Skip to main content
Log in

Signaling for access to high-demand markets: evidence from the US motion picture industry

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Cultural Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We develop a signaling model in which imperfectly competitive firms signal quality through expenditures in segmented markets. Separation in this model results in high-quality firms selling their products in a high-demand, and highly quality elastic, period. Low-quality firms sell their product in a low demand but less quality-sensitive period. A dataset including 1697 US theatrical releases between 1998 and 2008 is compiled and explored for evidence of this separating equilibrium. We find that our measures of signal intensity and realized quality (budgets and critical ratings, respectively) are both significantly greater during high-demand periods. Ticket sales are also shown to be more sensitive to expected quality as measured by budgets during the high-demand season. Other seasonal differences and implications are explored.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In reality, some studios may be unable to send a signal due to credit constraints and our model therefore applies to the set of firms that have the capacity to signal. We do not believe this constraint to be binding with very many films; only 6.7 % of the movies shown in our dataset were released by non-major studios.

  2. Studios frequently and costlessly change release dates but once the date is announced to the public during the promotion phase it becomes costly to change. Our focus is on consumers’ behavior and its implications for a separating equilibrium rather than post-entry competition in either the high-demand or low-demand market. For this reason, we treat the “pre-release” announcement period as an adjustment to a Nash Equilibrium and assume that it takes place instantaneously (i.e., we ignore the adjustment period and assume that studios’ announcements to the public represent a credible commitment).

  3. Again, quality here refers to mass appeal. There is no loss in assuming that these customers are in fact cinephiles interested in quality of a sort that does not appeal to the masses.

  4. While there are many pooling and partial pooling equilibria in this game, as in all signaling games, they can be eliminated by the use of refinements such as D1 (see Cho and Kreps 1987).

  5. While profits are frequently negative in reality, we have assured positive profits by assuming that there is no uncertainty regarding demand and that there are only two levels of quality.

  6. Our main results are unchanged if we include these 114 titles along with a control for whether a film is released by a major studio.

  7. One important source of signaling is advertising, which Einav (2007) reports to be a fixed percentage of the overall budget for movie production. Roger G. Friedman, vice chairman of the Motion Picture Group and COO of Paramount Pictures, estimated the average advertising expenditures to be 30 million dollars, of which 2.5–8 million dollars are spent on so called creative costs that include costs of creating the marketing campaign as well as travel expenses for promotional appearances of filmmakers (Friedman 2004, p. 292).

  8. Since the number of “release weeks” varies between 51 and 53 and key dates occur in different weeks across years, we make this determination using the 3-week average including the prior week and the following week.

  9. Only three movies in the dataset have a rating of NC-17.

  10. Again, we smooth the data here by using the 3-week average that includes the week before and the week after.

  11. The first stage regression results can be found in the Online Appendix.

  12. Seemingly Unrelated Regression results for the model are quite similar to those given here.

References

  • Ainslie, A., Drèze, X., & Zufryden, F. (2005). Modeling movie life cycles and market share. Marketing Science, 24(3), 508–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albert, S. (1998). Movie stars and the distribution of financially successful films in the motion picture industry. Journal of Cultural Economics, 22(4), 249–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albert, S. (1999). Movie stars and the distribution of financially successful films in the motion picture industry: Reply. Journal of Cultural Economics, 23(4), 325–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basuroy, S., Desai, K. K., & Talukdar, D. (2006). An empirical investigation of signaling in the motion picture industry. Journal of Marketing Research, 43(2), 287–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basuroy, S., & Ravid, S. A. (2014). How relevant are experts in the internet age? Evidence from the motion pictures industry. Working Paper, University of Oklahoma.

  • Bohnenkamp, B., Knapp, A., Hennig-Thurau, T., & Schauerte, R. (2015). When does it make sense to do it again? An empirical investigation of contingency factors of movie remakes. Journal of Cultural Economics, 39(1), 15–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calantone, R. J., Yeniyurt, S., Tonwsend, J. D., & Schmidt, J. B. (2010). The effects of competition in short product life-cycle markets: The case of motion pictures. The Journal of Product Innovation Management, 27(3), 349–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chintagunta, P. K., Gopinath, S., & Vankataraman, S. (2010). The effects of online user reviews on movie box office performance: Accounting for sequential rollout and aggregation across local markets. Marketing Science, 29(5), 944–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chisholm, D. C., Fernandez-Blanco, V., Ravid, S. A., & Walls, W. D. (2015). Economics of motion pictures: The state of the art. Journal of Cultural Economics, 39(1), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho, I., & Kreps, D. (1987). Signaling games and stable equilibria. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102(2), 179–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vany, A. S. (2004). Hollywood economics: How extreme uncertainty shapes the film industry. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Vany, A., & Walls, W. D. (1999). Uncertainty in the movie industry: Does star power reduce the terror of the box office? Journal of Cultural Economics, 23(4), 285–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vany, A. S., & Walls, W. D. (2004). Motion picture profit, the stable Paretian hypothesis, and the curse of the superstar. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 28(6), 1035–1057.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einav, L. (2007). Seasonality in the US motion picture industry. RAND Journal of Economics, 38(1), 127–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einav, L. (2010). Not all rivals look alike: Estimating an equilibrium model of the release date timing game. Economic Inquiry, 48(2), 369–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Einav, L., & Ravid, S. A. (2009). Stock market response to changes in movies’ opening dates. Journal of Cultural Economics, 33(4), 311–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elberse, A., & Eliashberg, J. (2003). Demand and supply dynamics for sequentially released products in international markets: The case of motion pictures. Marketing Science, 22(3), 329–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliashberg, J., Elberse, A., & Leenders, M. A. A. M. (2006). The motion picture industry: Critical issues in practice, current research, and new research directions. Marketing Science, 25(6), 638–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliashberg, J., Swami, S., Weinberg, C. B., & Wierenga, B. (2001). Implementing and evaluating SilverScreener: A marketing management support system for movie exhibitors. Interfaces, 31(3), S108–S127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez-Blanco, V., Orea, L., & Prieto-Rodriguez, J. (2013). Endogeneity and measurement errors when estimating demand functions with average prices: An example from the movie market. Empirical Economics, 44(3), 1477–1496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filson, D. (2005). Dynamic common agency and investment: The economics of movie distribution. Economic Inquiry, 43(4), 773–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, R. G. (2004). Motion picture marketing. In J. E. Squire (Ed.), The movie business book (3rd ed., pp. 282–299). New York: Fireside.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jedidi, K., Krider, R., & Weinberg, C. (1998). Clustering at the movies. Marketing Letters, 9(4), 393–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • John, K., Ravid, S. A., & Sunder, J. (2014). Managerial ability and success: Evidence from the career paths of film directors. Journal of Corporate Finance. doi:10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2014.11.001.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krider, R. E., & Weinberg, C. B. (1998). Competitive dynamics and the introduction of new products: The motion picture timing game. Journal of Marketing Research (JMR), 35(1), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lampel, J., & Shamsie, J. (2003). Capabilities in motion: New organizational forms and the reshaping of the hollywood movie industry. Journal of Management Studies, 40(8), 2189–2210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma, J., Huang, D., Kumar, M. V. S., & Strijnev, A. (2015). The impact of supplier bargaining power on the advertising costs of movie sequels. Journal of Cultural Economics, 39(1), 43–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marvasti, A. (2000). Motion pictures industry: Economies of scale and trade. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 7(1), 99–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie, J. (2009). Revealed word-of-mouth demand and adaptive supply: Survival of motion pictures at the Australian box office. Journal of Cultural Economics, 33(4), 279–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1986). Price and advertising signals of product quality. Journal of Political Economy, 94(4), 796–821.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moul, C. C. (2005). A concise handbook of movie industry economics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 78(2), 311–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, P. (1974). Advertising as information. Journal of Political Economy, 82(4), 729–754.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prag, J., & Casavant, J. (1994). An empirical study of the determinants of revenues and marketing expenditures in the motion picture industry. Journal of Cultural Economics, 18(3), 217–235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravid, S. A. (1999). Information, blockbusters, and stars: A study of the film industry. Journal of Business, 72(4), 463–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee, R. (1978). A model of advertising and product quality. Journal of Political Economy, 86(3), 485–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sedgwick, J., & Pokorny, M. (1999). Movie stars and the distribution of financially successful films in the motion picture industry: Comment. Journal of Cultural Economics, 23(4), 319–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sochay, S. (1994). Predicting the performance of motion pictures. Journal of Media Economics, 7(4), 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Squire, J. E. (Ed.). (2004). The movie business book (3rd ed.). New York: Fireside.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1961). The economics of information. The Journal of Political Economy, 69(3), 213–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swami, S., Eliashberg, J., & Weinberg, C. B. (1999). SilverScreener: A modeling approach to movie screens management. Marketing Science, 18(3), 352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watson, G. (2004). Uncertainty and contractual hazard in the film industry: Managing adversarial collaboration with dominant suppliers. Supply Chain Management, 9(5), 402–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zufryden, F. S. (1996). Linking advertising to box office performance of new film releases—A marketing planning model. Journal of Advertising Research, 36(4), 29–41.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the editor, Kathryn Graddy, two anonymous referees, Christopher S. Brunt, and seminar participants at Georgia Southern University and the 40th Annual Conference of the European Association for Research in Industrial Economics for helpful comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to John T. King.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Any opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Qatar National Research Fund.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 60 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

King, A.S., King, J.T. & Reksulak, M. Signaling for access to high-demand markets: evidence from the US motion picture industry. J Cult Econ 41, 441–465 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-016-9273-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-016-9273-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation