Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The rural exodus and the rise of Europe

  • Published:
Journal of Economic Growth Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We build a unified model of growth and internal migration and identify its deep parameters using an original set of Swedish data. Our structural estimation and counterfactual experiments suggest that conditions of migration between the countryside and cities have strongly shaped the timing and the intensity of the transition to growth. Mobility cost had to be low enough to enable population movement. Furthermore, initial productivity in rural industries had to be moderate to sustain the first phase of industrialization appearing in the countryside without delaying too much the second phase of industrialization taking place in cities. More than the initial productivity of rural industries or migration costs alone, what truly mattered for the transition to modern economic growth was the interplay between these two elements. By contrast, we evidence a poor role for mortality decline in the whole process. Finally, we discuss why our conclusions on Sweden are exemplary for the rest of Western Europe.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In 1850, approximately 10% of the Swedish population was living in cities; however, by 1960, this share had increased to 52.3%.

  2. If both agriculture and rural industries use rural abilities, they do so under different technological regimes. Skills are not initially equally distributed among adults, such that our framework is a heterogeneous agents model.

  3. Interestingly enough, Edvinsson (2017) evidences the existence of a Malthusian regime in Sweden before 1800 while positive checks may have persisted even until 1920.

  4. Considering income differentials between cities and the countryside as a driving force for urbanization is in line with most of the literature on the topic. See, for instance, Gollin et al. (2016).

  5. In Sect. 4.5, we discuss the reasons why we do not try to match additional moments. The main reason pertains to issues with the definitions of GDP per capita and school enrollment rates.

  6. The development of rural industries during the eve of the Industrial Revolution has often been qualified as protoindustrialization after Mendels (1972). Economic historians have had severe disagreements on the reality of this phenomenon, but they have all agreed on the fact that prior to the so-called Industrial Revolution, a non-negligible portion of industrial work was located in rural areas. See Ogilvie and Cerman (1996) for a complete discussion of the concept of protoindustrialization, as well as Sect. 6.

  7. Some papers have documented a significant impact of other types of mortality, such as young adult mortality and longevity, on the economic take-off. See, among others, the enlightening papers of Tamura (2002), Cervellati and Sunde (2011), Strulik and Werner (2016), Boucekkine et al. (2002), Strulik and Weisdorf (2014) and Voigtländer and Voth (2012).

  8. A large number of other refinements to unified growth theory have been produced. Galor (2011) provides an enlightening review of this literature.

  9. Other papers have applied calibration techniques to UGT. Lagerlöf (2006) presents a numerical exercise conducted with the model of Galor and Weil (2000) by choosing parameters either from the literature or currently observed moments. Cervellati and Sunde (2005) and Strulik and Weisdorf (2014) present illustrative numerical simulations that highlight the respective roles of longevity and child survival. Cervellati et al. (2013) use panel data for 59 countries beginning in 1880 to structurally estimate a unified growth model.

  10. Data comparability issues necessarily arise. In “Online Appendix A.1”, we describe the general procedures we used for data harmonization and smoothing. All statistics are computed using current Swedish borders.

  11. Centralbyrån (1969) provides an overview of Swedish cities and their year of foundation.

  12. This exercise has been possible thanks to the help of Umeå University and its retrieval tool, discussed in “Online Appendix A.2”.

  13. Schön (2010) also documents a share of 10% of the total population living in towns and cities for the first half of the nineteenth century.

  14. Brändström (1993) presents Swedish infant mortality rates at the provincial level and evidence on intra-rural and intra-urban differentials.

  15. We discuss the method and the advantages of using alternative fertility measures in “Online Appendix A.3”.

  16. See “Online Appendix A.4” for details.

  17. In his contribution to the EH.net Encyclopedia, Schön (2008) argues that “During the first half of the nineteenth century (...) many non-agrarian activities such as the iron industry, the saw mill industry and many crafts as well as domestic, religious and military services were performed in rural areas.” This argument is further developed in key contributions such as Schön (2010, 2012).

  18. Even if our theory does not offer any predictions regarding wages per sector, the latter may be used to evaluate whether our presentation of the timing of growth is plausible. In Figure 20 of “Online Appendix A.5”, we present wages by sector, normalized to 100 in 1800, and we can again identify the fact that industry started to outperform agriculture around 1820, at least in terms of growth rates.

  19. It has been widely documented that although school became compulsory in 1842 in Sweden, enrollment rates stayed well below 100% during the nineteenth century; see Flora (1983), Benavot and Riddle (1988) or Soysal and Strang (1989), among many others.

  20. Enrollment rates in integrated secondary and tertiary education indicate the number of pupils in the age groups 15–19 and 20–24, respectively. For details, see de la Croix et al. (2008).

  21. In setting up our model in this way, we disregard potentially important phenomena such as savings or intergenerational co-residence. On this latter point, see the recent contribution of Pensieroso and Sommacal (2019).

  22. This simplifying assumption implies that all members of the same dynasty share the same rural abilities.

  23. This assumption is in line with the history of Sweden but even more generally of Western European countries. See, among others, the key contributions of Lampe and Sharp (2015), Bairoch (1997), Berger et al. (2012) and Schön (2010).

  24. Such a hypothesis is supported by Squicciarini and Voigtländer (2015) and Lees and Lees (2007), among many others.

  25. See, for instance, the enlightening contributions of Simon and Nardinelli (1996, 2002) and Brunt and García-Peñalosa (2021) for the cases of England and the US. The magnifying effects of agglomeration (through peer effects and imitation) on the accumulation of human capital in cities compared to that in rural areas is theorized, for instance, by Glaeser (1999). The specific use of human capital in industry is also a central assumption in papers such as Tamura (2002).

  26. In line with the literature from Becker (1960) to Galor (2011), fertility decisions are represented with continuous numbers.

  27. Importantly enough, we do not assume differences in preferences between urban and rural persons because migration decisions are endogenous; it would allow people to decide on their own preferences. Nevertheless, assuming, for instance, that urban persons value more the human capital of their children than rural persons may help to capture the dynamics of the trade-off between quality and quantity over time in a better way. We present this alternative framework in “Online Appendix D.2”.

  28. For a discussion of childlessness, see Baudin et al. (2015).

  29. The perfect mobility between rural sectors ensures that \(g_{y_t^{{\mathcal {I}}}}=g_{y_t^{{\mathcal {A}}}}\).

  30. The condition \(\zeta ^U>\zeta ^R\) is satisfied in our calibration-simulation exercise, see Sect. 4.4.

  31. Population size could be stabilized at a level below \({\bar{N}}\) along the BGP relying on additional mechanisms like international immigration or public policies increasing net fertility to one.

  32. See “Online Appendix B.3” for a proof.

  33. We illustrate this argument in “Online Appendix D.1”, where we propose an alternative calibration and simulation exercise with \(a^i={\bar{a}}\) for all dynasties. Even if satisfactory, the fit of the predicted moments reduces significantly compared to our benchmark framework. In particular, the educational transition is less smooth. All rural parents start to educate their children at the exact same moment; the educational revolution is “rugged”.

  34. We describe the general procedure in more detail in “Online Appendix A.1”.

  35. Hutterites are German Anabaptists reputed to have fertility rates close to maximal reproduction capacities.

  36. See Baudin and Stelter (2021) for more details.

  37. In “Online Appendix C.4”, we show that, in our simulations, migrations were quantitatively much less important before 1800 than after, and even almost absent for some years. This result has to be interpreted carefully: in a context where migration costs represent almost 30% of the average potential income and given that families reallocated themselves in 1760 already, migration was not a viable option during some periods for the vast majority of the population. In reality, sizable internal migration existed before the industrialization in Sweden, especially short distance migration as explained by Dribe (2003) as well as Andersson (2018). One could imagine an extension of our model where migration costs would be heterogeneous. It would allow for short distance migration even in pre-industrial times. Though more realistic, such an extension would severely complexify our theory without changing its main predictions and its overall quantitative fit.

  38. It corresponds to approximately 11.7% of the average available income. This value is plausible, as Gary (2018) estimates that on average, in 1760, fewer than 50 days of casual work were required to earn a subsistence basket.

  39. Notice that in alternative parameter sets, poverty may lead to the disappearance of some dynasties.

  40. Our model predicts an increase in urban fertility between the first two periods, a result that is not in line with the data. This is because the dynasties are not perfectly allocated across areas in the initial state and then they reallocate themselves. We find that in 1760, the initial period in the simulation, some dynasties relocated from the countryside to a city (see Figure 31a and 31b in “Online Appendix C.4”). Approximately 5% of young adults in rural areas left their place of origin and moved to a city, where they represented 30% of the young adults. These relatively poor dynasties were associated with a significant reduction in average fertility in cities. They had low levels of human capital, and paying \(\kappa\) caused them to live in a Malthusian regime.

  41. These values correspond to the \(\hbox {R}^{2}\) of an ordinary least squares regression in which the observed TFR is the dependent variable and the predicted TFR is the independent variable. Another way to evaluate the quality of the model’s fit is to compute the average distance between the observed and predicted moments in percentage points. In the case of fertility, the distance equals 10.5% in cities and 6.1% in the countryside. See “Online Appendix C.1” for a further discussion.

  42. Even if the fit of the predicted moments speaks in favor of our estimation strategy, it does not guarantee that our set of estimated parameters is located in a well-behaved region of the parameter space nor that each parameter is well identified. We show in “Online Appendix C.3” that our estimation suffers from neither of these two issues.

  43. Using the GDP per capita or taking into account all sectors instead of being limited to industry and agriculture also leads to a convincing reproduction of the empirical moments; see “Online Appendix C.1”.

  44. More precisely, using Centralbyrån (1969) and Table 3, we compute the ratio between the number of urban workers and the number of urban workers plus rural industrial workers.

  45. For simplicity, we propose a constant threshold to “mimic” educational levels. In line with Galor and Weil (2000), we could also argue that the acceleration in technological progress required increasingly higher levels of education to maintain the relative educational level. Such a dynamic threshold would reduce the temporary underestimation in secondary and tertiary education enrollment rates.

  46. See details in “Online Appendix C.2”.

  47. Fertility rates below the replacement level are observed among many industrialized economies, like Japan and Germany having respectively 1.36 and 1.54 births per woman in 2019 according to the World Bank. In particular, several European countries experience what demographers have designated as lowest-low fertility levels since the 1990s (Kohler et al., 2002; Billari and Kohler, 2004; Sobotka, 2004).

  48. In Figure 21 of “Online Appendix B.2”, these persons live in the neighborhood of \({\bar{\omega }}^{j}\).

  49. Note that in the initial period, a higher \(A_0^{\mathcal {I}}\) provokes an urban exodus; this effect is quite sizable when \(A_0^{\mathcal {I}}\) is multiplied by 10.

  50. In Table 9 in “Online Appendix C.6”, we provide the series of net changes in the number of births in each area.

  51. Prussia introduced compulsory education with the famous school edict in 1717, while its industrialization was rather late (Van Horn Melton, 2003). In contrast, in England (and Wales), as the leader in industrialization, primary education was not compulsory before 1870 when compulsory primary education was established with the Elementary Education Act (Flora, 1983).

References

  • Adamopoulos, T. (2008). Land inequality and the transition to modern growth. Review of Economic Dynamics, 11(2), 257–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J. J. (2022). Urbanization, long-run growth, and the demographic transition. Journal of Demographic Economics, 88(1), 31–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alfani, G., & Gráda, C. Ó. (2018). The timing and causes of famines in Europe. Nature Sustainability, 1(6), 283–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson, M. (2018). Migration i 1600-talets Sverige: Älvsborgs lösen 1613–1618. Ph.D. thesis, Diss. Universus Academic Press.

  • Bairoch, P. (1997). Victoires et déboires: histoire économique et sociale du monde du XVIe siècle à nos jours (Vol. I). II and III: Gallimard.

  • Bar, M., & Leukhina, O. (2010). Demographic transition and industrial revolution: A macroeconomic investigation. Review of Economic Dynamics, 13(2), 424–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baudin, T., de la Croix, D., & Gobbi, P. E. (2015). Fertility and childlessness in the United States. The American Economic Review, 105(6), 1852–1882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baudin, T., & Stelter, R. (2021). A dynamic general equilibrium approach to migration in economic history. In High performance computing and data science in the Max Planck society (pp. 60–61).

  • Becker, G. S. (1960). An economic analysis of fertility. In Demographic and economic change in developed countries (pp. 209–240). Columbia University Press.

  • Benavot, A., & Riddle, P. (1988). The expansion of primary education, 1870–1940: Trends and issues. Sociology of Education, 61, 191–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, T. (2019). Railroads and rural industrialization: Evidence from a historical policy experiment. Explorations in Economic History, 74, 101277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, T., & Enflo, K. (2017). Locomotives of local growth: The short-and long-term impact of railroads in Sweden. Journal of Urban Economics, 98, 124–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, T., Enflo, K., & Henning, M. (2012). Geographical location and urbanisation of the Swedish manufacturing industry, 1900–1960: Evidence from a new database. Scandinavian Economic History Review, 60(3), 290–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertinelli, L., & Black, D. (2004). Urbanization and growth. Journal of Urban Economics, 56(1), 80–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Billari, F., & Kohler, H.-P. (2004). Patterns of low and lowest-low fertility in Europe. Population Studies, 58(2), 161–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bocquier, P., & Brée, S. (2018). A regional perspective on the economic determinants of urban transition in 19th-century France. Demographic Research, 38, 1535–1576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bocquier, P., & Costa, R. (2015). Which transition comes first? Urban and demographic transitions in Belgium and Sweden. Demographic Research, 33, 1297–1332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boucekkine, R., De la Croix, D., & Licandro, O. (2002). Vintage human capital, demographic trends, and endogenous growth. Journal of Economic Theory, 104(2), 340–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brändström, A. (1993). Infant mortality in Sweden—1750-1950—past and present research into its decline. In Carlo, C. A, & Viazzo, P. P. (Eds.), The decline of infant mortality in Europe? 1850–1950: Four national case studies (pp. 19–34).

  • Brändström, A., & Sundin, J. (1981). Infant mortality in a changing society: The effects of child care in a Swedish parish 1820–1894.

  • Brunt, L., & García-Peñalosa, C. (2021). Urbanisation and the onset of modern economic growth., aix-Marseilles School of Economics - Working Papers - WP 2021 - Nr 01.

  • Centralbyrån, S. (1969). Historisk statistik for Sverige. Del I. Befolkning. Andra upplagan 1720–1967.

  • Centralbyrån, S. (1999). Population development in Sweden in a 250-year perspective. Historisk statistik för Sverige.

  • Cervellati, M., Murtin, F., & Sunde, U. (2013). Unified growth empirics: 1880–2000.

  • Cervellati, M., & Sunde, U. (2005). Human capital formation, life expectancy, and the process of development. The American Economic Review, 95, 1653–1672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cervellati, M., & Sunde, U. (2011). Life expectancy and economic growth: The role of the demographic transition. Journal of Economic Growth, 16(2), 99–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charbonneau, P. (2002). An introduction to genetic algorithms for numerical optimization. NCAR Tech. Note TN-450+ IA, 74pp.

  • Chun-Chung, A., & Henderson, V. (2006). How migration restrictions limit agglomeration and productivity in China. Journal of Development Economics, 80(2), 350–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coale, A. (1969). The decline of fertility in Europe from the French Revolution to World War II. In S. J. Behrman & R. Freedman (Eds.), Fertility and family planning: A world view (pp. 3–24). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix, D. (2017). Did longer lives buy economic growth? From Malthus to Lucas and Ben-Porath. In M. Cervellati & U. Sunde (Eds.), Demographic change and long-run development (pp. 69–89). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • De la Croix, D., Docquier, F., Fabre, A., & Stelter, R. (2020). The academic market and the rise of universities in medieval and early modern Europe (1000–1800).

  • de la Croix, D., & Doepke, M. (2003). Inequality and growth: Why differential fertility matters. The American Economic Review, 93(4), 1091–1113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix, D., Doepke, M., & Mokyr, J. (2017). Clans, guilds, and markets: Apprenticeship institutions and growth in the preindustrial economy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133(1), 1–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix, D., Lindh, T., & Malmberg, B. (2008). Swedish economic growth and education since 1800. Canadian Journal of Economics, 41(1), 166–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desmet, K., & Parente, S. L. (2012). The evolution of markets and the revolution of industry: A unified theory of growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 17(3), 205–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doepke, M. (2004). Accounting for fertility decline during the transition to growth. Journal of Economic growth, 9(3), 347–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dribe, M. (2003). Migration of rural families in 19th century southern Sweden. A longitudinal analysis of local migration patterns. The History of the Family, 8(2), 247–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edvinsson, R. (2017). The response of vital rates to harvest fluctuations in pre-industrial sweden. Cliometrica, 11(2), 245–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, H., & Kindermann, F. (2018). Introduction to computational economics using Fortran. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Flora, P. (1983). State, economy and society in western Europe 1815–1975: a data handbook in two volumes. Vol. I: the growth of mass democracies and welfare states. Campus Verlag.

  • Galor, O. (2005). The demographic transition and the emergence of sustained economic growth. Journal of the European Economic Association, 3(2–3), 494–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O. (2011). Unified growth theory. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2002). Natural selection and the origin of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1133–1191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Weil, D. N. (1999). From Malthusian stagnation to modern growth. The American Economic Review, 89(2), 150–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor, O., & Weil, D. N. (2000). Population, technology, and growth: From Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. The American Economic Review, 90, 806–828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gary, K. (2018). Work, wages and income: Remuneration and labor patterrns in Sweden 1500–1850. Ph.D. thesis, Lund University.

  • Glaeser, E. L. (1999). Learning in cities. Journal of Urban Economics, 46(2), 254–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goffe, W. L., Ferrier, G. D., & Rogers, J. (1994). Global optimization of statistical functions with simulated annealing. Journal of Econometrics, 60(1), 65–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gollin, D., Jedwab, R., & Vollrath, D. (2016). Urbanization with and without industrialization. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(1), 35–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J., & Seshadri, A. (2002). The US demographic transition. AEA Papers and Proceedings, 92(2), 153–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodrick, R. J., & Prescott, E. C. (1997). Postwar US business cycles: An empirical investigation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houston, R., & Snell, K. D. (1984). Proto-industrialization? Cottage industry, social change, and industrial revolution. The Historical Journal, 27(2), 473–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knick, H. C. (1998). Cotton textile prices and the industrial revolution. The Economic History Review, 51(1), 49–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knodel, A. J. (1974). The decline of fertility in Germany, 1871–1939, Office of Population Research and others, vol. 2. Princeton University Press.

  • Kohler, H.-P., Billari, F. C., & Ortega, J. A. (2002). The emergence of lowest-low fertility in Europe during the 1990s. Population and Development Review, 28(4), 641–680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lagerlöf, N.-P. (2003). From Malthus to modern growth: Can epidemics explain the three regimes?*. International Economic Review, 44(2), 755–777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lagerlöf, N.-P. (2006). The Galor–Weil model revisited: A quantitative exercise. Review of Economic Dynamics, 9(1), 116–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lampe, M., & Sharp, P. (2015). Just add milk: A productivity analysis of the revolutionary changes in nineteenth-century Danish dairying. The Economic History Review, 68(4), 1132–1153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lampe, M., & Sharp, P. (2019). A land of milk and butter: How elites created the modern Danish dairy industry. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lees, A., & Lees, L. H. (2007). Cities and the making of Modern Europe, 1750–1914 (Vol. 39). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendels, F. F. (1972). Proto-industrialization: The first phase of the industrialization process. The Journal of Economic History, 32, 241–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (1977). Demand vs. supply in the industrial revolution. The Journal of Economic History, 37(4), 981–1008.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2005). Long-term economic growth and the history of technology. In Handbook of economic growth (pp. 1113–1180, vol. 1). Elsevier.

  • Mokyr, J. (2010). Understanding growth in Europe, 1700–1870: Theory and evidence. In S. Broadberry & K. H. O’Rourke (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Modern Europe (Vol. I, pp. 7–42). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Mosk, C. (1980). Rural-Urban fertility differences and the fertility transition. Population Studies, 34(1), 77–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2014). Long-term baseline projection—OECD economic outlook: Statistics and projections. Tech. Rep. 95, Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development. https://doi.org/10.1787/data-00690-en.

  • Ogilvie, S. (2014). The economics of guilds. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(4), 169–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogilvie, S., & Cerman, M. (1996). European proto-industrialization: An introductory handbook. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pensieroso, L., & Sommacal, A. (2019). Agriculture to industry: The end of intergenerational coresidence. Review of Economic Dynamics, 34, 87–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, M. J. (2002). UOBYQA: Unconstrained optimization by quadratic approximation. Mathematical Programming, 92(3), 555–582.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rozental, A. A. (1956). The enclosure movement in France. The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 16(1), 55–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saville, J. (2013). Rural depopulation in England and Wales, 1851–1951 (Vol. 9). London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schön, L. (2008). Sweden–economic growth and structural change, 1800–2000. EH. net Encyclopedia.

  • Schön, L. (2010). Sweden’s road to modernity: An economic history. Stockholm: SNS förlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schön, L. (2012). An economic history of modern Sweden. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schön, L., & Krantz, O. (2012). Swedish historical national accounts 1560-2010. Lund Papers in Economic History, 123.

  • Simon, C., & Nardinelli, C. (1996). The talk of the town: Human capital, information, and the growth of English cities, 1861 to 1961. Explorations in Economic History, 33(3), 384–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, C., & Nardinelli, C. (2002). Human capital and the rise of American cities, 1900–1990. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 32(1), 59–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobotka, T. (2004). Is lowest-low fertility in Europe explained by the postponement of childbearing? Population and Development Review, 30(2), 195–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Söderberg, J. (1984). A long-term perspective on regional economic development in Sweden, Ca. 1550–1914. Scandinavian Economic History Review, 32(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Söderberg, J., Jonsson, U., & Persson, C. (2003). A stagnating metropolis: The economy and demography of Stockholm, 1750–1850 (Vol. 13). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soysal, Y. N., & Strang, D. (1989). Construction of the first mass education systems in nineteenth-century Europe. Sociology of Education, 62, 277–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squicciarini, M. P., & Voigtländer, N. (2015). Human capital and industrialization: Evidence from the age of enlightenment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(4), 1825–1883.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics-Sweden. (2018). Sveriges framtida befolkning 2018–2070. Demografiska rapporter 2018:1, Statistics Sweden.

  • Strulik, H., & Weisdorf, J. (2014). How child costs and survival shaped the industrial revolution and the demographic transition. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 18(01), 114–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strulik, H., & Werner, K. (2016). 50 is the new 30–long-run trends of schooling and retirement explained by human aging. Journal of Economic Growth, 21(2), 165–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sundin, J., & Willner, S. (2007). Social change and health in Sweden: 250 years of politics and practice. Stockholm: Swedish National Institute of Public Health.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swedish Historical Population Statistics. The demographic data base on Swedish historical population statistics. CEDAR, Umeå University.

  • Tamura, R. (2002). Human capital and the switch from agriculture to industry. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 27(2), 207–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tamura, R. (2006). Human capital and economic development. Journal of Development Economics, 79(1), 26–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tamura, R., & Simon, C. (2017). Secular fertility declines, baby booms, and economic growth: International evidence. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 21(7), 1601–1672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United-Nations. (2018). World urbanization prospects: The 2018 revision (Online). Department of Economic and Social Affairs - Population Division: United Nations.

  • van der Woude, A., Hayami, A., & De Vries, J. E. (1995). Urbanization in history: A process of dynamic interactions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Horn Melton, J. (2003). Absolutism and the eighteenth-century origins of compulsory schooling in Prussia and Austria. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigtländer, N., & Voth, H.-J. (2012). The three horsemen of riches: Plague, war, and urbanization in early modern Europe. Review of Economic Studies, 80(2), 774–811.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weisdorf, J. L. (2004). From stagnation to growth: Revisiting three historical regimes. Journal of Population Economics, 17(3), 455–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woods, R. (2003). Urban-rural mortality differentials: An unresolved debate. Population and Development Review, 29(1), 29–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Baudin.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We gratefully thank Oded Galor and four anonymous referees who have greatly contributed to improve this paper. We also benefited from discussions with Philippe Bocquier, Shankha Chakraborty, David de la Croix, Alexia Fürnkranz-Prskawetz, Paula Gobbi, Victor Hiller, Joël Machado, Andreas Irmen, Fabian Kindermann, Carl Mosk, Jim Oeppen, Holger Strulik, Uwe Sunde and Nico Voigtlaender. We also thank the participants of seminars and conferences in Louvain-la-Neuve, Paris, Hamburg, Aix-en-Provence, Moscow, Rostock, Nanterre and Brussels for their helpful comments. We would like to thank Annika Westberg for helping us with the SHiPs data. We are deeply grateful for the computational infrastructure provided by the Max Planck Computing and Data Facility and the assistance offered by Markus Rampp. This project has benefited from the scientific and financial support of ARC project 15/19-063 on “Family transformations” (French-speaking community of Belgium) and Project MALYNES (ANR-18-CE26-0002). Robert Stelter acknowledges financial support from the Max Geldner foundation. The traditional disclaimer applies.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (pdf 1034 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Baudin, T., Stelter, R. The rural exodus and the rise of Europe. J Econ Growth 27, 365–414 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-022-09206-4

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-022-09206-4

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation