grossman, & K. Rogoff (Eds.), Handbook of International Economics, vol. 3. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schueren, P. V. (1997). Tariff classification: An Instrumint for EC trade policy. European Foreign Affairs Review, 2(2), 255–275.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tavares, S. (2005). Deeper tntegration and voting on the common european external rariff. Unpublished manuscript.

  • Trefler, D. (1993). Trade liberalization and the theory of endogenous protection: An econometric study of U.S. import policy. Journal of Political Economy, 101(1), 138–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vermulst, E. (1994). EC customs classification rules: Should ice-cream melt? Michigan Journal of International Law, 15(4), 1241–1325.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Samia Costa Tavares.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Tavares, S.C. The political economy of the European customs classification. Public Choice 129, 107–130 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-005-9012-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-005-9012-x

Keywords

Navigation