Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Social Capital and Endogenous Preferences

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we analyze whether social capital can emerge endogenously from a process of preference evolution. We define social capital as preferences that promote voluntary cooperation in a one-shot Prisoner’s Dilemma game. We investigate how the endogenous preferences depend on the amount of information individuals have about each other’s preferences. When there is sufficiently much information, maximal social capital emerges. In general, the level of social capital varies positively with the amount of information. Our results may add to an understanding of the factors that determine a society’s ability to generate cooperative outcomes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Ahn, T. K., Ostrom, E., Schmidt, D., Shupp, R. & Warker, J. (2001). Cooperatio in PD games, fear, greed and history of play. Public Choice, 106, 137–155.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binmore, K., & Samuelson, L. (1999). Evolutionary drift and equilibrium selection. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 363–393.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. (1998). Endogenous preferences: The cultural consequences of markets and other economic institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, XXXVI, 75–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Gintis, H (2002). Social capital and community governance. Economic Journal, 112, F419–F346.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brosig, J. (2002). Identifying cooperative behavior: Some experimental results in a prisoner’s dilemma game. Journal of Economic behavior and Organization, 47, 275– 290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1975). The samaritan’s dilemma. In E. S. Phelps (ed.), Altruism, Morality, and Economic Theory (pp. 71–85). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, K., & Sefton, M. (2001). The sequential prisoners dilemma: Evidence on reciprocation. Economic Journal, 111, 51–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J.S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, 95–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engelmann, D. (2001). Asymmetric type recognition with applications to dilemma games. Metroeconomica, 52(4), 357–375.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2002). Why social preferences matter—The impact of nonselfish motives on competition, cooperation, and incentives. Economic Journal, 112, C1–C33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (2002). Theories of fairness and reciprocity – evidence and economic applications, in Dewatripont, M. Hansen, L. & Turnovsky, S. (eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics – 8th World Congress, Econometric Society Monographs, Cambridge University Press.

  • Fershtman, C., & Weiss, Y. (1998). Why do we care what others think about us? In A. Ben-Ner & L. Putterman (eds.), Economics, Values and Organization (pp.133–151). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. (1988). Passions within reasons. W.W. Norton.

  • Frank, R. H., Gilovich, T. & Regan, D. (1993). The evolution of one-shot cooperation. Ethology and Sociobiology, 14, 247–256.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gambetta, D. (1988). Can we trust trust? In D. Gambetta (ed.), Trust: Making and breaking cooperative relations (pp. 213–237). Basil Blackwell.

  • Glaeser, L., Laibson, D., & Sacerdote, B. (2002). An economic approach to social capital. Economic Journal, 112, F437–F458.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guttman, J. M. (2000). On the evolutionary stability of preferences for reciprocity. European Journal of Political Economy, 16, 31–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guttman, J. M. (2003). Repeated interaction and the evolution of preferences for reciprocity. Economic Journal, 111(489), 631–656.

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W. (1995). An evolutionary approach to explaining cooperative behavior by reciprocal incentives. International Journal of Game Theory, 24, 323–344.

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., & Kliemt, H. (1994). Competition or cooperation—On the evolutionary economics of trust, exploitation and moral attitudes. Metroeconomica, 45, 155–187.

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., Kliemt, H., & Peleg, B. (2000). Co-evolution of preferences and information in simple games of trust. German Economic Review, 1(1), 83–110.

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W. & Yaari, M. (1992). An evolutionary approach to explain reciprocal behavior in a simple strategic game. ln Ulrich Witt, (ed.), Explaining process and change—approaches to evolutionary economics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J., & Selten, R. (1988). A general theory of equilibrium selection in games. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofbauer, J. (1981). On the occurrence of limit cycles in the Volterra-Lotka equation. Nonlinear Analysis, Theory, Methods & Applications, 5(9), 1003–1007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keser, C., & van Winden, F. (2000). Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 102(1), 23–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • McChesney, F. S. (2001). Rent seeking and rent extraction, In F. William, W. F. Shughart, II & L. Razzolini (eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice, (pp. 379–395). Cheltenham, UK, Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ockenfels, A., & Selten, R. (2000). An experiment on the hypothesis of involuntary truth-signalling in bargaining. Games and Economic Behavior, 33(1), 90–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ok, E., & Vega-Redondo, F. (2001). On the evolution of individualistic preferences: An incomplete information scenario. Journal of Economic Theory, 97, 231–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, M., & Rubinstein, A. (1994). A course in game theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paldam, M. (2000). Social capital: One or many? Definition and measurement. Journal of Economic Surveys, 14(5), 629–653.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paldam, M., & Svendsen, G. T. (2000). An essay on social capital: Looking for the fire behind the smoke. European Journal of Political Economy, 16, 339–366.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A. (1986). Finite automata play the repeated prisoner’s dilemma. Journal of Economic Theory, 39, 83–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, L. (1997). Evolutionary games and equilibrium selection. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schram, A. (2000). Sorting out the Seeking: The economics of individual motivations. Public Choice, 103(3/4), 231–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, F., & Pommerehne, W.W. (1981). Free riding and collective action: An experiment in public microeconomics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 96, 689–704.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, M., Teske, P., Marschall, M., Mintrom, M., & Roch, C. (1997). Institutional arrangements and the creation of social capital: The effects of public school choice. American Political Science Review, 91(1), 82–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sethi, R., & Somanathan, E. (1996). The evolution of social norms in common property resource use. American Economic Review, 86(4), 766–787.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sethi, R., & Somanathan, E. (2003). Understanding reciprocity. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 50, 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svendsen, G. T. (2003). Political economy of the European Union: Institutions, policy and economic growth. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, P. D., & Jonker, L. B. (1978). Evolutionarily stable srategies and game dynamics. Mathematical Biosciences, 40, 145–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Winden, F. (2002). Experimental investigation of collective action. In S. L. Winer, and H. Shibata (eds.), Political economy and public finance: The role of political economy in the theory and practice of public economics (pp. 178–196). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weibull, J. W. (1995). Evolutionary Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P. J., & Knack, S. (2001). Trust and growth. The Economic Journal, 111, 295–321.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anders U. Poulsen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Poulsen, A.U., Svendsen, G.T. Social Capital and Endogenous Preferences. Public Choice 123, 171–196 (2005). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-005-0266-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-005-0266-0

Keywords

Navigation