Skip to main content
Log in

Technology transfer offices and university patenting in Sweden and Germany

  • Published:
The Journal of Technology Transfer Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyses the factors that impact on the decision of researchers to patent their research results. Particular emphasis is put on the role of technology transfer offices. It builds on a survey of university professors in Sweden and Germany. The regression results show that researchers that received support from the public infrastructure and researchers that have experience with the patenting system—through own previous patents or joint patent applications with firms—are much more likely to apply for patents.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The support infrastructure has changed recently. The TBS were merged and the Innovationsbron (Innovation Bridge) was established. Innovationsbron supports researchers that want to commercialise research results through incubator services and the provision of seed capital. Innovationsbron is owned by the Swedish state (84%) and Industrifonden (16%).

  2. The study includes public actors that are the functional equivalent to TTOs such as the university holding companies in Sweden.

  3. Particularly relevant are OECD (1999, 2002, 2003a, b) and European Commission (2001). For a more detailed review, see Sellenthin (2006).

  4. Knowledge and technology transfer has been a widely debated issue in Sweden, see for instance SOU (1996), VINNOVA (2003), SOU (2005).

  5. A number of studies focus on knowledge and technology transfer in Germany, see for instance Schmoch et al. (2000), Czarnitzki et al. (2000), Beise and Stahl (1999), Cohausz et al. (1998).

  6. Patenting and licensing of university research has been an important topic in the US for quite a long time. Thus, there are a number of studies that are important for the context of this paper, such as Bozeman (2000), Bercovitz et al. (2001), Carlsson and Fridh (2002), Jensen and Thursby (2001), Mowery et al. (2001), Siegel et al. (2003).

  7. The dominating view on commercialisation of university research is that researchers should act like entrepreneurs. Henrekson and Rosenberg (2000, p. 11) claim that the main reason why commercialisation is more successful in USA compared to Sweden is that entrepreneurial culture is more developed in the US. One of their suggestions to increase commercial activity of universities is to change the content of academic courses and the allocation of funding for conducting research towards the demands of private industry.

  8. Holmstrom and Milgrom (1991, 1994) developed the multiple principal-agent theory.

  9. The principal—in our case the university—delegates tasks to an agent—in our case the researcher. Problems arise in such a situation if the principal cannot observe the behaviour and performance of the agent. This measurement problem is the result of asymmetric information between principal and agent and the costs of control. Both factors mean that the agent can exploit the information asymmetries resulting in behaviour that is not fully in accordance with the principal’s objectives.

  10. Please note that we talk about relative pay-offs in this context. Researchers receive usually a fixed wage. But the opportunity costs associated with the three different tasks are likely to be different which can result in different relative wage rates for each of the activities. E.g., researchers who never interacted with industry will have high costs in terms of time and effort needed to accomplish the third mission. In contrast, researchers are used to publish papers, which results in low costs in terms of time and effort. The individual costs associated with the different activities depend pretty much on individual factors, such as experience. The individual productivity of the different tasks has an impact on those individual costs.

  11. For example, VINNOVA (2003, p. 14) shows that at Stanford University about 15% of the research based projects in which resources were invested for patenting and commercialisation (via licenses or start-ups) “produced” benefits that covered the costs. Less than 0.5% resulted in returns larger than 50 million SEK. But one single project generated about 5% of Stanford’s research budget in about 10 years. This means that a limited number of university patents generate the majority of license income.

  12. The chi-square tests applied in this paper test whether the differences between Sweden and Germany are statistically significant.

  13. There are large selection effects in Sweden. In contrast to Germany, where the researchers have to notify the university in the case of an invention, the researchers in Sweden can commercialise on their own. This means the supporting infrastructure in Sweden does not possess information about all patenting and commercialisation efforts.

  14. This is in line with the argument by Gering & Schmoch (2003) that a major reason to seek patent protection for Fraunhofer institutes in Germany is to attract research grants and contracts. Patents are regarded as a signal about the research competence.

References

  • Beise, M., & Stahl, H. (1999). Public research and industrial innovations in Germany. Research Policy, 28, 397–422. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(98)00126-7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bercovitz, J., Feldman, M., Feller, I., & Burton, R. (2001). Organizational structure as a determinant of academic patent and licensing behavior: An exploratory study of Duke, Johns Hopkins, and Pennsylvania State universities. The Journal of Technology Transfer, 26, 21–35. doi:10.1023/A:1007828026904.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bozeman, B. (2000). Technology transfer and public policy: A review of research and theory. Research Policy, 29, 627–655. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00093-1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bundesministerium für Bildung und Forschung (BMBF). (2001). Knowledge creates markets—action scheme of the German Goverment, Bonn.

  • Carlsson, B., & Fridh, A. C. (2002). Technology transfer in United States universities: A survey and statistical analysis. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 12, 199–232. doi:10.1007/s00191-002-0105-0.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohausz, Hannig, Dawidowicz, & Partner. (1998). Untersuchung zum Verwertungsprivileg – Relevanz des sog. Hochschullehrerprivilegs nach § 42 ArbNErfG. Gutachten im Auftrag des Bundesministeriums für Bildung, Wissenschaft, Forschung und Technologie, Düsseldorf (Investigation of the relevance of the university teachers’ privilege).

  • Czarnitzki, D., Rammer, C., & Spielkamp, A. (2000). Interaktion zwischen Wissenschaft und Wirtschaft in Deutschland. Ergebnisse einer Umfrage bei Hochschulen und öffentlichen Forschungseinrichtungen. Mannheim: ZEW-Dokumentation Nr. 00-14, ZEW.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P., & David, P. (1987). Information disclosure and the economics of science and technology. In G. R. Feiwel (Ed.), Arrow and the ascent of modern economic theory. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P., & David, P. (1994). Toward a new economics of science. Research Policy, 23(5), 487–521. doi:10.1016/0048-7333(94)01002-1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2001). Benchmarking industry-science relations—the role of framework conditions. Final Report, Vienna/Mannheim.

  • Gering, T., & Schmoch, U. (2003). Management of intellectual assets by German public research organisations, in OECD, turning science into business: Patenting and licensing at Public Research Organisations. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geuna, A. (1999). The economics of knowledge production: Funding and the structure of university research. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153–161. doi:10.2307/1912352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrekson, M., & Rosenberg, N. (2000). Akademiskt entreprenörskap. SNS Förlag.

  • Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, W. P. (1991). Multitask principal-agent analyses. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 7(Special Issue), 24–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, W. P. (1994). The firm as an incentive system. The American Economic Review, 84, 972–991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B. (1989). Real effects of academic research. The American Economic Review, 79(5), 957–970.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, R., & Thursby, M. (2001). Proofs and prototypes for sale: The tale of university licensing. The American Economic Review, 91, 240–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kienbaum. (2006). Abschlussbericht: “Weiterentwicklung von Kriterien sowie Datenerhebung auf der Basis der Kriterien und Datenauswertung bezüglich der Kompetenz und Leistungsfähigkeit der Patent- und Verwertungsagenturen”. Düsseldorf: Kienbaum Management.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebeskind, J., Oliver, A., Zucker, L. G., & Brewer, M. (1996). Social networks, learning, and flexibility: Sourcing scientific knowledge in new biotechnology firms. Organization Science, 7, 428–443. doi:10.1287/orsc.7.4.428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Link, A. N., & Siegel, D. S. (2005). Generating science-based growth: An econometric analysis of the impact of organizational incentives on university-industry technology transfer. European Journal of Finance, 11, 169–182. doi:10.1080/1351847042000254211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Link, A. N., Siegel, D. S., & Bozeman, B. (2007). An empirical analysis of the propensity of academics to engage in informal university technology transfer. Industrial and Corporate Change, 16(4), 641–655. doi:10.1093/icc/dtm020.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1995). Academic research underlying industrial innovations: Sources, characteristics, and financing. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 77, 55–65. doi:10.2307/2109992.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1998). Academic research and industrial innovation: An update of empirical findings. Research Policy, 26, 773–776. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(97)00043-7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markman, G. D., Gianiodis, P. T., & Phan, P. H. (2008). Full-time faculty or part-time entrepreneurs. IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 55(1), 29–36. doi:10.1109/TEM.2007.912813.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mowery, D. C., Nelson, R. R., Sampat, B. N., & Ziedonis, A. A. (2001). The growth of patenting and licensing by U.S. universities: An assessment of the effects of the Bayh-Dole act of 1980. Research Policy, 30, 99–119. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(99)00100-6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (1999). University research in transition. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2002). Benchmarking industry-science relationships. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2003a). Governance of public research. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2003b). Turning science into business: Patenting and licensing at public research organisations. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Owen-Smith, J., & Powell, W. W. (2001). To patent or not: Faculty decisions and institutional success at technology transfer. The Journal of Technology Transfer, 26, 99–114. doi:10.1023/A:1007892413701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen-Smith, J., & Powell, W. W. (2003). The expanding role of university patenting in the life sciences: Assessing the importance of experience and connectivity. Research Policy, 32, 1695–1711. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(03)00045-3.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, W. W. (1990). Neither market nor hierarchy: Network forms of organization. Research in Organizational Behavior, 12, 295–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • RRV. (2001). Från forskning till tillväxt – statligt stöd till samverkan mellan högskola och näringsliv. Stockholm: Riksrevisionsverket.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandven, T., & Smith, K. (1998). Using Community Innovation Survey data for empirical analysis—data reliability and issues for analysts. IDEA Paper Series No. 4, STEP, Oslo.

  • Schild, I. (1999). A regional patent study to investigate inventive activity in East Gothia. Working Paper No. 207. Linköping: Department of Technology and Social Change, Linköping University.

  • Schmoch, U., Licht, G., & Reinhard, M. (Eds.). (2000). Wissens- und Technologietransfer in Deutschland. Stuttgart: Fraunhofer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sellenthin, M. O. (2006). Beyond the Ivory Tower: A comparison of patent rights regimes in Sweden and Germany. Doctoral dissertation, Department of Technology and Social Change, Linköping.

  • Siegel, D., Waldman, D., & Link, A. (2003). Assessing the impact of organizational practices on the relative productivity of university technology transfer offices: An exploratory study. Research Policy, 32, 27–48. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00196-2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • SOU. (1996). Samverkan mellan högskolan och näringslivet. Huvudbetänkande av NYFOR. Stockholm: Fritzes.

    Google Scholar 

  • SOU. (2005). Nyttiggörande av högskoleuppfinningar. Utredningen om rätten till resultaten av högskoleforskningen. Stockholm: Fritzes.

    Google Scholar 

  • VINNOVA. (2003). VINNFORSK – VINNOVAs förslag till förbättrad kommersialisering och ökad avkastning i tillväxt på forskningsinvesteringar vid högskolor. Stockholm: VINNOVA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

Comments from the editor as well as two anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mark O. Sellenthin.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sellenthin, M.O. Technology transfer offices and university patenting in Sweden and Germany. J Technol Transf 34, 603–620 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-009-9108-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10961-009-9108-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation