Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The generation and exploitation of technological change: market value and total factor productivity

  • Published:
The Journal of Technology Transfer Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we articulate and test the hypothesis that TFP is a reliable and relevant measure of firm’s innovation capabilities, and, as such, accounts for Tobin’s q indicator. With this aim, we investigate empirically the relationship between firm level total factor productivity and the Tobin’s q. Measuring Tobin’s q allows inferring the actual value of knowledge capital from stock market valuation. We use a panel of companies listed on UK and the main continental Europe financial markets (Germany, France and Italy) for the period 1995–2005. Our results confirm that TFP is a reliable indicator of firm’s innovative capabilities. When we control for firm’s R&D investments and intangible assets, the effects of TFP on market value remain highly significant. This suggests that TFP is a broader measure of innovation capability than R&D is. The validation of the Tobin’s q and TFP relationship has important implications concerning firm’s technological innovation measurement.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Tangible&intangible assets include all assets of the firm, both tangible and intangible. In Cockburn and Griliches (1988) and subsequent works, these assets are referred to as tangible capital or tangible assets. Hall et al. (2005) name them physical capital. In empirical analyses then different approaches are used in order to compute this variable: total fixed assets is used in Cockburn and Griliches (1988); net plant and equipment, inventories, and investments in unconsolidated subsidiaries, intangibles, and other in Hall et al. (2005); sum of property, plant, and equipment, inventory, and net working capital in Megna and Kloch (1993); total tangible assets in Hall and Oriani (2006). We chose the tangible&intangible assets definition for stressing that in our model we mean to include both tangible and intangible assets.

  2. These data were originally published and described in Van Ark (1995).

  3. As reviewed in Hall et al. (2010) two major approaches have been followed in order to estimate production functions. The first is the primal approach that estimates a production function using quantities as inputs and measures technical progress by means of total factor productivity. The second is the dual approach where technology is represented by a dual cost function that is used to derive the factor demand and the output supply equations. Our estimation of the production function follows the first approach. Yet, while the approach described in Hall et al. (2010) assumes that in the linear model the log of technical progress can be written as the sum of a firm-specific effect ωi and a time effect λt, in our approach the residual of the linear model representing TFP is assumed to be the sum of a productivity shock ωit, introducing an explicit behavioral hypothesis in the estimation procedure, and a random shock.

  4. A 15% depreciation rate is the most common value used in the literature. As a robustness check we also experimented with alternative (higher) depreciation rates. We found that the depreciation rate value makes little difference in empirical estimations as already discussed in Griliches and Mairesse (1984).

  5. Different assumptions on g did not significantly affect our results.

  6. We owe this comment to a Referee.

  7. We are indebted to Bronwyn Hall for crucial suggestions on this point.

References

  • Antonelli, C., & Quatraro, F. (2010). The effects of biased technological change on total factor productivity. Empirical evidence from a sample of OECD countries. The Journal of Technology Transfer, 35(4), 361–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C., & Teubal, M. (2008). Knowledge intensive property rights and the evolution of venture capitalism. Journal of Institutional Economics, 4, 163–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balasubramanyan, L., & Mohan, S. (2009). How well is productivity being priced? Journal of Economics and Finance. doi:10.1007/s12197-009-9083-5.

  • Bessen, J. (2008). The value of US patents by owner and patent characteristics. Research Policy, 37, 932–945.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, C. (2005). R&D investment and internal finance: The cash flow effect. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 15, 213–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, C. (2008). The market valuation of knowledge assets. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 17, 269–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Bond, S., Devereux, M., & Schiantarelli, F. (1992). Investment and Tobin’s Q. Journal of Econometrics, 51, 233–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Griffith, R., & Van Reenen, J. (1999). Market share, market value and innovation in a panel of British manufacturing firms. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 529–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassia, L., Colombelli, A., & Paleari, S. (2009). Firms’ growth: Does the innovation system matter? Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 20, 211–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cefis, E., & Ciccarelli, M. (2005). Profit differentials and innovation. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 15, 43–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coad, A., & Rao, R. (2006). Innovation and market value: A quantile regression analysis. Economics Bulletin, 15, 1–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cockburn, I., & Griliches, Z. (1988). Industry effects and appropriability measures in the stock market’s valuation of R&D and patents. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 78, 419–423.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corrado, C., Hulten, C., & Daniel Sichel, D. (2005). Measuring capital and technology: An expanded framework. In C. Corrado, J. Haltwinger, & D. Sichel (Eds.), Measuring capital in the new economy, studies in income and wealth (Vol. 65, pp. 11–41). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corrado, C., Hulten, C., & Daniel Sichel, D. (2006). Intangible capital and economic growth. NBER working paper no. 11948. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Corrado, C., Hulten, C., & Sichel, D. (2009). Intangible capital and US economic growth. Review of Income and Wealth, 55, 661–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crépon, B., Duguet, E., & Mairesse, J. (1998). Research and development, innovation and productivity: An econometric analysis at the firm level. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 7, 115–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dwyer, D. W. (2001). Plant-level productivity and the market value of a firm. Working paper no. 01-03, Center for Economic Studies, US Census Bureau.

  • Griliches, Z. (1981). Market value, R&D and patents. Economics Letters, 7, 183–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1984). R&D, patents and productivity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z., & Mairesse, J. (1984). Productivity and R&D at the firm level. In Z. Griliches (Ed.), R&D, patents, and productivity. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H. (1990). The manufacturing sector masterfile: 19591987. NBER working paper no. 3366, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

  • Hall, B. H. (1993). The stock market’s valuation of R&D investment during the 1980s. American Economic Review, 83, 259–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H., Jaffe, A. B., & Trajtenberg, M. (2005). Market value and patent citations. RAND Journal of Economics, 36, 16–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H., & Mairesse, J. (2006). Empirical studies of innovation in the knowledge-driven economy. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 15, 289–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H., Mairesse, J., & Mohnen, P. (2010). Returns to R&D and productivity. In B. H. Hall & N. Rosemberg (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of innovation (Vol. 2). North-Holland: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B. H., & Oriani, R. (2006). Does the market value R&D investment by European firms? Evidence from a panel of manufacturing firms in France, Germany, and Italy. International Journal of Industrial Organisation, 24, 971–993.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B. (1986). Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: Evidence from firms’ patents, profits, and market value. American Economic Review, 76, 984–1001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, H., Lim, H., & Park, Y. (2009). How should firms carry out technological diversification to improve their performance? An analysis of patenting of Korean firms. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 18(8), 757–770.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magri, S. (2009). The financing of small innovative firms: The Italian case. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 18, 24–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1965). Rates of return from industrial research and development. American Economic Review, 55, 310–322.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J. C. (1991). Exploration and exploitation in organizing learning. Organization Science, 2, 71–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Megna, P., & Klock, M. (1993). The impact of intangible capital on Tobin’s Q in the semiconductor industry. American Economic Review, 83, 265–269.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olley, G. S., & Pakes, A. (1996). The dynamics of productivity in the telecommunications equipment industry. Econometrica, 64, 1263–1297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shane, H., & Klock, M. (1997). The relation between patent citations and Tobin’s Q in the semiconductor industry. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 9, 131–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tobin, J. (1978). Monetary policies and the economy: The transmission mechanism. Southern Economic Journal, 37, 421–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Toivanen, O., Stoneman, P., & Bosworth, D. (2002). Innovation and the market value of UK firms, 1989–1995. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 64, 39–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trajtenberg, M. (1990). A penny for your quotes: Patent citation and the value of innovations. RAND Journal of Economics, 21, 172–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Ark, B. (1995). Sectoral growth accounting and structural change in Post-War Europe. In B. Van Ark & N. F. R. Crafts (Eds.), Quantitative aspects of Post-War European economic growth (pp. 84–164). Cambridge: CEPR/Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors wish to thank Bronwyn Hall, Raffaele Paci and Fabiano Schivardi for useful suggestions. Preliminary versions have been presented at CRENoS-DECA seminar series, University of Cagliari, and the AFSE 2009 tematic meeting, Sophia Antipolis. We are grateful for the useful comments of many participants. The financial support of the Collegio Carlo Alberto and the Dipartimento di Economia dell’università di Torino is acknowledged. The research leading to these results has received funding from the European Community’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007-2013) under grant agreement no. 216813.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alessandra Colombelli.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Table 10.

Table 10 Sectoral concordance table

Appendix 2: Robustness check, TFP series constructed under the assumption of constant returns to scale in production

See Tables 11, 12, and 13.

Table 11 Basic market value OLS, NLLS and FE regressions with dependent variable = log(q)
Table 12 Market value OLS, NLLS and FE regressions with dependent variable = log(q) controlling for R&D
Table 13 Market value OLS, NLLS and FE regressions with dependent variable = log(q) controlling for R&D and intangible assets

Appendix 3: Robustness check, TFP series constructed using sectoral elasticities

See Tables 14, 15, and 16.

Table 14 Basic market value OLS, NLLS and FE regressions with dependent variable = log(q)
Table 15 Market value OLS, NLLS and FE regressions with dependent variable = log(q) controlling for R&D
Table 16 Market value OLS, NLLS and FE regressions with dependent variable = log(q) controlling for R&D and intangible assets

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Antonelli, C., Colombelli, A. The generation and exploitation of technological change: market value and total factor productivity. J Technol Transf 36, 353–382 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-010-9198-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-010-9198-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation