Skip to main content
Log in

The Subjectivity Inherent in Objective Measures of Well-Being

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Happiness Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Man is far too clever to be able to survive without wisdom

E. F. Schumacher

Abstract

Claims abound that GDP accounting ignores social and ecological problems and misrepresents social well-being. While GDP growth continues to be a policy priority in most countries, it is at best one objective among many in achieving humanity’s “ultimate purpose.” Yet revisions to the income accounts and alternative well-being indicators are also problematic, since they reinforce the illusion that social and ecological impacts on well-being are objectively measurable. Future policy must not only be informed to a greater extent by qualitative and multi-dimensional assessments, but must recognize that any rank-ordering of society’s ultimate ends cannot but be subjective.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. By social well-being I refer specifically to the welfare of society as a whole, the measurement or estimation of which is often classified as “objective” (e.g., Paim 1995). I do not by this term mean an aggregation of the component individual subjective “well-beings”. I will have more to say later about this distinction.

  2. It is beyond my present cope to discuss plausible arguments for why growth may be negative-sum under such a criterion, but the point is amply addressed in the literature. See especially Scitovsky (1977) on this point.

  3. Kuznets (1955) was among the first to note this, presenting evidence that the income distribution in a country becomes more unequal as it begins along its development trajectory, only later to change course toward greater equality.

  4. The HDI differs in that consumption (income) counts as but one of three dimensions. Nevertheless, as I will discuss, the UNDP’s approach is also exceedingly narrow since well-being has many more dimensions, many of which defy quantitative measure.

  5. The diagram is as in Daly (1991, p. 19) save for two minor modifications. I use the label “philosophy and values” instead of ethics because the latter may be interpreted as relating more to narrow questions of individual morality. Also, I label the area of inquiry concerned with the ultimate end “spirituality” instead of religion in order to eliminate any suggestion of institutional influences and to more accurately convey a non-material (or post-material) ultimate purpose.

  6. To De Gregori (1986), ultimate means are those that only become resources once developed by the human hand and human ingenuity. Along similar lines, to Daly (1995) they are the “stuff to which value is added.” Ultimate means are also often classified as “low-entropy” matter-energy, the foundation for (and constraint on) all human activity. See also, e.g., Corning (2002), Ferrari et al. (2001), and Georgescu-Roegen (1971).

  7. Note the hierarchy among different areas of inquiry. Choices made regarding both the path of technological change and the extent of human impact on the environment are a product of the “economics” (i.e. intermediate means-intermediate ends) sphere. We can therefore say that nature and technology are subordinate to economics. The latter is in turn subordinate to “philosophy and values” since it is humanity’s pursuit of the “ultimate end” that directly, if unconsciously, determines our rank-ordering of competing intermediate ends.

  8. In all that follows I will take progress, development, or well-being improvement to refer to success in achieving the ultimate human purpose.

  9. I should be clear that by “subjective” I mean biased or partial and not individual or personal as the word is often used in the literature.

  10. The “positive” assumptions relate to different scenarios for allocation of the resource depletion externalities in the absence of reliable data. The competing scenarios regarding the weight or importance given to the performance of individual subgroups is a “normative” exercise, as discussed earlier. Finally, we might say that the different discount rate assumptions have a positive and a normative aspect—positive in the sense that they may correspond to available estimates of time value preference or capital opportunity cost, normative in that they imply some relative intergenerational preference.

References

  • Ackerman, F. (1997). Consumed in theory: Alternative perspectives on the economics of consumption. Journal of Economic Issues, 31(3), 651–664.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahluwalia, M., & Chenery, H. (1974). The economic framework. In H. Chenery, M. Ahluwalia, C. L. G. Bell, J. H. Dully, & R. Jolly (Eds.), Redistribution with growth (pp. 35–57). London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrera, A. (1999). Economic life, rights, and obligations: Perspective from theological teleology. Forum for Social Economics, 29(1), 63–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brekke, K., & Howarth, R. (2000). The social contingency of wants. Land Economics 76(4), 493–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brekke, K., Luras, H., & Nyborg, K. (1996). Allowing disagreement in evaluations of social welfare. Journal of Economics, 63(3), 303–324.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corning, P. (2002). Thermodynamics: Beyond the second law. Journal of Bioeconomics, 4(1), 57–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costanza R., & Cornwell, L. (1992). The 4P approach to dealing with scientific uncertainty. Environment, 34, 12–20, 42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Csikszentmihalyi, M. (2000). The costs and benefits of consuming. Journal of Consumer Research, 27, 267–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daly, H. (1991). Steady-state economics (2nd ed). Washington & Covelo: Island Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daly, H. (1995). Consumption and welfare: two views of value added. Review of Social Economy, 53(4), 451–473.

    Google Scholar 

  • Daly, H., & Cobb, J. (1989). For the common good: Redirecting the economy towards community, the environment, and a sustainable future. Boston: Beacon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Gregori, T. (1986). Technology and negative entropy: Continuity or catastrophe? Journal of Economic Issues, 20(2), 463–469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dupor, B., & Liu, W. (2003). Jealousy and equilibrium overconsumption. American Economic Review, 93(1), 423–428.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckersley, R. (2000). The mixed blessings of material progress: Diminishing returns in the pursuit of happiness. Journal of Happiness Studies, 1, 267–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faucheux, S., Muir, E., & O’Connor, M. (1997). Neoclassical natural capital theory and “weak” indicators for sustainability. Land Economics, 73(4), 528–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrari, S., Genoud, S., & Lesourd, J. (2001). Thermodynamics and economics: Towards exergy-based indicators of sustainable development. Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, 137(3), 319–336.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2004). Economic consequences of mispredicting utility. Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich. Working paper no. 218.

  • Georgescu-Roegen, N. (1971). The entropy law and the economic process. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, F., (1977). Social limits to growth. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howarth, R., (1996). Status effects and environmental externalities. Ecological Economics, 16, 25–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klasen, S., (1994). Growth and well-being: Introducing distribution-weighted growth rates to reevaluate U.S. Post-War Economic Performance. Review of Income and Wealth, 40(3), 251–272.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic growth and income inequality. American Economic Review, 45(1), 1–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane, R. (2000). Diminishing returns to income, companionship—and happiness. Journal of Happiness Studies, 1, 103–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H. (1950). Bandwagon, snob, and veblen effects in the theory of consumers’ demand. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 64, 183–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Alier, J. (1995). Distributional issues in ecological economics. Review of Social Economy, 53(4), 511–528.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Alier, J., Munda, G., & O’Neill, J. (2001). Theories and methods in ecological economics: A tentative classification. In C. Cleveland, D. Stern, R. Costanza (Eds.), The economics of nature and the nature of economics (pp. 34–56). Edward Elgar: Cheltenham and Northampton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maslow, A., (1968). Toward a psychology of being (3rd Ed.). John Wiley.

  • Max-Neef, M. (1992). Development and human needs. In P. Ekins, M. Max-Neef (Eds.), Real-life economics: Understanding wealth creation (pp. 197–214). London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J. (1848). Principles of political economy. London: Longmans, Green, and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munda, G. (1997). Multi-criteria evaluation as a multidimensional approach to welfare measurement. In J. van den Bergh & J. van der Straaten (Eds.), Economy and ecosystems in change: Analytical and historical approaches (pp. 96–115). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ng, Y. (2002). The East-Asian happiness gap: Speculating on causes and implications. Pacific Economic Review, 7(1), 51–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norgaard, R. (1994). Development betrayed: The end of progress and a coevolutionary revisioning of the future. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paim, L. (1995). Definitions and measurements of well-being: A review of the literature. Journal of Economic and Social Measurement, 21, 297–309.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D. W., & Barbier, E. (1990). Sustainable development: Economics and environment in the third world. Brookfield: Gower Pub. Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Repetto, R., Magrath, W., Wells, M., Beer, C., & Rossini, F. (1989). Wasting assets: Natural resources in the national income accounts. Washington: World Resources Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson, R., Findlay, A., Morris, A., & Coombes, M. (1989). Indicators of quality of life: Some methodological issues. Environment and Planning A, 21, 1655–1666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, W. (1992). Bygone splendour. In P. Ekins & M. Max-Neef (Eds.), Real-life economics: Understanding wealth creation (pp. 156–161). London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schor, J. (1991). Global equity and environmental crisis: An argument for reducing working hours in the north. World Development, 19(1), 73–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumacher, E.H. (1999). Small is beautiful: economics as if people mattered (2nd Ed.). Hartley &Marks.

  • Scitovsky, T., (1977). The joyless economy: An inquiry into human satisfaction and consumer dissatisfaction. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A (1997). Editorial: Human capital and human capability. World Development, 25(12), 1959–1961.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (2001). Economic development and capability expansion in historical perspective. Pacific Economic Review, 6(2), 179–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stockhammer, E., Hochreiter, H., Obermayr, B., & Steiner, K. (1998). The index of sustainable economic welfare (isew) as an alternative to GDP in measuring economic welfare. The results of the Austrian (revised) ISEW calculation 1955–92. Ecological Economics, 21, 19–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Torras, M. (2003). Welfare, inequality, and resource depletion: A reassessment of Brazilian economic growth, 1965–1998. Aldershot: Ashgate Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. B. (1912). The theory of the leisure class. London, MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Worster, D. (1995). The shaky ground of sustainability. In W. Sachs (Ed.), Global ecology: A new arena of political conflict (pp. 132–145). London & New Jersey: Zed Books.

Download references

Acknowledgments

I wish to thank Kazuya Ishii and Dean Jolliffe for comments on earlier versions of this work. All errors remain mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mariano Torras.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Torras, M. The Subjectivity Inherent in Objective Measures of Well-Being. J Happiness Stud 9, 475–487 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-007-9084-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-007-9084-z

Keywords

Navigation