Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Parental Leave Benefit Reform in Germany: Costs and Labour Market Outcomes of Moving towards the Nordic Model

  • Published:
Population Research and Policy Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Germany is known to have one of the lowest fertility rates among Western European countries and also relatively low employment rates of mothers with young children. Although these trends have been observed during the last decades, the German public has only recently begun discussing these issues. In order to reverse these trends, the German government recently passed a reform of the parental leave benefit system in line with the model practiced in Nordic countries. The core piece of the reform is the replacement of the existing means-tested parental leave benefit by a wage-dependent benefit for the period of one year. In this paper we simulate fiscal costs and expected labour market outcomes of this reform. Based on a micro-simulation model for Germany we calculate first-round effects, which assume no behavioural changes and second-round effects, where we take labour supply changes into account. Our results show that on average all income groups, couples and single households, benefit from the reform. The calculation of overall costs of the reform shows that the additional costs are moderate. As far as the labour market behaviour of parents is concerned, we find no significant changes of labour market outcomes in the first year after birth. However, in the second year, mothers increase their working hours and labour market participation significantly. Our results suggest that the reform will achieve one of its aims, namely the increase in the labour market participation of mothers with young children.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See the homepage of the Federal Ministry for Family Affairs, http://www.bmfsfj.de/Politikbereiche/Familie/familie-und-arbeitswelt.html.

  2. Note that in some Nordic countries, in particular Sweden and Norway, the number of part-time working mothers is relatively high, however still not as high as among German mothers. For example, in Germany, 60% of all working mothers with two or more children work part-time compared to only 41% in Norway, 22% in Sweden, 16% in Denmark and 14% in Finland (OECD 2002).

  3. Currently, parental leave and benefits are regulated in the child-rearing benefit law (“Bundeserziehungsgeldgesetz”). In addition, there is a special law, the mother protection law (“Mutterschutzgesetz”) regulating job-protection and wage-replacement during pregnancy. It also designates the mother protection period, which covers six weeks before and eight weeks after birth.

  4. For the current reform proposal, see BMFSFJ (2006b).

  5. However, parents do have the option to spread the total amount of the parent benefit over 24 instead of 12 months.

  6. For a recently published overview of family policies and fertility in Europe covering gender issues as well, see Neyer (2006).

  7. Other micro-data based studies focus on the effect of overall differences in family policies of various countries on mothers’ returns to work. See Gustafsson et al. (1996) as one example.

  8. For more details on the STSM, see Steiner et al. (2005).

  9. See Schupp and Wagner (2002) and http://www.diw.de/soep for more information on the GSOEP.

  10. This relates in particular to the so-called father quota.

  11. A detailed description and motivation of the model, which follows the approach of van Soest (1995), is given in Steiner and Wrohlich (2004).

References

  • Albrecht, J. W., Edin, P. A., Sundström, M., & Vroman, S. B. (1999). Career interruptions and subsequent earnings: A re-examination using Swedish data. Journal of Human Resources, 34, 294–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum, C. L. (2003). The effect of state maternity leave legislation and the 1993 family and medical leave act on employment and wages. Labour Economics, 10, 573–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, L. M., & Waldfogel, J. (2004). Maternity leave and the employment of new mothers in the United States. Journal of Population Economics, 17, 331–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BMFSFJ – Bundesministerium für Familie, Senioren, Frauen und Jugend (2005). (Hrsg.) Perspektive für eine nachhaltige Familienpolitik, Berlin.

  • BMFSFJ – Bundesministerium für Familie, Senioren, Frauen und Jugend (2006a). (Hrsg.) Familie zwischen Flexibilität und Verlässlichkeit, Perspektiven für eine lebenslaufbezogene Familienpolitik, Siebter Familienbericht, Bundestagsdrucksache 16/1360, Berlin.

  • BMFSFJ – Bundesministerium für Familie, Senioren, Frauen und Jugend (2006b). (Hrsg.) Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Einführung des Elterngelds, Gesetzentwurf der Bundesregierung, Kabinettsbeschluss vom 14. Juni 2006, Berlin.

  • BMFSFJ – Bundesministerium für Familie, Senioren, Frauen und Jugend (2006c) Kindertagesbetreuung für Kinder unter drei Jahren, Bericht der Bundesregierung über den Stand des Ausbaus für ein bedarfsgerechtes Angebot an Kindertagesbetreuung für Kinder unter drei Jahren, Berlin.

  • Bruning, G., & Plantenga, J. (1999). Parental leave and equal opportunities: Experiences in eight European countries. Journal of European Social Policy, 9(3), 195–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Büchel, F., & Spiess, C. K. (2002). Form der Kinderbetreuung und Arbeitsmarktverhalten von Müttern in West- und Ostdeutschland. Stuttgart: Kohlhammer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Büttner, T., & Lutz, W. (1990). Estimating fertility responses to policy measures in the German Democratic Republic. Population and Development Review, 16, 539–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Datta Gupta, N., Smith, N., & Verner, M. (2006). Child care and parental leave in the Nordic Countries: A model to aspire to? IZA Discussion Paper 2014.

  • Duvander, A.-Z., & Andersson, G. (2006). Gender equality and fertility in Sweden: A study on the impact of the father’s uptake of parental leave on continued childbearing. Marriage & Family Review, 39, 121–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duvander, A.-Z., Ferrarini, T., & Thalberg, S. (2005). Swedish parental leave and gender equality. Arbetsrapport/Institute för Framtidsstudies (11), Stockholm.

  • Ekberg, J., Eriksson, R., & Friebel, G. (2005). Parental leave – a policy evaluation of the Swedish “Daddy-Month” Reform. IZA Discussion Paper 1617, May 2005, Bonn.

  • Gustafsson, S., Wetzels, C., Vlsblom, J. D., & Dex, S. (1996). Women’s labor force transition in connection with childbirth: A panel data comparison between Germany, Sweden and Great Britain. Journal of Population Economics, 9, 223–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gutierrez-Domenech, M. (2005). Employment after motherhood: A European comparison. Labour Economics, 12, 99–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hashimoto, M., Percy, R., Schoellner, T., & Weinberg. B. A. (2004). The long and short of it: Maternity leave coverage and women’s labor market outcomes. IZA Discussion Paper 1207.

  • Hoem, J. M., Prskawetz, A., & Neyer, G. (2001). Autonomy or conservative adjustment? The effect of public policies and educational attainment on third births in Austria. Working Paper Series of the Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research, WP 2001-016.

  • Hoem, J. M. (2005). Why does Sweden have such a high fertility? MPIDR Working Paper WP-2005-009, Rostock.

  • Klerman, J., & Leibowitz, A. (1997). Labor supply effects of state maternity leave legislation. In F. Blau & R. Ehrenberg (Eds.), Gender and family issues in the workplace. New York: Russel Sage, Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klerman, J., & Leibowitz, A. (1999). Job continuity among new mothers. Demography, 36, 145–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lalive, R., & Zweimüller, J. (2005). Does parental leave affect fertility and return-to-work? Evidence from a “True Natural Experiment”. IZA Discussion Paper 1613, Bonn.

  • McFadden, D. (1973). Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior. In P. Zarembka (Ed.), Frontiers in econometrics. Academic Press.

  • Neyer, G. (2006). Family policies and fertility in Europe: Fertility policies at the intersection of gender policies, employment policies and care policies. MPIDR Working Paper WP 2006-010.

  • OECD (2002). Employment Outlook 2002. Paris.

  • OECD (2006). Starting strong II. Early childhood education and care. Paris.

  • Oláh, L. S. (2003). Gendering fertility: Second births in Sweden and Hungary. Population Research and Policy Review, 22, 171–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ondrich, J., Spiess, C. K., & Yang, Q. (2003a). Changes in women’s wages after parental leave. Schmollers Jahrbuch (Journal of Applied Social Science Studies), 123, 125–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ondrich, J., Spiess, C. K., Wagner, G. G., & Yang, Q. (2003b). The liberalization of maternity leave policy and the return to work after childbirth in Germany. Review of Economics of the Household, 1, 77–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ondrich, J., Spiess, C. K., Wagner, G. G., & Yang, Q. (1999). Full time or part time? German parental leave policy and the return to work after childbirth in Germany. Research in Labor Economics, 18, 41–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ondrich, J., Spiess, C. K., & Yang, Q. (1996). Barefoot and in a German kitchen: Federal parental leave and benefit policy and the return to work after childbirth in Germany. Journal of Population Economics, 9, 247–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pylkkänen, E., & Smith, N. (2003) Career interruptions due to parental leave: A comparative study of Denmark and Sweden. OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, DELSA/ELSA/WD/SEM (2003) 1, Paris.

  • Rönsen, M., & Sundström, M. (1996). Maternal employment in Scandinavia: A comparison of the after-birth employment activity of Norwegian and Swedish Women. Journal of Population Economics, 9, 267–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruhm, C. (1998). The economic consequences of parental leave mandates: Lessons from Europe. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1), 285–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruhm, C., & Teague, J. L. (1997). Parental leave policies in Europe and North America. In F. Blau & R. Ehrenberg (Eds.), Gender and family issues in the workplace (pp. 133–156). New York: Russel Sage, Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schupp, J., & Wagner, G. G. (2002). Maintenance of and innovation in long-term panel studies The case of the German Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP). Allgemeines Statistisches Archiv, 86, 163–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steiner, V., Haan, P., & Wrohlich, K. (2005). Das Steuer-Transfer Simulationsmodell STSM 1999–2002. DIW Data Documentation, 9.

  • Steiner, V., & Wrohlich, K. (2004). Household taxation, income splitting and labor supply incentives—a microsimulation study for Germany. CESifo Economic Studies, 50(3), 541–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steiner, V., & Wrohlich, K. (2008). Introducing family tax splitting in Germany: How would it affect the income distribution and work incentives? FinanzArchiv–Public Finance Analysis, 64(1), 115–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Soest, A. (1995). Structural models of family labor supply: A discrete choice approach. Journal of Human Resources, 30(1), 63–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldfogel, J. (1998). Understanding the family gap in pay form women with children. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12, 137–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Waldfogel, J., Higuchi, Y., & Abe, M. (1999). Family leave policies and women`s retention after childbirth: Evidence from the United States, Britain, and Japan. Journal of Population Economics, 12, 523–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, A. M. (2004). Wann kehren junge Mütter auf den Arbeitsmarkt zurück. ZEW Discussion Paper 04-08.

  • Wrohlich, K. (2008). The excess demand for subsidized child care in Germany. Applied Economics (forthcoming).

  • Wrohlich, K. (2006). Labor supply and child care choices in a rationed child care market. IZA Discussion Papers 2053.

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Peter Haan, Michal Myck and Viktor Steiner for helpful comments on an earlier draft and Deborah A. Bowen and Nicole Scheremet for editorial assistance. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to C. Katharina Spiess.

Appendix: Formal Description of the Labour Supply Model, Data and Estimation Procedure

Appendix: Formal Description of the Labour Supply Model, Data and Estimation Procedure

The labour supply model used for the estimation of the behavioural effects resulting from the parental leave benefit reform is a structural household utility model. Household utility is assumed to be a function of net household income, the leisure of the mother and the leisure of the father. The estimation of the utility function is based on a discrete choice model. The underlying assumption is that households compare the utility U of J number of different choice categories, i.e. combinations of working hours and net household incomes, and choose the combination, which yields the highest utility.Footnote 11

We follow van Soest (1995) and specify the household utility function as a trans-log function, i.e.

$$ U_k (x_k ) = x^{\prime}_k Ax_k + \beta ^{\prime}x_k + \varepsilon _k $$
(1)

where U k is the utility of the household in choice category k and the vector x contains the linear, quadratic and cross terms of the natural logs of net income, leisure of the mother and leisure of the father. Matrix A contains the coefficients of the cross and quadratic terms, vector β contains the coefficients of the linear terms and ε is a stochastic error term.

Assuming that households maximize utility, they choose category k if the utility in this choice category is greater than in all other categories. In probability terms, this decision rule can be stated as follows:

$$ P(U_k > U_l ) = P\left( {\left( {x_k 'Ax_k + \beta 'x_k } \right) - \left( {x_l 'Ax_l + \beta 'x_l } \right) > \varepsilon _l - \varepsilon _k } \right) $$
(2)

Assuming that the error terms ε are independently and identically distributed over all choice categories and follow an extreme value distribution, the probability to choose category k as stated in equation (2) can be estimated using the conditional logit model (McFadden, 1973):

$$ P\left( {U_k > U_l } \right) = \frac{{\exp \left( {x^{\prime}_k Ax_k + \beta ^{\prime}x_k } \right)}}{{\sum\limits_{j = 1}^J {\exp \left( {x^{\prime}_j Ax_j + \beta ^{\prime}x_j } \right)} }}{\text{, }}\forall l \ne k $$
(3)

In order to include individual or household specific characteristics, we also include interaction terms between these characteristics and leisure. These characteristics are age of the mother, age of the father, age of the youngest child, number of children and a dummy variable indicating whether the household is living in east Germany (see Table A.3).

For the estimation of the labour supply model, we include two-parent families (either married or cohabiting couples) who have at least one child less than 24 months. We exclude single parents because it seems plausible that the parameters of their utility function would differ from those of two-parent families. Unfortunately, we do not have enough observations to estimate a separate regression for single parents, who make up about 10% of our sample. Thus, our results refer to two-parent families only. We further exclude households in which one of the parents is still in education, self-employed or severely disabled. As we pool observations from three periods (2001–2003), some households enter the sample in two periods. We assume that the error terms are independently and identically distributed following an extreme value distribution, as specified above.

Table A.1 shows the distribution of households in our sample for the estimation of the labour supply equation across choice categories. The definition of the hours categories is motivated by both economic considerations and the actual distribution of hours in the sample. Although a relatively fine aggregation of hours into categories seems desirable in order to realistically approximate the household’s budget constraint, the actual distribution of hours in the sample severely restricts the number of possible categories. Furthermore, for couples, the feasible number of categories is not only restricted by the distribution of hours within one gender, but by the bivariate distribution of the two spouses’ working hours. For example, we observe few men in our sample who are either not working or are working part-time. Thus, for these two working categories of men, we define only two working hours categories for women, non-working and working.

Table A.1 Sample size and distribution of households across choice categories

Table A.2 presents further descriptive characteristics such as net household income, age of the parents and number of children in each hours category.

Table A.2 Descriptive statistics of the sample used for the labour supply estimation

The results of the labour supply estimations are presented in Table A.3.

Table A.3 Coefficients of the conditional logit model

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Spiess, C.K., Wrohlich, K. The Parental Leave Benefit Reform in Germany: Costs and Labour Market Outcomes of Moving towards the Nordic Model. Popul Res Policy Rev 27, 575–591 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11113-008-9086-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11113-008-9086-5

Keywords

Navigation