Skip to main content
Log in

Legislative district configurations and fiscal policy in American States

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In accordance with the median voter theorem the median legislator is decisive in representative democracy. If the preferences of the median legislator differ from the preferences of the median voter in the polity, fiscal policy choices will predictably diverge from those favored by the median voter. This paper seeks to identify the median district (and therein the preferences driving the median legislator) in American State legislatures. Using economic characteristics of constituents, we find substantial differences between the median district and the statewide median. As the income of the median district rises above the median income of the polity, government expenditures increase. In addition, the degree to which income is skewed across legislative districts affects spending for redistribution programs. Finally, we find that direct democracy procedures, which allow the statewide median voter to check legislative decisions, limit the impact of differences between the district and polity medians.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alesina, A., & Roderick, D. (1994). Distributive politics and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 465–490.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrom, T. C., & Goodman, R. P. (1973). Private demands for public goods. American Economics Review, 63, 280–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, William D., Ringquist, Evan J., & Fordig, Richard S. (1998). Measuring citizen and government ideology in the American States, 1960–93. American Journal of Political Science, 42(1), 327–348.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowen, H. R. (1943). The interpretation of voting in the allocation of economic resources. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 58, 27–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Bicameral legislatures and fiscal policy. Southern Economic Journal, 68, 646–659.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Legislative organization and government spending: Cross-country evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 309–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury, J. C., & Johnson, J. M. (2002). Do Supermajority rules limit or enhance tyranny of majority spending? Evidence from the US States, 1960–1997. Manuscript.

  • Chicoine, D. L., Walzer, N., & Deller, S. C. (1989). Representative vs. direct democracy and government spending in a median voter model. Public Finance, 44, 225–236.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M. (1999). Districts, diversity, and fiscal biases: Evidence from the American States. Journal of Law and Economics, 52, 675–698.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M. (2003). Volatile states: Institutions, policy, and the performance of American state economies, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

  • Crain, W. M., & James C. M. III (1990). Budget process and spending growth. William and Mary Law Review, 31(4), 1021–1046.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. L., Grofman, B., & Miller, N. (1988). Centripetal forces in spatial voting: On the size of the yolk. Public Choice, 59, 37–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Ronald C. (1996). State and local public finance. Boston: Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (1993). Seats and spending: Legislative structure and median voter outcomes. University of Southern California. Unpublished manuscript.

  • Gilligan, T. W., & Matsusaka, J. G. (1997). Structural constraints on partisan bias under the efficient gerrymander. Public Choice, 100, 65–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1980). An empirical test of the median voter model. Economic Inquiry, 18, 260–274.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1978). Public choice and public spending, National Tax Journal, 31, 373–383.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G., & Caudill, S. B. (1985). Tax shares and government spending in the median voter model. Public Choice, 46, 197–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in competition. Economic Journal. 39, 41–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Husted, T. A., & Kenny, L. W. (1997). The effect of the expansion of the voting franchise on the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 105, 54–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R. P. (1978). Testing political economy's ‘As if’ proposition: Is the median voter really decisive? Public Choice, 33, 45–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inman, R. P., & Henning B. (1996). Balanced-budget rules and public deficits: Evidence from the US States. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 45, 13–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenny, L. W. (1978). The collective allocation of commodities in a democratic society: A generalization. Public Choice, 33, 117–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, B. G. (2001). Supermajority voting requirements for tax increases: Evidence from the States. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 41–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krussell, P., & Rios-Rull, J-V (1999). “On the size of US government: Political economy in the neoclassical growth model. American Economic Review, 89, 1156–1181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lilley, DeFranco, and Diefenderfer (1995). Almanac of State Legislatures, Diskette. Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly, Inc.

  • Lott, J. R., & Kenny, L. W. (1999). Did woman's suffrage change the size and scope of government? Journal of Political Economy, 107, 163–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G. (1992). Economics of direct legislation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107, 541–571.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matsusaka, J. G. (1995). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative: Evidence from the last 30 years. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 587–623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. D. (1986). Covering, dominance, and institution-free properties of social choice. American Journal of Political Science, 30, 283–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A., & Richard, S. (1983). Tests of a rational theory of the size of government. Public Choice, 41, 403–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A., & Richard, S. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–927.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N. (1980). A new ‘solution set’ for tournaments and majority voting. American Journal of Political Science, 24, 68–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (2003). Public Choice III. Cambridge University Press.

  • Munley, V. G. (1984). Has the median voter found a ballot box that he can control? Economic Inquiry, 22, 323–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine & Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1975). Bureaucrats and politicians. Journal of Law and Economics, 18, 617–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1992). Voters as fiscal conservatives. Quarterly Journal of Economics, CVII (2). 327–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Perotti, R. (1993). Political equilibrium, income distribution, and growth. Review of Economic Studies, 60, 755–776.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1994). Is inequality harmful for growth? American Economic Review, 84, 600–621.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. W. (1978). Institutional approaches to public expenditure: Empirical evidence from swiss municipalities. Journal of Public Economics, 9, 255–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. W., & Frey, B. S. (1978). Bureaucratic behavior in democracy: A case study. Public Finance/Finances Publiques, 33, 98–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. W., & Schneider, F. (1978). Fiscal illusion, political institutions, and local public spending. Kyklos, 31, 381–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. M. (1997). Do Budget Rules Work? in Fiscal Policy: Lessons from Economic Research, Alan J. Auerbach (Ed.), Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press: 53–86. (Reprinted as NBER No. 2152.).

  • Poterba, J. M. (1996). “Budget institutions and fiscal policy in the US states.” American Economic Review, 86, 395–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ram, Rati (1987). “Wagner's Hypothesis in time-series and cross-section perspectives.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 69, 194–204.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1979a). “The elusive median voter.” Journal of Public Economics, 12, 143–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1979b). “Bureaucrats versus voters: On the political economy of resource allocation by direct democracy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 93, 563–587.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1982). “Median voters or budget maximizers: Evidence from school expenditure referenda.” Economic Inquiry, 20, 556–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santerre, Rexford E. (1986). “Representative versus direct democracy: A Tieboat test of relative performance.” Public Choice, 48, 55–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John Charles Bradbury.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bradbury, J.C., Crain, W.M. Legislative district configurations and fiscal policy in American States. Public Choice 125, 385–407 (2005). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-005-3058-7

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-005-3058-7

Keywords

Navigation