Skip to main content
Log in

Reforms, Exchange Rates and Monetary Commitment: A Panel Analysis for OECD Countries

  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper investigates the link between monetary policy and structural reforms in open economies. We test three hypotheses: (a) the Calmfors hypothesis that the degree of reforms is higher in the case of autonomous policy and lower in the case of commitment, (b) the TINA hypothesis which implies a positive impact of a monetary policy rule on the extent of reforms, and (c) a third factors hypothesis. In our empirical analysis on panel data of 23 OECD countries from 1980–2000 we find little evidence for the Calmfors hypothesis, but evidence in favor of the TINA argument for labor market and regulatory reform.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. OECD (2005) applies a consistent procedure to derive policy priorities to foster growth across OECD countries and identifies labor market reforms as being particularly important in, e.g., the Euro area. However, this does not at all imply that reforms in other areas are unimportant. Hence, we analyze a variety of different reform measures in the empirical part.

  2. We are grateful to an anonymous referee to point out this problem.

  3. Consistent with the implications of the imperfect competition/bargaining model of Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003), the estimates by Nicoletti and Scarpetta (2005) suggest that restrictive regulations have curbed employment rates significantly in countries where no product market reforms were implemented. These effects appear to have been magnified by the interaction of such regulations with labor market settings that provide a strong bargaining power to insiders, suggesting that rent sharing tends to depress employment. The implication is that significant employment gains can be obtained by deregulating product markets in overly regulated countries. Moreover, these employment gains are likely to be higher in countries that have rigid labor markets.

  4. A possible explanation is that, in the wake of liberalisation, employment is boosted both by the expansion of activity and entry and by a shrinking wage-productivity gap, as insiders lose their leverage on rents. When labor markets are more flexible, employment gains are smaller because they are obtained only through the first channel. This evidence is consistent with recent computable general equilibrium studies showing that the employment effects of deregulation are stronger in centralized bargaining settings than in decentralized ones.

  5. Again, we are grateful to an anonymous referee for this argument.

  6. Since we do not exclude complementarities among reforms ex ante, we see a clear need of controlling the starting institutional conditions in each country—the need for reforms.

  7. Ellis and Thoma (1990) estimate rational partisan theory approaches for open economies. In their study, party-specific inflation rates lead to party specific differences in exchange rate movements.

  8. The 23 OECD economies correspond to the category high-income industrialized countries in the World Development Indicators database (World Bank 2002) and cover Australia, Canada, the former EU-15, Iceland, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Switzerland and the United States.

  9. We use the chain-weighted EFW index (Gwartney et al. 2003), which corrects for the limited availability of some components over time. Such chain-linked correction is only available for the summary indicator, however. For the sub-areas money and banking system, government size, freedom to trade, market regulation and labor market regulation, we have to rely on uncorrected data instead. Missing data for indicator elements may distort the value of the sectoral indicators and distort the accuracy of these measures of economic reform.

  10. The de facto measure improves on the de jure classification of IMF (2003) since it takes into account that de jure exchange rate regimes are not necessarily applied in practice. This has especially been the case in developing, but also in industrialized countries. Austria, e.g., had a de facto fixed exchange rate regime vis-à-vis Germany for a long time without being a formal member of the exchange rate mechanism of the EMS. See Hochreiter and Tavlas (2005).

  11. Reinhart and Rogoff (2002) include freely falling rates as an additional category. We add the cases of freely falling rates to the free-float category, however.

  12. Note that the political constraints may restrict changes in either direction, however. They may limit both liberalization and the restriction of economic freedom. Further evidence may be derived from an interaction between political constraints and the government’s programmatic orientation. This extension is beyond the paper’s focus, however. Herz and Vogel (2005) and Pitlik (2004) provide an in-depth discussion of the impact of political constraints.

  13. The Sargan test for instrument validity is taken from the two-step estimates, however, because the one-step statistics tends to over-reject the test in the presence of heteroskedasticity (Arellano and Bond 1991).

  14. The effect is limited however. Given the estimates in Table 3, a one percentage-point inflation increase leads to 0.06 additional points on the reform index during the subsequent decade.

References

  • Alogoskoufis GS (1994) On inflation, unemployment and the optimal exchange rate regime. In: van der Ploeg F (ed) The handbook of international macroeconomics. Blackwell, Oxford, pp 192–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental variables estimation of error-component models. J Econom 68:29–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Gordon DB (1983) Rules, discretion and reputation in a model of monetary policy. J Monet Econ 12(1):101–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bean C (1998) The interaction of aggregate-demand policies and labor market reform. Swed Econ Policy Rev 5(2)

  • Beck T, Clarke G, Groff A, Keefer P, Walsh P (2001) New tools in comparative political economy: the database of political institutions. World Bank Econ Rev 15(1):165–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belke A, Gros D (1999) Estimating the costs and benefits of EMU: the impact of external shocks on labor markets. Weltwirtsch Arch 135:1–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Belke A, Kamp A (1999) When do labor market reforms achieve a double dividend under EMU? Discretionary versus rule based monetary policy revisited. J Econ Integr 14(4):572–605

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertola G, Boeri T (2001) EMU labor markets two years on: microeconomic tensions and institutional evolution. Paper presented at the workshop “The functioning of EMU: challenges of the early years” organized by the Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs, European Commission, Brussels, 21–22 March 2001, April 27th 2001 version

  • Blanchard O (2006) European unemployment—the evolution of facts and ideas. Econ Policy 45:5–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Giavazzi F (2003) Macroeconomic effects of regulations and deregulation in goods and labor markets. Q J Econ 118(3):879–907

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econom 87:115–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buscher H, Dreger C, Ramos R, Surinach J (2005) The impact of institutions on the employment performance in European labour markets. IZA Discussion Paper 1732, Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn

  • Calmfors L (1997) Unemployment, labor-market reform and EMU. IIES seminar paper 639. Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Calmfors L (1998) Macroeconomic policy, wage setting and employment—what difference does the EMU make? Oxford Economic Policy Review 14:125–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calmfors L, Holmlund B (2000) Unemployment and economic growth: a partial survey. Swed Econ Policy Rev 7:107–153

    Google Scholar 

  • Cukierman A (1992) Central bank strategy, credibility, and independence. MIT Press, Cambridge MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Daveri F, Tabellini G (2000) Unemployment, growth and taxation in industrial countries. Econ Policy 15:47–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A, Easterly W (2001) Do crises induce reform? Simple empirical tests of conventional wisdom. Econ Polit 13:139–157

    Google Scholar 

  • Duval R, Elmeskov J (2005) The effects of EMU on structural reforms in labor and product markets. OECD economics department working papers 438, Paris

  • Ebell M, Haefke C (2004) Product market deregulation and labour market outcomes. Swiss National Bank Working Papers 02.08

  • Ellis CJ, Thoma MA (1990) The implications for an open economy of partisan political business cycles: theory and evidence. University of Oregon Department of Economics Working Paper 90/2

  • Emerson M, Gros D, Italianer A, Pisani-Ferry J, Reichenbach H (1992) One market, one money. an evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming an economic and monetary union. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Freytag A (2005) The credibility of monetary reform: new evidence. Public Choice 121:319–409

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruener HS, Hefeker C (1996) Militant labor and inflation aversion—the impact of EMU on labor union interaction. University Bonn, SFB 303 Discussion Paper A-539

  • Gwartney J, Lawson R (2003) The concept and measurement of economic freedom. Eur J Polit Econ 19:405–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney J, Lawson R, Park W, Skipton C (2003) Economic freedom of the world: 2003 annual report. Fraser Institute, Vancouver

    Google Scholar 

  • Haffner RCG, Nickell S, Nicoletti G, Scarpetta S, Zoega G (2000) European integration, liberalisation and labour market performance: report for the Fondazione Rodolfo DeBenedetti

  • Henisz W (2000) The institutional environment for economic growth. Econ Polit 12(1):1–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henisz W (2002) The institutional environment for infrastructure investment. Ind Corp Change 11(2):355–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herz B, Vogel L (2005) Determinants of market-oriented policy reforms: an empirical analysis. mimeo

  • Hochreiter E, Tavlas GS (2005) The two roads to the euro: the monetary experiences of Austria and Greece. In: Schadler S (ed) Euro adoption in central and eastern Europe—opportunities and challenges. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsiao C (2003) Analysis of panel data. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2003) International financial statistics. CD-ROM. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2004) Fostering structural reforms in industrial countries. Chapter III in world economic outlook. Advancing structural reforms. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Koeniger W, Vindigni A (2003) Employment protection and product market regulation, WZB Economics Seminar Series, Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin

  • Kugler A, Pica G (2004) Effects of employment protection and product market regulation on the Italian labor market. Paper presented at the CEPR/ECB Workshop, June

  • Kydland FE, Prescott EC (1977) Rules rather than discretion: the inconsistency of optimal plans. J Polit Econ 85:473–491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Snower D (1997) Centralized bargaining, multi-tasking and work incentives. CEPR Discussion Paper 1563. Center for Economic Policy Research, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Lora E (2000) What makes reforms likely? Timing and sequencing of structural reforms in Latin America. Inter-American development bank working paper 424, Washington

  • Mélitz J (1997) The evidence about the costs and benefits of EMU. Swed Econ Policy Rev 4(2):191–234

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicoletti G, Scarpetta S (2005) Product market reforms and employment in OECD countries. OECD Economics Department Working Paper 472, Paris

  • OECD (2005) Economic policy reforms. Going for growth. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitlik H (2004) Are less constrained governments really more successful in executing market-oriented policy changes? Diskussionsbeiträge aus dem Institut für Volkswirtschaftslehre der Universität Hohenheim 255/2005. University Hohenheim, Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitlik H, Wirth S (2003) Do crises promote the extent of economic liberalization? Eur J Polit Econ 19(3):565–581

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart CM, Rogoff KS (2002) The modern history of exchange rate regime arrangements: a reinterpretation. NBER Working Paper 8963, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

  • Saint-Paul G, Bentolila S (2000) Will EMU increase eurosclerosis?, International macroeconomics and labour economics. CEPR Discussion Paper 2423, April, London

  • Sibert AC, Sutherland A (1997) Monetary regimes and labor market reform. CEPR Discussion Paper 1731, November, London

  • Svensson L (1997) Optimal inflation targets, “Conservative” central banks, and linear inflation contracts. Am Econ Rev 87:98–114

    Google Scholar 

  • van Poeck A, Borghijs A (2001) EMU and labor market reform: needs, incentives and realisations. Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh C (1995) Optimal contracts for independent central bankers. Am Econ Rev 85:150–167

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2002) World development indicators. World Bank Publications, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Jean-Yves Gnabo for his excellent and helpful discussion of an earlier version of this paper at the 10th International Conference on Macroeconomic Analysis and International Finance, May 25–27, 2006, Rethymno/Crete, and two anonymous referees for their stimulating comments and suggestions. We gratefully acknowledge the delivery of data from Stefan Pitlik and Andreas Freytag.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ansgar Belke.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Belke, A., Herz, B. & Vogel, L. Reforms, Exchange Rates and Monetary Commitment: A Panel Analysis for OECD Countries. Open Econ Rev 18, 369–388 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9042-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9042-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation