Skip to main content
Log in

NGO research program: a collective action perspective

  • Published:
Policy Sciences Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper outlines a collective action approach to study nongovernmental organizations (NGOs). We contend that while political scientists and sociologists have extensively written about NGOs, they have not systematically examined fundamental collective action issues such as why and where NGOs emerge, how they function, how they are structured, and what strategies they employ to mitigate agency conflicts and ensure accountability. Instead of theorizing about NGOs as a category, NGO scholars have developed descriptive typologies relevant to study small subsets of the NGO population. In contrast, the non-profit literature, which studies broadly the same actor category, has systematically focused on fundamental questions inherent in any collective endeavor. We conclude that by employing a collective action perspective, specifically the theories of firm, NGO scholars will be able to develop explanations about NGO origin, structure, and strategy that have superior explanatory power and are generalizable across NGOs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In this context, the “economics of religion” literature, which conceptualizes the religion sector as a market characterized by producers (religious organizations) and consumers (religious adherents), is instructive. Scholars have applied the theories of firm to understand why denominations vary in their organizational forms, outreach strategies, and the supply of religious goods. For an overview, see Iannaccone (1998).

  2. By this we refer to beyond-compliance policies adopted by firms with the explicit objective of creating positive social externalities (Prakash and Potoski 2006).

  3. We do not subsume the social capital literature (Putnam 1993) under NGO politics literature because we are less interested in how social capital is created and deployed, and more interested in engaging with scholars who study how non-governmental actors directly influence public policy and provide collective goods and services.

  4. We recognize that some political scientists have produced exceptional work on governance and collective action that has the potential to be labeled as non-profit scholarship. Professor Ostrom (1990) is an obvious example, as her work focuses on governance of common-pool resources by non-market and non-state mechanisms. While some self-governance institutions studied by Professor Ostrom have characteristics of non-profits—they operate under the non-distributional constraint—some do not. For example, a farmers’ cooperative established to manage a common pool resource might distribute all of its profits to its member. While it is a self-governing institution, it is not a non-profit because it violates the non-distributional constraint. In sum, while various governance literatures in political science might overlap with the non-profit literature, the former cannot be subsumed under the latter.

  5. Social movement literature is popular in political science as well. Incidentally, Professor Tarrow is a Professor of Political Science (Government) and Sociology at Cornell University.

  6. Political scientists and sociologists have tended to view NGOs primarily as physical organizations, not as rule structures. Consequently, they tend not to focus on the institutional dimensions of these actors. In contrast, the non-profit literature implicitly recognized that prior to examining non-profits as organizations, scholars must figure out these organizations’ institutional foundations. Non-profit scholars therefore have paid considerable attention to collective action issues germane for this institutional category.

  7. While we respect the heterodoxy of views on generalizable theories, we do not think that this “area studies approach” is an analytically useful way to study NGOs. Lessons from one “area” are seldom useful for the study of other areas because every area is supposed to be analytically unique and therefore needs a different theory. As a result, NGO scholars tend to overlook opportunities to cumulate knowledge about NGOs as a category of collective actors and employ insights from other types of collective action to study NGOs.

  8. Indeed, Salamon and Anheier (1998a, b) made a similar appeal for developing and testing a generalizable theory of non-profit organizations that would link nonprofit studies to “bodies of thought of central concern to social science more generally” (1998a, p. 281).

  9. Chandler (1977) identifies two phases in the development of the American business organization: the pre-1850 phase of the market economy and the post-1850 phase of managerial capitalism. Chandler masterfully documents how the “visible hand” of the modern firm economized on administrative costs in relation to economic exchanges via the “invisible hand.” For him, the railroads were the first modern industrial enterprise embodying managerial capitalism.

  10. Moreover, other non-profit scholars point to an inverse relationship between trust in the government and non-profit formation and participation. In this view, higher numbers of non-profits emerge when trust in government is low (Brooks and Lewis 2001) or when dissatisfaction with the quality or quantity of public or private services is high (Douglas 1987).

  11. The U.S. regulatory environment has anticipated this problem. To discourage “excessive” executive compensation in non-profits, the 1996 Federal Taxpayer Bill grants the IRS the authority to impose penalties in this regard (Barragato 2002).

  12. Research on executive compensation in non-profits is seeking to explore this issue. Frumkin and Keating (2004) find that executive compensation is higher in non-profits with free cash flows and with stronger financial performance. This violates the non-distributional constraint and therefore is indicative of agency problems.

  13. Also, see Niskanen’s (1971) budget maximizing model of public bureaucracies.

  14. For different types of accountability, also see Grant and Keohane (2005, pp. 35–37).

References

  • Barney, J. B. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17, 99–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P. (2003). Private politics. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 12, 31–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barragato, C. (2002). Linking for-profit and non-profit executive compensation. Voluntas, 13, 301–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Ner, A. (1986). Nonprofit organizations: Why do they exist in market economies? In S. Rose-Ackerman (Ed.), The economics of nonprofit institutions: Studies in structure and policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Ner, A. (2004). For-profit, state, and nonprofit: How to cut the pie among the three sectors. Presented at Centre Saint-Gobain for Economic Studies Conference, Public Sector, Private Sector: New National and International Frontiers. Paris, October 2–3, 2003.

  • Berle, A. A., & Means, G. C. (1932). The modern corporation and private property. New York: Harcourt, Brace & World.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, A. C., & Lewis, G. B. (2001). Giving, volunteering, and mistrusting government. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 20, 765–770.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A. D. (1962). Strategy and structure. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, A. D., Jr. (1977). The visible hand: The managerial revolution in American business. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Belknap.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, R. A., & Ebrahim, A. (2006). How does accountability affect mission? The case of a nonprofit serving immigrants and refugees. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 17, 195–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clifford, B. (2005). The marketing of rebellion: Insurgents, media, and international activism. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooley, A., & Ron, J. (2002). The NGO scramble: Organizational insecurity and the political economy of transnational action. International Security, 27, 5–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Covey, J. G. (1995). Accountability and effectiveness of NGO policy alliance. Boston: Institute for Development Research, IDR Reports, 11.

  • Dalton, T., Recchia, S., & Rohrschneider, R. (2003). The environmental movement and the modes of political action. Comparative Political Studies, 36, 743–771.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. J., & Anheier, H. K. (1990). The sociology of nonprofit organizations and sectors. Annual Review of Sociology, 16, 137–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Douglas, J. (1987). Political theories of nonprofit organizations. In W. W. Powell (Ed.), The nonprofit sector: A research handbook. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyer, J. H. (1996). Does governance matter? Keiretsu alliances and asset specificity as sources of Japanese competitive advantage. Organization Science, 7, 649–666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebrahim, A. (2003a). Making sense of accountability: Conceptual perspectives for Northern and Southern nonprofits. Nonprofit Management and Leadership, 14, 191–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebrahim, A. (2003b). Accountability in practice: Mechanisms for NGOs. World Development, 31, 813–829.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebrahim, A. (2005). Institutional preconditions to collaboration: Indian forest and irrigation policy in historical perspective. Administration and Society, 36, 208–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, M., & Hulme, D. (1996). Too close for comfort? The impact of official aid on nongovernmental organizations. World Development, 24, 961–973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E., & Jensen, M. (1983). Separation of ownership and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 301–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Florini, A. (Ed.) (2000). The third force: The rise of transnational civil society. Washington, D.C.: The Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fowler, A. (1997). Striking a balance: A guide to the effective management of NGOs in international development. London: Earthscan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frumkin, P., & Keating, E. (2004). The effectiveness of regulating governance. The case of executive compensation in non-profit organizations. http://www.ksghome.harvard.edu/∼ekeatin/papers/Regulating%20Governance.pdf. Accessed on April 26, 2007.

  • Gamson, W. A. (1975). The strategy of political protest. Homewood, IL: Dorsey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goddeeris, J. H., & Weisbrod, B. A. (1998). Conversion from nonprofit to for-profit legal status: Why does it happen and should anyone care? Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 17, 215–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grant, R., & Keohane, R. (2005). Accountability and abuses of power in world politics. American Political Science Review, 99, 29–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P. D. (1982). The organization of American culture, 1700–1900. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamel, G., & Prahald, C. K. (1990). Core competence of the corporation. Harvard Business Review, 68, 79–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Handy, F., & Katz, E. (1998). The wage differential between nonprofits institutions and corporations. Journal of Comparative Economics, 26, 246–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann, H. (1987). Economic theories of nonprofit organizations. In W. W. Powell (Ed.), The nonprofit sector: A research handbook. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, S. L. (2002). Selling civil society: Western aid and the nongovernmental organization sector in Russia. Comparative Political Studies, 35, 139–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, voice, and loyalty. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. (1998). Introduction to the economics of religion. Journal of Economic Literature, XXXVI, 1465–1496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keck, M. E., & Sikkink, K. (1998). Activists beyond borders: Advocacy networks in international politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, G., Keohane, R., & Verba, S. (1994). Designing social enquiry. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, J. (1992). Institutions and social conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, D., & Wallace, T. (Eds.) (2000). New roles and relevance: Development NGOs and the challenge of change. Bloomfield, CT: Kumarian Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipsky, M. (1968). Protest as a political resource. American Political Science Review, 62, 114–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manne, H. (1965). Mergers and the market for corporate control. Journal of Political Economy, 73, 110–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marris, R. L. (1964). The economic theory of ‘managerial’ capitalism. London: Free Press of Glencoe.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAdam, D. (1996). Conceptual origin, current problems, future directions. In D. McAdam, J. D. McCarthy, & M. N. Zald (Eds.), Comparative perspectives on social movements. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAdam, D. (1997). Tactical innovation and the pace of insurgency. In D. McAdam & D. Snow (Eds.), Social movements: Readings on their emergence, mobilization and dynamics. Los Angeles: Roxbury.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAdam, D., McCarthy, J. D., & Zald, M. N. (Eds.) (1996). Comparative perspectives on social movements. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAdam, D., Tarrow, S., & Tilly, C. (2001). Dynamics of contention. New york: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCarthy, J. D. (1995). Constraints and opportunities in adopting, adapting, inventing. In D. McAdam, J. D. McCarthy, & M. N. Zald (Eds.), Comparative perspectives on social movements. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCarthy, J. D., & Zald, M. (1977). Resource mobilization and social movements. American Journal of Sociology, 82, 1212–1241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendelson, S. E., & Glenn, J. K. (Eds.) (2002). The power and limits of NGOs. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, J. W., Boli, J., Thomas, G. M., & Ramirez, F. O. (1997). World society and the nation-state. American Journal of Sociology, 103, 144–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, C. A. (1999). The economics and politics of NGOs in Latin America. Westport, CT: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G. J. (1993). Managerial dilemmas. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T. M. (1984). The new economics of organization. American Journal of Political Science, 28, 739–777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T. M. (2005). Power and political institutions. Perspectives on Politics, 3, 215–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. Jr. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Regan, K., & Oster, S. (2002). Does government funding alter non-profit governance? Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 21, 359–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1960[1920]). The economics of welfare. London: MacMillan & Co. Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prakash, A. (2000). Greening the firm. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prakash, A., & Potoski, M. (2006). The voluntary environmentalists. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Price, R. (2003). Transnational civil society and advocacy in world politics. World Politics, 55, 579–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D. (1993). Making democracy work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Remmer, K. (2004). Does foreign aid promote the expansion of government? American Journal of Political Science, 48, 77–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rohrschnieder, R., & Dalton, T. (2002). A global network? Journal of Politics, 54, 510–533.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ron, J., Ramos, H., & Rodgers, K. (2005). Transnational information politics: NGO human rights reporting, 1986–2000. International Studies Quarterly, 49(3), 557–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, M. (2001). Does oil hinder democracy? World Politics, 53, 325–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salamon, L. M., & Anheier, H. (1998a). Social origins of civil society: Explaining the nonprofit sector cross-nationally. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 9(3), 213–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salamon, L. M., & Anheier, H. (1998b). On developing comparative nonprofit sector theory: A reply to Steinberg and Young, and Ragin. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations, 9,(3) 271–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sasser, E., Prakash, A., Cashore, B., & Auld, G. (2006). Direct targeting as NGO political strategy: Examining private authority regimes in the forestry sector. Business and Politics, 8, 1–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sell, S. K., & Prakash, A. (2004). Using ideas strategically. International Studies Quarterly, 48, 143–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, S., & Lipsky, M. (1995). Non-profits for hire. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spar, D., & Dail, J. (2002). Of measurement and mission: Accounting for performance in non-governmental organizations. Chicago Journal of International Law, 3, 171–182.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sperling, V. (1998). Foreign funding of social movements in Russia. Program on new approaches to Russian Security Policy Memo Series No. 26. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

  • Tarrow, S. G. (1998a). Contentious politics and social movements. In S. G. Tarrow (Ed.), Power in movement: Social movements and contentious politics (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarrow, S. G. (Ed.) (1998b) Power in movement: Social movements and contentious politics (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarrow, S. (2001). Transnational politics: Contention and institutions in international politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 4, 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vakil, A. C. (1997). Confronting the classification problem: Toward a taxonomy of NGOs. World Development, 25, 2057–2070.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wapner, P. (1995). Politics without borders: Environmental activism and world civic politics. World Politics, 47, 311–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wapner, P. (2002). Defending accountability mechanisms in NGOs. Chicago Journal of International Law, 3, 191–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisbrod, B. A. (1991). The nonprofit economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisbrod, B. A. (1997). The future of the nonprofit sector: Its entwining with private enterprise and government. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 16, 541–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weisbrod, B. A. (1998). Modeling the nonprofit organization as a multiproduct firm: A framework for choice. In B. A. Weisbrod (Ed.) To profit or not to profit: The commercial transformation of the nonprofit sector. Chicago: Northwestern University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies, analysis and antitrust implications: A study in the economics of internal organization. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1986). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, D. R. (1998). Commercialism in nonprofit social service organizations: Its character, significance, and rationale. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 17, 278–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

We thank Matt Auer, Kristin Bakke, David Baron, Brenda Bushouse, Margaret Levi, Tom Lyon, Elinor Ostrom, Steve Pfaff, Gary Segura, and Oran Young for comments. Previous versions of this paper were presented at the 2006 annual conference of the Midwest Political Science Association and the University of Michigan Business School.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aseem Prakash.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Johnson, E., Prakash, A. NGO research program: a collective action perspective. Policy Sci 40, 221–240 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-007-9043-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-007-9043-x

Keywords

Navigation