Skip to main content
Log in

Policy Responsiveness and Electoral Incentives: A (Re)assessment

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Political Behavior Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Competitive democratic theory predicts that electoral factors enhance policy makers' responsiveness to public opinion. Yet findings on the effects of electoral incentives on policy responsiveness point in different directions and comparative research remains limited, lacking of a systematic evaluation. We draw on previous work, expand the range of electoral incentives, and re-assess their role in influencing policy responsiveness by using spending preferences. We provide extensive tests of an Electoral Vulnerability Hypothesis and an Electoral Proximity Hypothesis. Contra competitive democratic theory, time-series analysis from Canada, the United Kingdom and the United States in twenty policy domains and nine different indicators for electoral incentives finds limited support for these hypotheses. Our findings have implications for democracy and question the importance of electoral pressures in explaining policy responsiveness.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This finding is backed up by consistent cross-country evidence on policy agendas that policy makers’ attention follows or is congruent with public issue priorities (Jones and Baumgartner 2004; Jennings and John 2009; Bonafont and Palau 2011; John et al. 2011; Lindeboom 2012; Bevan and Jennings 2014; Visconti 2018).

  2. However, note that re-election is not the only goal that parties would follow (Strøm 1990) and that governing parties have intrinsic preferences over the policies they enact (see, e.g., Wittman 1977, 1983).

  3. Soroka and Wlezien (2010, p. 139) provided a basic test for the hypothesis on social domains combined and found limited evidence of a marginality effect only in the United States (the interaction between public preferences and vote margin was statistically significant only at p ≤ 0.10), but not in the United Kingdom and Canada.

  4. Note that, in the United States, the impact of electoral pressures on policy responsiveness might be conditional on whether the Presidential party holds a majority in Congress. It might be the case that electoral incentives have a greater impact on policy responsiveness in cases of unified than divided government, for the President would have freer hands to follow what the public wants and the Congressional party may share the incentives of a president to be responsive to high salience public concerns (see Coleman 1999; Green and Jennings 2017). Unfortunately, our N is too small for fully testing this possibility empirically.

  5. Note that, although less relevant to us, a great deal of work focuses on US legislators’ roll call behaviour and, in comparison with the presidential literature, finds wide evidence that legislators are more responsive to public opinion in the year they face re-election.

  6. Data on Canada are downloaded from Soroka and Wlezien’s “Degrees of Democracy: Politics, Public Opinion and Policy” Canadian data set available at: http://www.degreesofdemocracy.net/data.html. Data on the United Kingdom and the United States are downloaded from the Replication data for the Jennings and Wlezien (2015) article published in Political Science Research and Methods available at: https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataset.xhtml?persistentId=doi:10.7910/DVN/27496. Due to some missing values in the UK and US preferences, we follow Jennings and Wlezien (2015) and use interpolated data in our analyses.

  7. Of course other measures exist, but they are either about institutional vulnerability or based on aggregate electoral data such as indices of electoral competitiveness, the closeness of electoral result, and the frequency of turnover (Schlesinger 1955, 1960; Ranney 1965; Stern 1972; Meltz 1973; Elkins 1974; Ferejohn 1977; Patterson and Caldeira 1984; Endersby et al. 2002; Grofman and Selb 2009; Blais and Lago 2009; André et al. 2014; Immergut and Abou-Chadi 2014; Abou-Chadi and Orlowski 2016). These kinds of measures are problematic when we want to study government responsiveness, for at least three reasons. First, we simply are not interested in institutional vulnerability. Second, responsiveness occurs not at election time but between elections, therefore using measures based on election data would be problematic if not misleading. Third, such measures are time invariant and artificially static for the whole election cycle, they are US-specific, measured at the district level and not at the national level, or designed for other purposes. It is much better, both from a validity and degrees of freedom/variability perspective, to measure potential vulnerability with survey estimates for each year, rather than using the single value of the posterior elections for all the 3–5 years prior to the elections. Note that using measures based on voter’s propensity to vote (Kroh et al. 2007; Tillie 1995; van der Eijk and Oppenhuis 1991) would not solve our issue since such data come from pre-election surveys and hence not available at least on a yearly basis.

  8. Vote intentions data for Canada come from Environics, data for the United Kingdom come from different polls available in Wlezien et al. (2013) and Green and Jennings (2012), and data for the United States come, again, from different polls available in Jennings and Wlezien (2016).

  9. Being the United States a case of presidentialism with a pure two-party system, the formateur argument is clearly less relevant here and the FPV measure would simply be identical to the GPV measure.

  10. Data on marginality come from Soroka and Wlezien (2010). Note that for the United States we re-estimated our analyses while using presidential vote margins, which mirror the findings based on congressional vote margins.

  11. Data on Kayser and Lindstädt’s (2015) LPR measure are available here: http://mark-kayser.com/data.html.

  12. Given the concern around the use of the lagged dependent variable (LDV) whereby its inclusion would depress the explanatory power of main explanatory factors and absorb part of the trend in the dependent variable (Achen 2000; Plümper et al. 2005), we re-estimated our models without the [POLICY (t − 1)] variable and our substantive conclusions do not change. Hence, we preferred to present in the paper results from the models that control for the past level of spending. However, the analyses without the LDV are reported in Tables S49–S51.

  13. We considered the possibility that 1 year lag might not be enough for policy to respond. Thus we re-estimated our analyses with public preferences and the dynamic measures of electoral vulnerability variables lagged of 2 years. Although these analyses should be taken with extra caution given our already small N, we found no particular evidence of such a delayed (conditional) effect. The analyses are reported in Tables S70–S72.

  14. Given the way the lagged electoral vulnerability variables are created, in the empirical analyses we omit country-years when a new government emerged whose ideology differed from the previous government. This is because in these years the lagged levels of government vulnerability pertain to different governments. However, we consider successive governments with the same Prime Minister (or President) as the same and include country-years where there was continuity in the governing party but a new President (Prime Minister), for the incoming head of government was closely associated with the outgoing leader’s government (see Bernardi and Adams 2017). We re-estimated our analyses (reported in Tables S67–S69) while including those few omitted observations and our substantive conclusions do not change.

  15. We use the partisanship variables available in the same data sets of the spending and preferences data (see footnote 6).

  16. SUR models are preferred to OLS models since our dependent variables are unlikely to be independent, as they are part of the same budget. We thank the anonymous reviewer for this suggestion. Further, we note that, given our small N, in the paper we only report the results for our basic models without over controlling for any additional factors. In particular, since controlling for economic indicators does not subvert the validity of the main conclusions drawn from our basic models (these analyses are reported in Table S64–S66), we opted for a parsimonious strategy and decided to exclude such variables from the analyses. Also, as some readers might want to see the analyses for the Electoral Vulnerability Hypothesis and the Electoral Proximity Hypothesis controlling for the other electoral incentive, we report these analyses in Tables S52–S63.

  17. The analyses with GPU are excluded in the UK because the indicator never falls within the values identified for uncertainty in Table 1. We also note that in UK analyses, the partisan variable is omitted because all governments are from the Conservative Party.

  18. For the US we only report GPV and GPU but not FPV and FPU because both sets of indicators are always computed between Democrats and Republicans, and so the measures are identical.

  19. Though not advisable with very small number of observations (e.g., Jennings 2013), as a final test, we have also re-estimated our analyses by using an error correction model (ECM) in order to capture some short- and long-term effects (analyses are available upon request). Although these analyses should be taken with extra caution, only in a handful of occasions the interaction between changes in public opinion and electoral incentives was statistically significant in the expected direction, supporting our findings of a limited impact of electoral incentives on policy responsiveness.

  20. Note that whether the sign of the coefficient for public preferences in the policy representation analyses should be positive, the sign of the coefficient for policy in the public responsiveness analyses can be either negative, if a negative feedback prevails, or positive, if a positive feedback prevails (for a full discussion on feedback, see Soroka and Wlezien 2010, pp. 29–30). The dependent variable in the public responsiveness model is estimated in levels (e.g., see Soroka and Wlezien 2005). Like in previous analyses, the analyses on public responsiveness control for the lagged dependent variable, which indeed appears to be strongly significant in all instances. Without the inclusion of the lagged dependent variable we find four more cases of public responsiveness (Tables S44, S46 and S48). However, this difference does not undermine the conclusions we can draw from Table 3.

  21. However, we tried whether past spending influences opinion change conditional on (current and past) electoral vulnerability but we did not find much evidence of elite manipulation. Analyses are available upon request.

References

  • Abou-Chadi, T., & Orlowski, M. (2016). Moderate as necessary: The role of electoral competitiveness and party size in explaining parties’ policy shifts. The Journal of Politics,78(3), 868–881.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Achen, C. H. (2000). Why lagged dependent variables can suppress the explanatory power of other independent variables. Paper Prepared for the Annual Meeting of the Political Methodology Section of the American Political Science Association, UCLA, July 20–22.

  • Adler, S. E., & Wilkerson, J. D. (2012). Congress and the politics of problem solving. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • André, A., Depaw, S., & Martin, S. (2014). Electoral systems and legislators’ constituency effort: The mediating effect of electoral vulnerability. Comparative Political Studies.,48, 464–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartolini, S. (1999). Collusion, competition and democracy: Part I. Journal of Theoretical Politics,11(4), 435–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartolini, S. (2000). Collusion, competition and democracy: Part II. Journal of Theoretical Politics,12(1), 33–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, N., & Katz, J. N. (1995). What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-section data. The American Political Science Review,89(3), 634–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernardi, L. (2018). From popularity to vulnerability: An application to dynamic representation in coalition governments. Party Politics. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068818790117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernardi, L., & Adams, J. (2017). Does government support respond to governments’ social welfare rhetoric or their spending? An analysis of government support in Britain, Spain and the United States. British Journal of Political Science. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123417000199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bevan, S., & Jennings, W. (2014). Representation, agendas and institutions. European Journal of Political Research,53(1), 37–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bischof, D. (2018). Ideological congruence between party rhetoric and policy-making. West European Politics,41(2), 310–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A., & Lago, I. (2009). A general measure of district competitiveness. Electoral Studies,28(1), 94–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonafont, L. C., & Palau, A. M. (2011). Assessing the responsiveness of Spanish policymakers to the priorities of their citizens. West European Politics,34(4), 706–730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breunig, C. (2006). The more things change, the more things stay the same: A comparative analysis of budget punctuations. Journal of European Public Policy,13(7), 1065–1081.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burstein, P. (1998). Bringing the public back in: Should sociologists consider the impact of public opinion on public policy? Social Forces,77(1), 27–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burstein, P. (2003). The impact of public opinion on public policy: A review and an agenda. Political Research Quarterly,56(1), 29–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canes-Wrone, B. (2004). The public presidency, personal approval ratings, and policy making. Presidential Studies Quarterly,34(3), 477–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canes-Wrone, B., & Park, J.-K. (2012). Electoral business cycles in OECD countries. American Political Science Review,106(1), 103–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canes-Wrone, B., & Shotts, K. W. (2004). The conditional nature of presidential responsiveness to public opinion. American Journal of Political Science,48(4), 690–706.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, J. E. (1995). Presidential rhetoric and the public agenda. American Journal of Political Science,39(1), 87–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, J. E. (1997). Presidential responsiveness and public policy-making. The public and the policies that Presidents choose. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. J. (1999). Unified government, divided government, and party responsiveness. The American Political Science Review,93(4), 821–835.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. A. (1971). Polyarchy: Participation and opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easton, D. (1965). A framework for political analysis. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elkins, D. J. (1974). The measurement of party competition. The American Political Science Review,68(2), 682–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Endersby, J. W., Galatas, S. E., & Rackaway, C. B. (2002). Closeness Counts in Canada: Voter participation in the 1993 and 1997 Federal Elections. The Journal of Politics,64(2), 610–631.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epp, D. A., Lovett, J., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2014). Partisan priorities and public budgeting. Political Research Quarterly,67, 864–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erikson, R. S., Mackuen, M. B., & Stimson, J. A. (2002). The macro polity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fagan, E. J., Jones, B. D., & Wlezien, C. (2017). Representative systems and policy punctuations. Journal of European Public Policy,24(6), 809–831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fenno, R. F., Jr. (1977). U.S. house members in their constituencies: An exploration. The American Political Science Review,71(3), 883–917.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. A. (1977). On the decline of competition in congressional elections. The American Political Science Review,71(1), 166–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fortunato, D., & Stevenson, R. T. (2013). Perceptions of Partisan ideologies: The effect of coalition participation. American Journal of Political Science,57(2), 459–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franzese, R. J. (2002). Electoral and Partisan cycles in economic policies and outcomes. Annual Review of Political Science,5(1), 369–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedrich, C. J. (1963). Man and his government. New York: McGraw Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrett, G., & Mitchell, D. (2001). Globalization, government spending and taxation in the OECD. European Journal of Political Research,39(2), 145–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, J., & Jennings, W. (2012). Valence as macro-competence: An analysis of mood in party competence evaluations in Great Britain. British Journal of Political Science,42(2), 311–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, J., & Jennings, W. (2017). Party reputations and policy priorities: How issue ownership shapes executive and legislative agendas. British Journal of Political Science. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123416000636.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B., & Selb, P. (2009). A fully general index of political competition. Electoral Studies,28(2), 291–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakhverdian, A. (2010). Political representation and its mechanisms: A dynamic left-right approach for the United Kingdom, 1976–2006. British Journal of Political Science,40, 835–856.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hakhverdian, A. (2012). The causal flow between public opinion and policy: Government responsiveness, leadership, or counter movement? West European Politics,35(6), 1386–1406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hobolt, S. B., & Klemmensen, R. (2005). Responsive government? Public opinion and government policy preferences in Britain and Denmark. Political Studies,53(2), 379–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hobolt, S. B., & Klemmensen, R. (2008). Government responsiveness and political competition in comparative perspective. Comparative Political Studies,41(3), 309–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Immergut, E. M., & Abou-Chadi, T. (2014). How electoral vulnerability affects pension politics: Introducing a concept, measure and empirical application. European Journal of Political Research,53(2), 269–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, L. R., & Shapiro, R. Y. (2000). Politicians Don’t Pander. Political manipulation and the loss of democratic responsiveness. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jennings, W. (2013). Error-correction as a concept and as a method: Time series analysis of policy-opinion responsiveness. In M. Bruter & M. Lodge (Eds.), Political science research methods in action (pp. 203–228). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Jennings, W., & John, P. (2009). The dynamics of political attention: Public opinion and the queen’s speech in the United Kingdom. American Journal of Political Science,53(4), 838–854.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jennings, W., & Wlezien, C. (2015). Preferences, problems and representation. Political Science Research and Methods.,3, 659–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jennings, W., & Wlezien, C. (2016). The timeline of elections: A comparative perspective. American Journal of Political Science,60(1), 219–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • John, P., Bevan, S., & Jennings, W. (2011). The policy-opinion link and institutional change: The legislative agenda of the UK and Scottish Parliaments. Journal of European Public Policy,18(7), 1052–1068.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B. D., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2004). Representation and agenda setting. The Policy Studies Journal,32(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B. D., & Baumgartner, F. R. (2005). The politics of attention: How government prioritizes problems. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B. D., et al. (2009). A general empirical law of public budgets: A comparative analysis. American Journal of Political Science,53(4), 855–873.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kayser, M. A., & Lindstädt, R. (2015). A cross-national measure of electoral competitiveness. Political Analysis,23, 242–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kroh, M., van der Brug, W., & van der Eijk, C. (2007). Prospects for electoral change. In W. van der Brug & C. van der Eijk (Eds.), European elections and domestic politics. Lessons from the past and scenarios for the future (pp. 209–225). Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lau, R., & Redlawski, D. (2001). Advantages and disadvantages of cognitive heuristics in political decision making. American Journal of Political Science,45, 951–971.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lax, J. R., & Phillips, J. H. (2009). Gay rights in the states: Public opinion and policy responsiveness. American Political Science Review,103(3), 367–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lax, J. R., & Phillips, J. H. (2012). The democratic deficit in the States. American Journal of Political Science,56(1), 148–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of Democracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindeboom, G.-J. (2012). Public priorities in government’s hands: Corresponding policy agendas in the Netherlands? Acta Politica,47(4), 443–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lipsmeyer, C. S., Philips, A. Q., & Whitten, G. D. (2017). The effects of immigration and integration on European budgetary trade-offs. Journal of European Public Policy,24(6), 912–930.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loftis, M. W., & Mortensen, P. B. (2017). A new approach to the study of partisan effects on social policy. Journal of European Public Policy,24(6), 890–911.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lühiste, M., Morales, L., Bernardi, L., Bischof, D., Sabaté, O., & Visconti, F. (2017). “ResponsiveGov’s codebook and appendices.” Harvard Dataverse, V1, UNF:6:wlfV9HEyxkYtEGXMcITAdQ== https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/PINCO4.

  • Lupia, A., & McCubbins, M. (1998). The democratic dilemma: Can citizens learn what they need to know?. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mair, P. (2013). Ruling the void: The hollowing of western democracy. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manin, B., Przeworski, A., & Stokes, S. C. (1999). Elections and representation. In A. Przeworski, S. C. Stokes, & B. Manin (Eds.), Democracy, accountability, and representation (pp. 29–54). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Manza, J., & Cook, F. L. (2002). The impact of public opinion on public policy: The state of the debate. In J. Manza, F. L. Cook, & B. I. Page (Eds.), Navigating public opinion: Polls, policy and the future of American democracy (pp. 17–32). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, L. W., & Stevenson, R. T. (2001). Government formation in parliamentary democracies. American Journal of Political Science,45(1), 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew, D. R. (1974). Congress: The electoral connection. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGann, A. J., & Latner, M. (2013). The calculus of consensus democracy: Rethinking patterns of democracy without veto players. Comparative Political Studies,46(7), 823–850.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltz, D. B. (1973). An index of the measurement of interparty competition. Behavioral Science,18(1), 60–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, W. E., & Stokes, D. E. (1963). Constituency influence in congress. The American Political Science Review,57(1), 45–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. P. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies,42(2), 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Page, B. I., & Jacobs, L. R. (2009). Class war? What American really think about economic inequality. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Page, B. I., & Shapiro, R. Y. (1983). Effects of public opinion on policy. The American Political Science Review,77(1), 175–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patterson, S. C., & Caldeira, G. A. (1984). The etiology of partisan competition. The American Political Science Review,78(3), 691–707.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics. Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2002). Do electoral cycles differ across political systems? IGIER Working Paper No. 232.

  • Pickup, M., & Hobolt, S. B. (2015). The conditionality of the trade-off between government responsiveness and effectiveness: The impact of minority status and polls in the Canadian house of commons. Electoral Studies,40, 517–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pierson, P. (1993). When effect becomes cause: Policy feedback and political change. World Politics,45(4), 595–628.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pierson, P. (2004). Politics in time: History, institutions, and political analysis. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Plümper, T., Troeger, V. E., & Manow, P. (2005). Panel data analysis in comparative politics: Linking method to theory. European Journal of Political Research,44, 327–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, G. B. (2000). Elections as instruments of democracy. Majoritarian and proportional visions. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Powell, G. B., & Whitten, G. D. (1993). a cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context. American Journal of Political Science,37(2), 391–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ranney, A. (1965). Parties in state politics. In H. Jacob & K. Vines (Eds.), Politics in American states (pp. 62–71). Boston: Little Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sartori, G. (1976). Parties and party systems: A framework for analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sartori, G. (1977). Democrazia Competitiva Ed Elites Politiche. Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica,7, 327–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schlesinger, J. A. (1955). A two-dimensional scheme for classifying the states according to degree of inter-party competition. The American Political Science Review,49(4), 1120–1128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schlesinger, J. A. (1960). The structure of competition for office in the American States. Behavioral Science,5(3), 197–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M. S., & Carey, J. M. (1992). Presidents and assemblies. Constitutional design and electoral dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Soroka, S. N., & Wlezien, C. (2005). Opinion-policy dynamics: Public preferences and public expenditure in the United Kingdom. British Journal of Political Science,35, 665–689.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soroka, S. N., & Wlezien, C. (2010). Degrees of democracy: Politics, public opinion, and policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Soroka, S. N., & Wlezien, C. (2015). The majoritarian and proportional visions and democratic responsiveness. Electoral Studies.,40, 539–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soroka, S. N., Wlezien, C., & McLean, I. (2006). Public expenditure in the UK: How measures matter. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society Series A,169, 255–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern, M. (1972). Measuring interparty competition: A proposal and a test of a method. The Journal of Politics,34(3), 889–904.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stimson, J. A., Mackuen, M. B., & Erikson, R. S. (1995). Dynamic representation. The American Political Science Review,89(3), 543–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strøm, K. (1989). Inter-party competition in advanced democracies. Journal of Theoretical Politics,1(3), 277–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strøm, K. (1990). A behavioral theory of competitive political parties. American Journal of Political Science,34(2), 565–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strom, K. (1992). Democracy as political competition. American Behavioral Scientist,35(4/5), 375–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tillie, J. (1995). Party utility and voting behavior. Amsterdam: Het Spinhuis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems: Veto players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science,25, 289–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tufte, E. R. (1975). Political control of the economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van der Eijk, C., & Oppenhuis, E. V. (1991). European parties’ performance in electoral competition. European Journal of Political Research,19(1), 55–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Visconti, F. (2018). The legislative representation of public opinion policy priorities in Italy. Italian Political Science Review/Rivista Italiana di Scienza Politica. https://doi.org/10.1017/ipo.2018.4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warwick, P. V. (1996). Coalition government membership in West European parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science,26(4), 471.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1977). Candidates with policy preferences: A dynamic model. Journal of Economic Theory,14(1), 180–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1983). Candidate motivation: A synthesis of alternative theories. The American Political Science Review,77(1), 142–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wlezien, C. (1995). The public as thermostat: Dynamics of preferences for spending. American Journal of Political Science,39(4), 981–1000.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wlezien, C. (2004). Patterns of representation: Dynamics of public preferences and policy. The Journal of Politics,66(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wlezien, C. (2005). On the salience of political issues: The problem with ‘Most Important Problem’. Electoral Studies,24, 555–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wlezien, C., & Soroka, S. N. (2003). Measures and models of budgetary policy. The Policy Studies Journal,31(2), 273–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wlezien, C., & Soroka, S. N. (2012). Political institutions and the opinion-policy link. West European Politics,35(6), 1407–1432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wlezien, C., et al. (2013). Polls and the vote in Britain. Political Studies,61, 66–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Several people provided helpful comments on this research and on older versions of this paper. Among others, I wish to thank Jim Adams, Shaun Bevan, Daniel Bischof, Mark Franklin, Sara Hobolt, Will Jennings, Laura Morales, Stuart Soroka, Rick Whitaker, and Chris Wlezien. Different versions of this paper were presented at the ECPR Joint Sessions 2013, ECPR General Conference 2013 and MPSA 2015, and I am grateful for the feedback received. Lastly, I wish to thank the editor and the two anonymous reviewers for helping me improve the final version of this research.

Funding

The research leading to these results has received funding from the European Research Council under the European Commission’s Seventh Framework Programme through a Starting Grant (FP7/2007-2013 Grant Agreement 284277) to the project “Democratic Responsiveness in Comparative Perspective: How Do Democratic Governments Respond to Different Expressions of Public Opinion? (ResponsiveGov)” (http://www.responsivegov.eu/) led by Prof Laura Morales.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luca Bernardi.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 1424 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bernardi, L. Policy Responsiveness and Electoral Incentives: A (Re)assessment. Polit Behav 42, 165–188 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-018-9490-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-018-9490-4

Keywords

Navigation