Introduction

A large number of empirical studies within environmental justice research show that wealthier people suffer less from environmental burdens and yet leave behind a greater ecological footprint (Wackernagel et al. 1999; York et al. 2003) than poorer people (Diekmann and Jann 2000; Lenzen and Murray 2001; Evans and Kantrowitz 2002; Muniz and Galindo 2005, among others). This socially unequal distributionFootnote 1—of environmental burdens and consumption of resources—represents two sides of the same coin, resulting in a double advantage to wealthier individuals. To what extent are the affluent thus prepared to pay more for the protection of the environment? A greater willingness to pay (WTP) could be viewed as compensation for this double advantage. We do not presume that this trade-off is always subject to intention; in some circumstances, the compensation behavior may have the character of a byproduct of individual environment-related behavior. Alongside the compensatory view, with its argument for the retributive effect of varying degrees of WTP, within public debate and academic literature, some argue that environmental protection is a good that is reserved for those who are better off (the affluence hypothesis) and can afford it (e.g., Baumol and Oates 1979; Barry and Field 2009).

These two complementary hypotheses—the compensation hypothesis and the affluence hypothesisFootnote 2—both prompt the central question: is income really the most important factor determining WTP for public and for (quasi-)private environmental goods?Footnote 3 Can a social distribution of WTP, dominated by those with higher incomes, be identified at all? Or are there other factors of equal significance affecting WTP independent of income? In order to answer such questions conclusively, various competing determinants affecting WTP must be taken into consideration. Previous studies have not always done so, and our paper takes this gap as its starting point. Many economic studies in the field of WTP analysis (or more specifically in the field of economic valuation) place the emphasis, along with attitudes relating to environmental goods, solely and fundamentally on income as the main explanatory variable (e.g., Bateman et al. 2002: 195). On the other hand, in sociological and psychological studies, income is given far less attention (e.g., Ajzen and Driver 1992; Kahneman and Ritov 1994). These studies place the emphasis largely on attitudes and norms as the determinants (using, e.g., the theory of planned behavior, as in Pouta and Rekola 2001 or the norm activating model, as in Guagnano 2001). Although some studies support individual theories and confirm the effect of particular characteristics, it is uncertain if these theories and effects hold up in a direct comparison. In general, often the acknowledgement of competing explanatory factors shows that the effects of individual characteristics are overestimated or lose their significance entirely.

To assess the validity of the compensation hypothesis while controlling for alternative explanations, we examine the competing theoretical determinants of individuals’ WTP for environmental goods discussed in various economic, psychological, and sociological theories. Besides income, we also take into account altruism, generalized trust, conditional cooperation (strategies), environmental concern, and post-materialistic values. In addition, and to our knowledge for the first time, we examine the influence of time preferences, or subjective discount rates, on survey-based WTP for environmental goods. By systematically incorporating competing determinants, our study also contributes to the literature that argues in favor of comparing and combining theories to explain environmental attitudes (Franzen and Meyer 2010), WTP (Liebe et al. 2010), and other forms of pro-environmental intentions or behavior (see, e.g., Stern 2000; Wall et al. 2007). To date, most studies have focused on a single theory or a limited number of theoretical determinants.

Using data from the 2007 Swiss Environment Survey (N = 3,369), a general population study, we empirically test the effects of several theoretically proposed determinants of WTP for increased general environmental protection, CO2-neutralizing devices for cars as well as CO2-neutral fuel. This variety of dependent variables allows us to draw more general conclusions about the determinants of WTP for environmental goods. From a theoretical perspective, the focus is on the distinction between pure public environmental goods such as measures toward general environmental protection and quasi-private environmental goods such as CO2-neutral fuel. All the environmental goods examined have one commonality: they involve the payment of a ‘surcharge’ on top of the cost of less environmentally friendly alternatives. These payments thus constitute the characteristic differentiating them from traditional forms of pro-environmental behavior, which are not dependent on individual wealth per se and may even bring financial benefits (saving energy, for example).

Theoretical determinants of willingness to pay

According to the compensation hypothesis, we begin our theoretical review of the determinants of WTP for environmental goods with the standard economic theory (i.e. income). Then, we discuss the importance of time preferences (i.e. subjective discount rates), altruism, and aspects of social dilemmas (i.e. generalized trust and conditional cooperation). Finally, we examine determinants from research into attitudes and values (i.e. environmental concern and post-materialistic values).

As discussed in the introduction, we differentiate our explanatory objects and distinguish between WTP for pure public environmental goods (e.g., measures toward general environmental protection) and quasi-private environmental goods (e.g., CO2-neutral fuel). Pure public environmental goods are characterized by a non-excludability and non-rivalry of consumption (Samuelson 1954; Cornes and Sandler 1986). Quasi-private environmental goods, however, show all the characteristics of private goods (excludability and rivalry) and thus produce individual private utility (e.g., the benefits of driving). But at the same time they do also have positive external effects on the environment (e.g., the improvement of environmental quality by using CO2-neutral fuel). Thus, some of the theoretical determinants may vary in the strength of their effect depending on the environmental good considered.

Income

According to the compensation hypothesis (or the affluence hypothesis), income is the most important determinant of WTP for public and quasi-private environmental goods (Baumol and Oates 1979; Carson et al. 2001; Barry and Field 2009). In the context of a restricted budget—given identical preferences—individuals with a higher income will be able to spend more for environmental goods than individuals with a lower income. Thus, we expect a positive effect of income on WTP for both pure public environmental goods and quasi-private environmental goods (see Table 1). From this standard economic view, behavioral differences do not arise from varying preferences, which are assumed to be the same for all but are the result of unequal constraints (i.e. incomes).

Table 1 Theoretical determinants of and effects on willingness to pay for environmental goods

Subjective discount rate

Thwarting the expectations of standard economic theory, individuals do not always behave rationally when purchasing environmentally friendly goods. For example, when buying durable household goods such as a refrigerator, people often do not choose the model likely to be the most economical in the long run and which is ecologically preferable. When consumers have a stronger preference for the present over the future, they choose models with higher energy consumption but lower initial costs over models with low energy consumption but greater initial costs (Hausman 1979; Gately 1980; Ruderman et al. 1987).

Time preferences can be expressed in the subjective discount rate as an element of the discounting function (Samuelson 1937), which corresponds to the relative value that a person ascribes to her well-being at the point t in time compared to the point t + x (see Frederick et al. 2002 for a theoretical overview). The higher the subjective discount rate, the less important the future well-being. Investments in public and quasi-private environmental goods such as political measures toward environmental protection and the consumption of CO2-neutral fuel are exactly the kind of investments which only pay off in the distant future, and their utility for the environment is not directly noticeable. Thus, people with a higher subjective discount rate or a lower orientation toward the future should be less likely to pay for such goods.Footnote 4

Altruism

As the use-value of environmental goods is often not immediately apparent and is not restricted to those who pay, altruism must also be taken into consideration as a determinant. In the literature on economic valuation of public environmental goods, this idea has already been taken up with the concept of ‘non-use values’ (e.g., Freeman III 2003). According to this notion, expenditure on environmental goods leads to a bequest value in that the natural environment (diversity of species, water quality, etc.) is preserved for future generations: individuals’ own children and grandchildren. Altruism is not, however, necessarily directed solely at other people as beneficiaries; it can also be aimed at animals and plants, whole landscapes or the biosphere itself (Stern et al. 1993; Guagnano et al. 1994). Altruists are interested in improving the welfare of third parties, whether people or elements of the natural environment. In contrast to this ‘pure’ altruism, some studies have shown that altruistic behavior can itself generate use-value (‘participatory altruism’ is examined in Margolis 1982, and ‘impure altruism’ in Andreoni 1989, 1990), the feeling of ‘doing something good’. Expenditure on environmental goods is one way of purchasing this ‘feel-good factor’ or ‘moral satisfaction’ (see Kahneman and Knetsch 1992). Empirically, it is difficult to separate ‘pure’ altruism from ‘impure’ altruism (the ‘feel-good factor’). In the context of an additional use-value component, altruists, whether acting from ‘pure’ or ‘impure’ altruism, should show a greater WTP for environmental goods.

The influence of altruism is certainly not restricted to pure public environmental goods. In the case of WTP for quasi-private environmental goods, too, a positive relationship can be expected (Guagnano 2001, among others). This relationship is likely to be weaker because the private utility component is added to the public one.

Generalized trust and conditional cooperation

So far, we have viewed WTP (within the literature on economic valuation) as the purchase of environmental goods influenced by income as a budget constraint as well as time preferences and explicit altruistic preferences. This view changes fundamentally when WTP is taken as a contribution to a public (environmental) good for which non-excludability from the benefit applies (Samuelson 1954). This means that even people who have contributed nothing profit from the provision of the good, in the sense that their preferences are also met. The individual incentive to use the good as a ‘free rider’ leads to a social dilemma: “Social dilemmas are situations in which individual rationality leads to public irrationality. […] As individuals we are each better off when we make use of a public resource, such as public television, without making any contribution, but if everyone acted on this conclusion, the public resource would not be provided and we would all be hurt” (Kollock 1998, p. 183).

In contrast to these incentive structures, individuals do nevertheless make substantial (albeit often suboptimal) contributions to public (environmental) goods (see Ledyard 1995; Camerer 2003 for overviews). They are willing to make expenditures although they could benefit from the others’ expenditure without doing anything themselves. Are people not aware of the structure of the social dilemma situation, or do they rely on the simultaneous financial contributions of others? Various theoretical approaches have attempted to place these and other questions in relation to voluntary contributions to public goods. Two determinants are consistently addressed: conditional cooperation and generalized trust (e.g., Ostrom 2000; Putnam 2000; Fischbacher et al. 2001; Gächter 2007). Central to both concepts (which are somewhat related) is the dependence of individuals’ behavior on expectations regarding the behavior of others. Conditionally cooperating individuals only make a contribution to a specific public good such as environmental protection when they are convinced that others are also doing so. Conversely, unconditionally cooperating individuals make decisions concerning WTP for a specific good entirely independent of their expectations of third parties’ actions. One might argue that generalized (or social) trust turns people into unconditional cooperators or that it makes conditional cooperators confident that the others also contribute to public goods. In either case, those who have a high level of generalized trust are more likely to initiate cooperation and, hence, to contribute more to the provision of public goods than those with lower levels of generalized trust.

Independent of other determinants, WTP should be lower when people base their pro-environmental behavior on the contributions of third parties and higher when they have generalized trust in others. These expected correlations should apply to both public and quasi-private environmental goods, as both improve the general quality of the environment. With quasi-private environmental goods such as CO2-neutral fuel, however, the private utility component comes into play; therefore, aspects of a (perceived) social dilemma should be less significant for these goods. Thus, we expect a lower correlation for general trust and conditional cooperation in the case of a quasi-private environmental good.

Environmental concern

In contrast to economic theories, in the (social-)psychological approach, attitudes constitute a key determinant—possibly the most important determinant—of behavior and behavioral intentions. In (social-)psychological environmental research, general environmental concern is used to explain individual pro-environmental behavior. However, attitudes and behavior are shown to be only moderately related when, contrary to the correspondence rule, they are not measured on the same level of specificity (see Hines et al. 1986/1987). Several empirical studies still, however, infer significant effects of general environmental concern on specific pro-environmental behaviors such as WTP for environmental goods (e.g., Cooper et al. 2004; Kotchen and Reiling 2000). Despite a stimulating discussion of newer models postulating indirect effects of environmental concern (e.g., the ABC model in Guagnano et al. 1995 or the low-cost hypothesis in Diekmann and Preisendörfer 2003), in this paper, we are only examining direct effects, according to which individuals with a higher environmental concern should show a higher WTP for public and quasi-private environmental goods.

Post-materialistic values

The final rival determinant comes from values research. According to Inglehart’s post-materialism hypothesis (Inglehart 1990, 1995, 1997), people with post-materialistic values can be assumed to show a greater WTP for environmental goods. These ideals are the result of a fundamental shift from materialistic to post-materialistic values experienced by people who grow up in secure conditions. With increasing prosperity, people are freed of pressing economic problems and can follow other—post-materialistic—goals such as self-fulfillment, ‘freedom’ or environmental protection (the ‘scarcity hypothesis’). In contrast to the income effect, the post-materialism hypothesis concerns a long-term change in preferences and/or values and not in constraints. These values are formed during socialization and often remain intact throughout individuals’ entire lives (the ‘socialization hypothesis’). Thus, those who show greater WTP for environmental goods do not necessarily have high incomes. They must, however, have been socialized under conditions of physical and economic security in order to develop post-materialistic values.

Table 1 offers a summary of the theoretical determinants to be tested and their expected effects (direction and strength) on WTP, by type of environmental good.

Data basis, variables, and descriptive findings

The following sections provide information about our dataset, the methods and the measurements of determinants. In addition, we present descriptive findings on the dependent and explanatory variables.

Database and methods

The empirical analyses are based on data gathered in a nationwide, general population study, the Swiss Environmental Survey 2007.Footnote 5 Data collection is based on a two-stage random sample taken from members of the adult population of Switzerland with a registered telephone.Footnote 6 The selected households were notified by mail before the survey was carried out. The study was described as an investigation into ‘living conditions in Switzerland’ and not as an ‘environmental study’ in order to avoid a disproportionate number of people with an above-average interest in the environment taking part. The households were then contacted by telephone. The respondent in each household was selected at random from all members of the household over eighteen and interviewed in German, French, or Italian. Foreigners who belonged to the resident population were also included as long as they could answer questions in one of these three languages. The response rate was 52% (RR2, according to standards laid down by the American Association for Public Opinion Research, AAPOR). The telephone interview, with an average length of 37 min, was followed by a written follow-up questionnaire. A total of 83% of those interviewed by telephone also took part in the written, postal questionnaire (Diekmann and Meyer 2008).Footnote 7

Variables and descriptive findings

The dependent variables constitute three questions on WTP for environmental goods (for the exact wording, see Table 5 in the Appendix). The first question is about WTP higher taxes to improve general environmental protection. The second question is about the acquisition of an additional car device that prevents the emission of CO2 while driving. The third question concerns WTP a surcharge for CO2-neutral fuel. The technology to produce both these CO2-neutral goods does not (yet) exist, and so these are hypothetical scenarios. For both scenarios, respondents were told to assume no other changes in the vehicle. The question relating to fuel was answered only by motorists.

With these three questions, willingness or unwillingness to pay in principle was first established and, in the case of a positive response, a follow-up question asked for the amount the respondent would be willing to pay. The general environmental protection question requested a monthly sum additional to all current taxes and expenditures. With the CO2 device, the follow-up question asked how much the respondents would be willing to pay for such a product, including the cost of installing it in their vehicle. To determine the size of the surcharge for CO2-neutral fuel, 1.6 Swiss francs were assumed to be the normal price of a liter of gas (the market price at the time of the survey).

A shared characteristic of these three dependent variables is the voluntary financial contribution to public environmental protection. The first question asks about a pure public good, improved general environmental protection (see Table 1, left-hand column). The second and third questions ask about quasi-private goods, a CO2-neutral device, and CO2-neutral fuel (see Table 1, right-hand column): alongside their benefits to the environment, they also provide the benefits of driving. In addition, if the vehicle is understood as a status symbol (see ‘conspicuous consumption’, in Veblen 1899; Frank 1985), an increase in prestige constituting a private utility could also be seen to apply for these two CO2-related goods (particularly as the questions stipulated that the other characteristics of the vehicles remain the same). The CO2-neutral fuel and the additional device are in any case tied to a durable consumer good: the vehicle.

Table 2 gives descriptive statistics of the dependent variables. For WTP in principle (Yes–No), the share of individuals willing to pay is shown firstly for all valid responses to this question and then only for observations included in multivariate analyses.Footnote 8 Despite different numbers of observations, the shares remain largely identical and show that the Swiss population’s WTP can be rated highly when compared internationally, particularly as far as taxes for environmental protection are concerned (see, for example, Franzen and Meyer 2010 on reference values in 2000 for Germany, Japan and the United States). About 70% of the respondents are prepared to pay higher taxes or expenditures for improved general environmental protection. For the reduction of CO2 specifically, the acceptance rate is even 10 percentage points higher (CO2-neutralizing device and fuel around 80%). On the one hand, the high agreement rates are hardly due to a selection bias (cf. “Database and methods”); on the other hand, we cannot completely rule out the influence of social desirability. However, it should be kept in mind that we are not primarily interested in absolute rates but in explaining WTP by competing determinants and, hence, their relative effects.

Table 2 Variables and descriptive results for willingness to pay

The amounts people say they are willing to pay (assuming WTP in principle) are listed at the bottom of the table. On average, participants are prepared to pay additional taxes amounting to around CHF 100 ($88, calculated according to the exchange rate in June 2009) per month for improved environmental protection. The standard deviation is relatively high, however. In order to avoid biases through extreme outliers, the top centile is excluded from the multivariate analyses. This procedure was also used for the CO2-neutralizing device.Footnote 9 The mean WTP for this is CHF 1,680 ($1,500) and, even with the above-mentioned boundary, reaches a maximum of CHF 7,000 ($6,250).Footnote 10 For CO2-neutral fuel, the upper boundary was set at CHF 1.60, the amount indicated in the survey as the reference price for a liter of fuel. For amounts above CHF 1.60, despite unambiguous wording of the question, it is still unclear whether or not these values refer to the total price (1.60 plus surcharge). Around 6% of the responses were thus excluded. In relation to the reference price, the mean surcharge of 0.27 CHF corresponds to a price increase of around 17 percentage points.

Table 3 contains descriptions of the variables and descriptive results for the theoretical determinants and other control variables included in the multivariate analyses as independent variables (for exact wording, see Table 6 in the appendix). Income as the central explanatory variable is operationalized by what is known as the net household equivalence income. This is calculated by dividing the disposable household income by the square root of the number of individuals living in the household. Due to its right-skewed distribution, the logarithm is taken before it is entered in regression analysis in Table 4.

Table 3 Variables and descriptive findings of the dependent variables
Table 4 Full multivariate models to explain willingness to pay for environmental goods

In order to determine the subjective discount rate, respondents participated in a hypothetical game at the end of the telephone interview. In this game, they chose between two amounts of money: CHF 1,000 ($880) immediately or a larger amount of money in a year’s time. If the respondent opted for the larger sum, this amount was reduced and the person was asked again to choose between the sum of CHF 1,000 paid out immediately and the larger sum after a year. This was continued until the respondent either opted for the sum of CHF 1,000 immediately or until the amount closest to CHF 1,000 was reached.Footnote 11 In order to make this game as realistic as possible, three respondents were randomly selected to receive an amount between CHF 1,000 and CHF 2,000 in accordance with their responses. From the results of these games, we calculated each respondent’s discount rate. The average discount rate was 65%. This result is in line with other studies (Frederick et al. 2002), which also found the average subjective discount rate to be well above the objective market interest on monetary loans.

Altruism was measured using a behaviorist approach. A ‘2’ on the index for altruism is given to people who have an organ donor card and have voluntarily given blood at least once in their life. Anyone who fulfills one of the two criteria is given a ‘1’ and everyone else a ‘0’. On average, participants answer fewer than one of the questions in the affirmative (see Table 3).

The generalized trust of the participants, on the other hand, is more pronounced. It is measured with an additive index of three 5-point questions on perceived trustworthiness, opportunism, and helpfulness. Ranging from 3 to 15, the index has a mean of almost 10, and the reliability is 0.61 (Cronbach’s alpha). On a 5-point response scale (1 = cooperation irrespective of others, 5 = cooperation only if others also make a contribution), the average for the extent of conditional cooperation is 2. In other words, for at least some of the respondents, the contribution of others does not appear to be a prerequisite for taking environmental action themselves.

Environmental concern is measured using nine 5-point questions proposed by Diekmann and Preisendörfer (2001). In line with socio-psychological research on attitudes, the questions can be classified according to three components: ‘affective’, ‘cognitive’, and ‘conative’. A factor analysis with subsequent varimax rotation gives a one-dimensional solution, and the reliability of the scale is 0.76 (Cronbach’s alpha). Ranging from 10 to 45, the environmental concern scale has a mean of 33.

Post-materialism is measured with the set of questions proposed by Inglehart (1990) where participants have to select the two most important policies for the country from four specified policies (two materialistic and two post-materialistic). The index of post-materialism can have the values 0, 1 or 2, depending on how many post-materialist goals are preferred. Only 9% of respondents may be described as pure post-materialists, that is these persons reported both of the two post-materialistic items to be a priority for the country.

In addition to the theoretical determinants, we also tested a number of socio-demographic variables that might influence WTP for environmental goods. Compared to the official statistics (BFS Bundesamt für Statistik, Sektion Demografie und Migration 2007), there are slightly more women in our dataset (54%) than in the population (52%), and the middle-age group is somewhat overrepresented (18–39 years: 33 vs. 36%, 40–59 years: 41 vs. 36%, 60–95 years: 26 vs. 27%). In a large number of studies (e.g., Greenbaum 1995; Dietz et al. 1998; Zelezny et al. 2000), women, younger people, and those with a higher educationFootnote 12 display greater tendency toward environmentally friendly action. As we control for these variables in our models, we rule out a potential bias of the effects of interest from a theoretical perspective. Education in years was calculated from the highest degree of education completed according to recommendations of the Swiss Federal Statistical Office. In the models on WTP for a reduction of CO2 emissions (CO2-neutralizing device for the vehicle and fuel), the number of kilometers driven per year and car ownership were also included as control variables.

Multivariate analyses

For all dependent variables, the WTP was measured in two steps, firstly willingness in principle and secondly the amount. In our analysis, we interpret these two steps as two independent decisions and analyze them separately, using a logistic model for WTP in principle and an OLS regression for the amount. We believe separating these analyses is justified both statistically and substantively. WTP involves two qualitatively different decisions (intention to buy versus no intention to buy; amount willing to pay given an intention to buy), which might be determined differently. For example, the decision to buy a vehicle is likely distinct from the decision about the price that a person is prepared to pay: income may not influence the decision to buy at all, but clearly has an effect on the price paid. The same mechanism likely plays a role regarding environmental goods.

These arguments can also be supported statistically. We have tested to what extent a separate analysis of both decisions is statistically acceptable and whether explanatory determinants display the same effect on both decisions. We compared a Tobit model against a Cragg model (see Cragg 1971; Jones 1989; Liebe 2007). The Tobit model is based on censored data and is a ‘hybrid’ of a binary and a continuous regression, while the Cragg model is a ‘two-part model’ that assumes independence of both decisions and comprises a separate estimate of a binary model and a truncated regression. Over and above that, a further simplification (complete dominance) can be made if in addition to the superiority of the Cragg model, a dominance of the WTP in principle over decisions on the WTP amount (first hurdle dominance) can be observed. This can be tested with a Heckman selection model (see specifically Jones 1989). Our data fulfills the assumptions of the Cragg model as well as the dominance assumption on the basis of a Heckman model, supporting the separate estimate of a logistic model for WTP in principle and an OLS regression for the WTP amounts on statistical grounds.

The results of the multivariate models with all variables are shown in Table 4.Footnote 13 The first three columns give the results of the binary logistic regressions for WTP in principle and the last three columns the results of the OLS regressions explaining the amount participants were willing to pay (among those who said they were willing to pay in principle).

Income—the central variable from the perspective of the compensation hypothesis (or affluence hypothesis)—has a consistent positive and significant effect. While the effect on general environmental protection in principle is rather weak (significant at the 10% level), the effect on the amount of WTP is quite strong. This trend can also be detected in a basic model in which only income and the control variables are included as predictors (see Appendix, Table 7; no significant effect in the logistic model for general environmental protection). The income effects from these basic models also remain stable or even gain in importance under control of all other theoretical determinants (Table 4). The compensation hypothesis is therefore generally confirmed.Footnote 14

The stronger the time preference or the higher the subjective discount rate, the lower the WTP, as shown by the result for a CO2-neutralizing device for the car. This negative effect applies both to WTP in principle and to the WTP amount. For the other two environmental goods, time preference does not play any role. The influence of the subjective discount rate therefore seems not to depend on the type of decision but rather on the characteristics of the environmental good. One differentiating criterion implied here is the time schedule of the financial investment made and the resulting pay-off. Of the environmental goods considered, the CO2-neutralizing device is the one that most closely encapsulates the basic problem of time preferences in the environmental sector, that is, a large initial investment in a consumer durable with subsequent (private) pay-offs in the long term (Hausman 1979, among others). With the other two environmental goods considered, in each case the investment is a matter of repeated decisions (monthly contribution for the environment in general and filling up with fuel).

The pattern for the influence of altruism is also quite clear. Persons behaving altruistically in other ways show a significant higher WTP for CO2-neutral fuel (in principle and also concerning the amount they are willing to pay) and they are willing to pay a higher amount for a CO2-neutral device for their vehicle. In the other models, the coefficient on altruism has the expected positive sign but does not exceed the significance threshold. Our measure of altruism by means of willingness to donate blood or organs only captures the altruism described by Stern et al. (1993) as ‘anthropocentric’. In fact, CO2 is an issue connected to medium and long-term consequences for humanity. Regarding general environmental protection, however, concern about the welfare of all creatures and plants (‘biospheric’ altruism) might also be of significance (Stern et al. 1993). If ‘biospheric’ altruism is really more important than ‘anthropocentric’ altruism, this would explain the lack of an altruism effect in connection with general environmental protection. Unfortunately, this idea cannot be tested here; in future work, these two types of altruism (‘anthropocentric’ and ‘biospheric’) should be measured separately in order to shed more light on this question.

Generalized trust has the expected positive and significant effect on WTP in principle in all three models. Trust in other people encourages the decision to make a contribution toward environmental protection through buying public and quasi-private environmental goods. As for the amount people are willing to pay, a significant positive effect can be observed for taxes to support general environmental protection, which confirms our hypothesis that the effect of trust in a social dilemma situation is more pronounced for pure public goods than for quasi-private ones. The results for conditional cooperation, however, do not show the expected pattern. Here, the effect is stronger for quasi-private environmental goods: the more people make their own environment-related behavior dependent on the behavior of others, the lower the willingness to pay in principle for CO2-neutral fuel. Apart from this effect, no other significant effects of conditional cooperation can be observed. Overall, a pattern emerges where trust in others and strategies of conditional cooperation have a greater influence on WTP in principle than on the amount people are willing to spend. This is in line with the intuitive expectation that in the context of a social dilemma, the expected behavior of others has a stronger effect on the decision to cooperate per se than on the amount of the contribution (given a willingness to cooperate).

Environmental concern as a general attitude is the most influential determinant across all models in Table 4. It has the expected positive and significant effect. Those with environmentally friendly attitudes are more willing to pay in principle for public and quasi-private environmental goods and are also willing to make higher payments. Some authors (e.g., Kahneman et al. 1993, 1999) put the direct measure of WTP on the same level as specific attitudes toward the environmental good and, therefore, would assign it to the conative component of environmental concern. From this perspective, the effects of environmental concern reported here should not be interpreted causally. However, we understand and operationalize environmental concern as a general attitude toward the environment, the basis for specific behavioral intentions and actual behavior.

The effects of the intensity of post-materialist values do not give such a coherent picture. Nevertheless, except for the CO2-neutralizing device (WTP in principle) and the additional environmental taxes (WTP amount), the expected positive significant effect can be observed. Overall—along with general environmental concern and income—post-materialism proved to be one of the key determinants in our study.

With regard to the control variables, relatively stable effects of education can be seen where the WTP in principle and the WTP amount mostly rise significantly with an increasing level of education.

The overall explanatory power of the models is rather low (see Pseudo-R 2 and Adj. R 2). Compared to the basic models (see Appendix), containing only control variables and income as independent variables, the additional determinants in Table 4 show improvements in the model performance of between 6 percentage points (for the CO2-neutral device) and 11 percentage points (for general environmental protection) as far as WTP in principle is concerned and of about 3 percentage points for the amount people are willing to pay. This indicates that the compensation hypothesis is most convincing in explaining the additional amount people are willing to pay for the environment. However, with regard to WTP in principle, other competing explanatory variables such as environmental concern and aspects of social dilemmas are equally important.

Conclusions and discussion

‘Environmental Justice’ research consistently finds unequally distributed environmental burdens and social differences in consumption—both weighted in favor of more affluent individuals. We asked to what extent affluent individuals were willing to pay more for environmental protection in return. The validity of the compensation hypothesis was tested empirically by accounting for the effect of income and controlling for competing theoretical determinants on WTP. For this, the classic economic theory, which explains behavior using assumptions about preferences and constraints, was supplemented by altruistic preferences and aspects of social dilemmas. Additionally and for the first time to our knowledge, we included survey-based time preferences (subjective discount rates) as a determinant of WTP for environmental goods. The selection of theory-based determinants was completed with environmental concern as general attitude, the central concept in (socio-) psychological research, and with post-materialistic values. In line with the results of other studies (e.g., Cragg 1971; Liebe et al. 2010), not all determinants in our analysis have the same effect on the WTP in principle as they have on the WTP amount. A separate analysis for these two decisions was, therefore, deemed important.

Two key findings emerge: first, the affluent are more willing to spend money to offset the environmental destruction of their spending habits. This holds true for the WTP in principle and the WTP amount. When all other competing theoretical determinants are simultaneously taken into account, the compensation hypothesis can be confirmed particularly regarding the amount of WTP. Second, the effect of income does not change with the environmental good under examination. Therefore, the compensation hypothesis is confirmed universally, irrespective of the environmental good in question. However, in convincing individuals to make a contribution to the environment at all (i.e. WTP in principle), general environmental concern, generalized interpersonal trust and, to a certain degree, strategies of conditional cooperation as well as post-materialistic values are all at least equally important.

While subjective discount rates were shown to have no universal effect on WTP for environmental goods, a significant influence could be identified in the case of the CO2-neutralizing device for motor vehicles. This quasi-private environmental good most closely resembles the consumer durables whose acquisition is discussed within environmental research under the heading of ‘time preferences’. Apart from this, the theoretically based assumption that certain determinants display varying effects depending on the characteristic of the environmental good (public vs. quasi-private goods, see Table 1) cannot be confirmed in the current analysis.

Further, our results indicate that, alongside income, environmental concern and aspects of social dilemmas should also be taken into consideration when (political) decision makers seek to encourage financial contributions toward environmental protection. Income has a strong positive influence on the amount that would be paid (assuming a WTP in principle), which implies that some form of compensation for the double advantage enjoyed by affluent individuals over poorer individuals can be found.

Future research into such environment-related inequalities should more precisely analyze the effects of income and their social distribution using other research objects as well (e.g., the sustainability of consumption patterns or the individuals’ adaptation to environmental innovations). It would also be desirable to compare the size of these compensation effects with the smaller degree of environmental burdens and the greater consumption of resources enjoyed by the affluent. Collecting data on actual purchasing behavior would be an additional useful step in this line of research.

Our theoretical and empirical analysis strategy has several strengths compared to other studies—although they could also be viewed as weaknesses. All of the theoretical determinants we considered have a vague relationship to WTP in terms of a behavioral intention or behavior. Accordingly, these factors were measured on a general level (e.g., the subjective discount rates). The strength thus lies in the fact that these determinants comply with many different types of behavior, in this case WTP for diverse kinds of environmental goods. Our study does indeed show that factors such as general environmental concern and generalized trust play a significant role in explaining WTP for various environmental goods and ultimately complement the compensation hypothesis, putting it into perspective. The relationships between such general factors and specific behavioral intentions or behavior (such as the purchase of CO2-neutral fuel), however, lead to regression models of low explanatory power, which could be interpreted as a weakness of our analyses. Following the correspondence rule, more specific determinants might lead to stronger empirical relationships—for example, attitudes toward CO2 reduction in the field of transport (e.g., within the context of the theory of planned behavior, Ajzen 1991). But one should be aware that with such an approach, the number of research objects would be greatly reduced. Occasionally, it cannot be ruled out that general attitudes might even develop a stronger effect than specific attitudes (see, e.g., Liebe et al. 2010 for an example regarding WTP for the protection of biodiversity in forests).

Although no strong effects can be noted in our study, the inclusion of time preferences in explanations of WTP for environmental protection and for other forms of pro-environmental behavior can be regarded as important. But subjective discount rates are currently not assessed in standardized forms and, hence, measurement instruments should be improved.

Studies that systematically incorporate competing determinants for the explanation of pro-environmental behavior are rare (Kollmuss and Agyeman 2002). Future research should pursue this approach further. Decision makers need to know the real incentives for pro-environmental behavior. This study is an important step in that direction.