Skip to main content
Log in

Estimating the Equilibrium Effective Exchange Rate for Potential EMU Members

  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this study, we attempt to examine the possibility of emergence of significant fluctuations of the exchange rates in the future for the candidate EMU countries. In doing so, we estimate the equilibrium rate of the nominal effective exchange rate for Poland, Hungary, Slovak Republic and Malta through the BEER and PEER approaches. While the PEER-based estimation implies a large misalignment rate for the Hungarian forint, the BEER-based analysis shows that the present exchange rates of the countries considered do not deviate significantly from their equilibrium rates. As a consequence, based on BEER analysis, we do not expect large fluctuations in the effective exchange rates among the currencies considered. Hence, the relevant effective exchange rates are expected to be relatively stable. As a matter of fact, the entry of those countries into EMU is not expected to weaken the stability of Euro.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On January 1, 2007, Slovenia adopted the Euro.

  2. In this study we examine nominal effective exchange rates. However, the Maastricht exchange rate criterion does not deal with effective exchange rates. A successful entry into EMU requires stability in the bilateral rate against Euro. We argue that an unstable effective exchange rate may entail instability in bilateral exchange rates, such as this against Euro.

  3. The Fundamental Equilibrium Exchange Rate (FEER) was originally presented by Williamson (1985). This approach indicates that the exchange rate is at its equilibrium value when satisfies the condition of simultaneous internal and external balance. In other words, the Fundamental Equilibrium Exchange Rate is the equilibrium rate that would be consistent with ideal macroeconomic performance.

  4. The Deutsche mark is used as a proxy of Euro until 1999.

  5. This study examines the Czech crown/Deutsche mark rate by the NATREX approach, presented by Stein (1994). This rate is consistent with simultaneous internal and external balance and equates the sustainable current account with saving and investment.

  6. Clark and MacDonald (1998) and MacDonald (2000) assume that in the UIP condition a risk premium is included. This has a time-varying component, which reflects the relative supply of domestic to foreign debt. Here, due to lack of data availability we assume that the risk premium is equal to zero.

  7. A lot of criticism has been applied to the statistical properties of the H–P filter. One of the discussed issues is its poor performance near the end of the sample. Mise et. al. (2005), Kaiser and Maravall (1999) and Baxter and King (1999) provide evidence of suboptimal H–P filtering at the endpoints. To avoid this inconsistency, following Kaiser and Maravall (1999), we estimate optimal ARIMA forecasts and we apply the H–P filter to the extended series. As noted by Mise et. al. (2005), this approach minimizes revision standard deviation.

  8. Other studies use the Univariate and Multivariate Beveridge and Nelson (1995) Decomposition. This methodology entails the direct decomposition of the exchange rate into permanent and transitory components. Some of these studies are Huizinga (1987) and Cumby and Huizinga (1990). A different way of measuring PEERs is that proposed by Clarida and Gali (1994). They decompose the real exchange rate into supply, demand and nominal components and test the importance of these variables to the exchange rate. In other words, they create three shocks (supply, demand and nominal) and examine the effects of each shock to the variability of the exchange rate. Moreover, two of the studies, which applied the Gonlzalo–Granger approach to estimate PEERs are Clark and MacDonald (2000) and Hoffmann and MacDonald (2000).

  9. Since a VAR model is valid only when stationary variables are included, we regress VAR models in an error correction form by using the first differences of the variables. Robustness of the corresponding VEC models is confirmed since the residuals are non-autocorrelated, homoskedastic and normally distributed in each of the estimated models. Diagnostics’ tests are available on request.

  10. We test the restricted against the less restricted model using their computed trace statistics. These tests follow the X 2 distribution and the degrees of freedom are as shown below: \( 1 \sim 2{\left( {r\,{\text{d}}{\text{.f}}{\text{.}}} \right)},2 \sim 3{\left( {p - r\,{\text{d}}{\text{.f}}{\text{.}}} \right)},3 \sim 4{\left( {r\,{\text{d}}{\text{.f}}{\text{.}}} \right)},4 \sim 5{\left( {p - r\,{\text{d}}{\text{.f}}{\text{.}}} \right)} \) where r is the number of cointegrated vectors and p is the number of parameters.

  11. This test’s output is available on request.

  12. Based on the money multiplier theory, the amount of money (coins & notes) held by domestic residents, decreases. Since the monetary base (H) is equal to the sum of bank reserves (R) plus coins & notes held by domestic residents \( {\left( P \right)}{\left[ {H = R + P} \right]} \), monetary base declines. Thus, domestic money supply declines as well because money supply is equal to monetary base multiplied by the money multiplier. However, this holds only if the purchase of foreign bonds is financed by coins and notes. In case of an exchange between domestic and foreign bonds, monetary base remains unaffected.

  13. The robustness of this decomposition is confirmed because the summation of the permanent and the transitory components yields to unity. The estimation procedure is not presented here to save space. However, the analytical decomposition is available on request.

  14. See footnote 13.

  15. About the 78% of the foreign asset movements are permanent and only the 26% of the oil price fluctuation is permanent. To find more, see footnote 13.

  16. National Bank of Slovakia was fixing exchange rates of selected currencies during the period 1993–1998. Slovak crown was pegged on a basket of two currencies (60% of Deutsche mark and 40% of US dollar), and it was allowed to fluctuate by no more than 7%. Since October 1998, Slovak crown is freely determined in the foreign exchange market.

  17. About the 89% of the interest rate differential, the 81% of the foreign asset holding and the 99% of the oil price movements are permanent. To find more, see footnote 13.

  18. This finding should worry us about robustness of the trend-cycle decomposition. This is not a panacea, since alternative procedures can lead to different, and in some cases contradictory, estimates.

References

  • Alba JD, Park D (2003) Purchasing power parity in developing countries: multi-period evidence under the current float. World Dev 31(12):2049–2060

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arghyrou M, Boinet V, Martin C (2005) Beyond purchasing power parity: nominal exchange rates, output shocks and non linear/asymmetric equilibrium adjustment in Central Europe. In: 37th Annual Conference on Money Macro and Finance Research Group, 1–3 September, Crete

  • Bahmani-Oskooee M, Mirzai A (2000) Real and nominal effective exchange rates for developing countries: 1973:1–1997:3. Appl Econ 32:411–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baxter M, King R (1999). Measuring business cycles: approximate band-pass filters for economic time series. Rev Econ Stat 81:575–593

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beveridge S, Nelson RC (1995) A new approach to decomposition of economic time series into permanent and transitory components with particular attention to measurement of the ‘Business Cycle.’ J Monet Econ 7:151–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branson W (1977) Asset markets and relative prices in exchange rate determination. Sozwiss Ann 1:69–89

    Google Scholar 

  • Bulir A, Smidkova K (2005) Exchange rates in the new EU accession countries: what have we learned from the forerunners? IMF Working Paper 27

  • Clarida R, Gali J (1994) Sources of real exchange rate fluctuations: how important are nominal shocks? Carnegie-Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 41:1–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark P, MacDonald R (1998) Exchange rates and economic fundamentals: a methodological comparison of BEERs and FEERs. IMF Working Paper 67

  • Clark P, MacDonald R (2000) Filtering the BEER: a permanent and transitory decomposition. IMF Working Paper 144

  • Colletaz G, Serranito F (1998) Test of unit root with endogenous time break. http://www.estima.com/procindx.shtml

  • Coudert V, Couharde C (2002) Exchange rate regimes and sustainable parities for CEECs in the run-up to EMU membership. CEPII Working Paper Series 15

  • Cumby R, Huizinga J (1990) The predictability of real exchange rate changes in the short run and in the long run. NBER Working Paper 3468

  • Egert B (2002) Equilibrium real exchange rates in central Europe’s transition economies: knocking on heaven’s door. William Davidson Working Paper 480

  • Egert B, Lahreche-Revil A (2003) Estimating the fundamental equilibrium exchange rate of central and eastern European countries. The EMU enlargement perspective. CEPII Working Paper

  • Egert B, Lommatzsch K (2003) Equilibrium real exchange rates in acceding countries: how large is our confidence (interval)? Focus on Transition 2:107–137

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez F, Osbat C, Schnatz B (2001) Determinants of the Euro real effective exchange rate: A BEER/PEER approach. European Central Bank Working Paper 85

  • Frait J, Komarek L (2001) Real exchange rate trends in transitional countries. Warwick Economic Research Papers 596

  • Gonzalo J, Granger C (1995) Estimation of common long-memory components in cointegrated systems. J Bus Econ Stat 13:27–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckscher E (1916) Vaxelkurens grundval vid pappersmynfot. Economisk Tidskrift 18:309–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodrick RJ, Prescott EC (1997) Postwar US business cycles: an empirical investigation. J Money Credit Bank 29:1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffmann M, MacDonald R (2000) A real differential view of equilibrium real exchange rates and misalignments. Center for Financial Studies 08

  • Huizinga J (1987) An empirical investigation of the long run behavior of real exchange rates. Carnegie-Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 27:149–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1988) Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. J Econ Dyn Control 12:231–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1991) Estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegration vectors in gaussian vector autoregressive models. Econometrica 52:388–402

    Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1995) Likelihood-based inference in cointegrated vector autoregressive models. Oxford University Press

  • Kaiser R, Maravall A (1999) Estimation of the business cycle: a modified Hodrick–Prescott filter. Span Econ Rev 1:175–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanas A (2005) Modeling the US/UK real exchange rate—real interest rate differential relation: A multivariate regime switching approach. The Manchester School 73:123–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koukouritakis M, Michelis L (2005) Term structure linkages among the new EU countries and the EMU. University of Crete, Discussion Paper

  • MacDonald R (2002) Modelling the long-run real effective exchange rate of the New Zealand dollar. Reserve Bank of the New Zealand, Discussion Paper Series (DP2002/02)

  • MacKinnon J, Haug A, Michelis L (1999) Numerical distribution functions of likelihood ratio tests for cointegration. J Appl Econ 14:563–577

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahdavi S, Zhou S (1994) Purchasing power parity in high-inflation countries: further evidence. J Macroecon 16(3):403–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melecky M, Komarek L (2005) The behavioral equilibrium exchange rate of the Czech Koruna. University of New South Wales, Discussion Paper

  • Michael P, Nobay AR, Peel DA (1997) Transaction costs and nonlinear adjustment in real exchange rates: An empirical investigation. J Polit Econ 105:862–879

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mise E, Kim T, Newbold P (2005) On suboptimality of the Hodrick–Prescott filter at time-series endpoints. J Macroecon 27:53–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M, Taylor A (1997) Nonlinear aspects of goods-market arbitrage and adjustment: Heckscher’s commodity points revisited. J Jpn Int Econ 11:441–479

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perron P (1997) Further evidence on breaking trend functions in macroeconomic variables. J Econom 80:355–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarno L (2000) Real exchange rate behavior in the Middle East: a re-examination. Econ Lett 66:127–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarno L, Valente G, Wohar E (2004a) Monetary fundamentals and exchange rate dynamics under different nominal regimes. Econ Inq 42:179–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarno L, Taylor M, Chowdhury I (2004b) Nonlinear dynamics in deviations from the law of one price: A broad-based empirical study. J Int Money Financ 23:1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stein J (1994) The natural real exchange rate of the US Dollar and determinants of capital flows. In: Williamson J (eds) Estimating equilibrium exchange rates. Washington, DC, pp 133–176

  • Taylor M, Peel D, Sarno L (2001) Nonlinear mean-reversion in real exchange rates: toward a solution to the purchasing power parity puzzles. Int Econ Rev 42:1015–1042

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venus Khim-Sen Liew (2003) The validity of PPP revisited: an application of non-linear unit root test. Economics Working Paper Archive EconWPA, International Finance

  • Williamson J (1985) The exchange rate system. In: Policy analyses in international economics, vol. 5. Institute of International Economics, Washington

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Professor Zisimos Koustas for helpful comments on a previous draft of the paper. We also thank Dr. Minoas Koukouritakis for his assistance in computational methods. Of course, we are alone responsible for any remaining errors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nikolaos Giannellis.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Giannellis, N., Papadopoulos, A.P. Estimating the Equilibrium Effective Exchange Rate for Potential EMU Members. Open Econ Rev 18, 307–326 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9040-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9040-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation