1 Introduction

Anthropogenic climate change and trans-boundary pollution have long justified the emergence of international environmental agreements (henceforth IEAs). There are increasing efforts worldwide to find joint solutions to curb greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions (and to save the ecosystems in general) while ensuring socio-economic security, as shown by the definition of the seventeen Sustainable Development Goals.Footnote 1 The issue of stability and effectiveness of IEAs has attracted growing attention from the academic literature in recent decades.

Since the seminal paper of Barrett (1994), the economic literature has approached this issue by modelling the optimal IEA coalition size within the framework of game theory (see Marrouch et al. 2016, for a review). The general consensus is that a global agreement on emissions reduction is not feasible (Yang 2017) and that only small coalitions are stable (Gelves and McGinty 2016). On the contrary, the actual number of parties to climatic IEAs has increased over time, from 84 countries that signed the first ratification of the Kyoto Protocol (COP3) in 1999 to 200 countries participating in the last COP25 held in Madrid in 2019.Footnote 2

Beyond that, few key players actually determine the structure and success of self-enforcing IEAs (Finus et al. 2009). A case in point was the US reversal from a leadership role in forming climate coalitions in the lead-up to the Paris Agreement (COP 23 in 2015), to its announcement of a withdrawal from the same treaty in 2017 (Zhang et al. 2017). This situation reflects the so-called breadth and depth dilemmas (Keohane and Victor 2011; Hannam et al. 2017), i.e. the trade-off between breadth (wanting many actors) and depth (wanting strength of action/mitigation) agreements.Footnote 3 Despite many theoretical and empirical advances, one under-explored aspect is the role of domestic economic structures on the outcome of climate agreements (and their effectiveness thereof). The current contribution aims to fill this gap.

Given this premise, we aim to shed a light on the following questions: 1) To what extent does the country-specific economic structure determines the success or failure of IEAs? 2) How do global inequalities and economic growth affect the road towards a low-carbon transition? 3) Are local initiatives able to boost pro-environmental behaviours or do they hamper the success of environmental laws? To answer these questions, we propose a novel framework, based on a two-nested-game approach that covers alternative economic structures, cross-country inequalities, and different consumer environmental attitudes. We propose a model that analyses the linkages between the macro-scale (international agreements) and the micro-scale (firm and consumer choices) to evaluate the actual effectiveness of IEAs. Thus, environmental performances that differ from what is ratified—i.e. failure, fulfilment or over-performance (i.e. when CO\(_2\) reductions exceed than what is agreed)—are explained by endogenous dynamics determined by both the stringency of the targets defined during the IEAs and the interactions among economic agents within each country.

This approach challenges some of the main (often hidden) assumptions behind the available studies, namely:

a1:

the ratified agreement will automatically yield, in the real economy, the planned effect;

a2:

the failure to comply with the IEA is only explained in terms of free-riding behaviour;

a3:

local initiatives are ineffective: people submit to environmental legislation without making any voluntary effort to support or hinder the introduction of such environmental laws.

Assumption a1 appears in contrast with the fact that, despite the ratification of several climatic IEAs, GHG emissions are still increasing at the global level (Testa et al. 2016). Moreover, there is considerable cross-country heterogeneity in environmental performance, in terms of the difference between what is signed in IEAs and the actual level of emissions.Footnote 4

The assumption a2 imposes a free-riding behaviour—i.e. despite the global benefits of reducing GHG emissions, no agent has the incentive to reduce his/her own burden—neglecting the possibility of voluntary initiatives. On the contrary, even developing countries decided to implement national environmental policies although they were exonerated from emission controls. India approved a fund of US$ 1,371 million to boost energy efficiency and develop clean technologies and electrification, while since 2014 China has deployed more solar and wind capacity than any country worldwide, adding around 17.5 Gigawatts of solar energy by the end of 2015 alone.Footnote 5

The last assumption (a3) excludes bottom-up initiatives. In reality, many environmental NGOs (e.g. Greenpeace and WWF), climate campaigners (“Fridays for future”, the school strike movement) and local communities have put pressure on governments (e.g. the EU’s Covenant of Mayors initiative) in order to actively protect and preserve ecological systems (Nasiritousi et al. 2016). On the other hand, increasing economic disparities and job instability within national boundaries (Alvaredo et al. 2018) have led to social unrest against the introduction of green laws (Ponticelli and Voth 2020) such as the protests of the “Gilets Jaunes” after a carbon tax was introduced by the French government in November 2018.Footnote 6

This study is structured as follows. Section 2 briefly explains the methodology and the logic of the two games. Section 3 describes the one-shot 2x2 asymmetric IEA game, and Sect. 4 deals with the evolutionary interactions between households and firms. Section 5 presents and discusses the results of alternative scenarios based on numerical simulations, defined by a handy Maple algorithm. Finally, Sect. 6 draws the main conclusions and policy implications.

2 Methods

Before moving onto the mathematical details, it is worth explaining the logic behind our model in order to clarify the interpretations thereof. Figure 1 shows a schematic representation of the step-by-step procedure proposed. We develop a model which integrates the results from two nested games:Footnote 7 Game 1 analyses the results (at the macro-scale) of a one-shot 2x2 game, where two asymmetric countriesFootnote 8—representative of the richer (N) and poorer (S) regions, respectively (e.g. Anand 2017)—bargain over the share of clean energy (\(\theta \)) to attain given emission abatement targets.Footnote 9 Each country differs in terms of income level and technological development which determines the attainable value of the welfare function (W).

Game 2 embeds the outcome of Game 1 (i.e. \(\theta \)) that modifies the pay-off of firms and consumers. Note that Game 2 models the evolutionary dynamic (at the micro-scale) of the country’s economic structure represented by the interaction of the economic decisions of consumers and firms, who decide whether or not to be environmentally friendly. Their interactions determine endogenously the actual level of carbon emissions, which can differ from what is agreed in the bilateral IEA.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Macro-view of the model structure. Schematic representation of the logic and the sequential phases composing the two nested games. On the left (blue panel) the structure of each country—i.e. benefits from green (\(\pi ^E\)) and brown (\(\pi ^P\)) profits and damages due to local (L) and global (D) pollution—determines the Welfare function of the rich (\(W_N\)) and poor (\(W_S\)) country. Then, Game 1 (green panel) determines the outcome of the IEA, i.e. the optimal abatement target (\(\theta ^*\)) that will be implemented in each country by law. The environmental law will affect the firms and consumers pay-off. In Game 2 they interact until an evolutionary equilibrium (\(\alpha ^*, \beta ^*\)) emerges. Finally (orange panel), the country’s actual GHG emissions will be compared with what was ratified in the IEA, being greater, equal or lower

The timing of the whole model is as follows: each country recognizes the importance of transboundary effects of carbon emissions and then decides to bargain (i.e. Game 1 on bilateral IEA) to ratify an international environmental standard (\(\theta \)). This target is conceived as the minimum share of clean production, with respect to industrial profits (or GDP), thus reflecting a decision on the energy mix of the production process. Indeed, the amount of renewable resources increases with \(\theta \) because firms have to install new green technologies to curb polluting emissions.

The treaty is enforced by national law and so \(\theta \) is embodied in the agents’ pay-off. Game 2 determines the evolutionary stable state(s) depending on the evolutionary strategic interactions between consumers and firms. The emissions in equilibrium are then compared with the level of emissions ratified in the IEA (right-hand panel of Fig. 1). Note that we do not consider any feedback from Game 2 to Game 1. Although this might represent a limitation, the main purpose of our study is to assess to what extent the economic structure influences the actual level of emissions, considering that the government has no perfect information about the complexity of the underlying economic system (Hatase and Matsubayashi 2019). Hence, our approach explains under what (micro- and macro-) conditions environmental performance might differ from what was ratified during the IEA.

3 Bilateral IEA (game 1)

Each country \(i = \{N,S\}\) has a welfare objective function defined as:Footnote 10

$$\begin{aligned} W_i(\theta _i, \pi _i) = B_i(\theta _i, \pi _i) - a_i\cdot D(\theta , \pi ), \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where the parameter 0 \(\le a_i\le \) 1 represents the country-specific climate risk, i.e. the probability of undergoing economic losses due to climate change induced by global pollution (Cai et al. 2013). As is commonly found in the literature on static simultaneous move games (see Marrouch et al. 2016, p.249), the welfare function is defined as the difference between the net economic benefits of production minus the estimated (monetary) costs of environmental damage. We define the net benefits (\(B_i\)) as the difference between the overall country-specific economic production (\(\Pi _i\)) and the local damage (\(L_i\), i.e. within national boundaries), expressed as a quadratic function (see Pavlova and de Zeeuw 2013). Hence, even in the absence of any IEA a country might find it worth introducing environmental laws to tackle environmental deterioration and health problems due to industrial discharges of national polluting firms. Total country-specific industrial profits (\(\Pi _i\)) are determined by the profits of clean (\( \pi _i^E \)) and polluting (\( \pi ^P_i \)) profits weighted by the share of green (\(\theta \)) and brown (\( 1 -\theta \)) firms, respectively. Note that a one-to-one relationship is assumed between production and emissions such that \(\pi _p\) denotes both production and emissions (see Pavlova and de Zeeuw 2013). Namely:

$$\begin{aligned} B_i(\theta _i, \pi _i)&= b_i[d_i\cdot \Pi _i(\theta _i, \pi _i) - L_i(\theta _i, \pi _i)],\end{aligned}$$
(2)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _i(\theta _i, \pi _i)&= \theta _i\cdot \pi _i^E + ( 1 - \theta _i)\cdot \pi _i^P,\end{aligned}$$
(3)
$$\begin{aligned} L_i(\theta _i, \pi _i)&= \frac{[( 1 - \theta _i)\cdot \pi _i^P]^2}{2}, \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where the parameter 0 \(\le b_i \le \) 1 is the overall opportunity cost, while 0 \(\le d_i \le \) 1 is the marginal industrial benefit. The damage to country i from global pollution (\(D_i\)) is a quadratic function of the global emissionsFootnote 11—given by the sum of domestic and foreign pollution—representing a proxy of the potential damage caused by extreme climate events (Coronese et al. 2019). Namely

$$\begin{aligned} D(\theta , \pi ) = \left(\sum _{k = \{i,j\}} (1 - \theta _k)\cdot \pi _k^P \right)^2 . \end{aligned}$$
(5)

Note that using a linear-quadratic framework allows us to avoid discrete solutions (pollute or not) and then to provide a more realistic representation of the abatement target ratified during the IEA.

3.1 Agreement formation in the international setting

The decision rule to find the optimal single agreement is based on the “smallest common denominator” (SCD) to ensure the external stability of the IEA. The SCD rule implies that a compromise is found on the lowest environmental target: if \(\theta _N > \theta _S\), then the Nash equilibrium is \(\theta ^*= \theta _S\), and the reverse (Finus 2002). Although one would expect proposals to be strategically motivated, it is possible to demonstrate that the SCD decision rule is immune to strategic offers; rather, it is a best reply and a Nash equilibrium (Endres and Finus 1999, pp. 539–540).

From Eqs. (1) and (2), it derives that each country has an incentive to implement environmental laws even in the absence of an IEA (\(a_i = 0\)) to tackle local environmental damage from polluting production, as formally discussed in “Appendix” A (see the business-as-usual case). For the sake of clarity, here we only expose the analytical results from the IEA, viz. when global externalities are recognized (\(a_{i}>\) 0). The non-cooperative Nash equilibrium is given by the maximization of Eq. (1) with respect to \(\theta _i\). Namely

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \theta _{i}&= K_{i} \{\pi _j^P (b_j b_i + a_j b_i) [ (\pi _i^P)^2 - d_i (\pi _i^P - \pi _i^E)] \\&\quad + \pi _i^P\cdot a_i b_j\cdot [\pi _i^P \pi _j^P + d_j (\pi _j^P - \pi _j^E)] \}, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where

$$\begin{aligned} K_{i} = [\pi _j^P (\pi _i^P)^2 \cdot (b_{j}b_{i} + a_{j}b_{i} + a_{i}b_{j})]^{-1}, \end{aligned}$$
(7)

with (ji) = {N,S} and \(j \ne i\).

Given the high nonlinearity of these solutions, it is not possible to establish a simple relationship between the optimal level of environmental standards and the parameters and variables involved. For this reason, Sect. 5 performs numerical simulations, while in “Appendix” A.2 there are the ceteris paribus analytical discussions (propositions and proofs) about the conditions that determine the bottleneck of the IEA.

4 Evolutionary (micro-)economic structure (game 2)

In the second step, we construct a dynamic model of the process by which the proportions of various strategies in a population evolve (Weibull 1997). To analyse the evolutionary dynamics governing transitions between the two conventions (Green–Green, Carbon Economy), let us assume a two-person two-strategy (\(s = \{E, P\}\)) game in a large population of individuals subdivided into two groups—namely households (\({\mathcal {H}}\)) and firms (\({\mathcal {F}}\))—the members of which are randomly matched to interact in a non-cooperative game with the members of the other group. Individuals’ best-response play is based on a single-period memory: they maximize their expected pay-off based on the distribution of the population in the previous period (Bowles 2009; Belloc and Bowles 2013). Both populations are normalized to unit size, so we refer equivalently to the numbers of players and to the fraction of the population.Footnote 12 The application of evolutionary games to study the link between economics and the environment is gaining attention because of its ability to disentangle complex dynamics (e.g. Antoci et al. 2019).

We assume that when people with different strategies are matched they do not sign any contract; in other words, green consumers do not want to buy polluting goods and vice versa.Footnote 13 The dynamic evolution of the proportion of ecological households and firms (\(\alpha \) and \(\beta \), respectively) follows the so-called replicator dynamic (Santos and Pacheco 2011) :

$$\begin{aligned}&{\dot{\alpha }}_t = \alpha _t\cdot (1 - \alpha _t)\cdot [H_{E,t} - H_{P,t}] \end{aligned}$$
(8)
$$\begin{aligned}&{\dot{\beta }}_t = \beta _t\cdot (1 - \beta _t)\cdot [F_{E,t} - F_{P,t}] \end{aligned}$$
(9)

where \(H_{s,t}\) and \(F_{s,t}\) are the expected fitness of households and firms’ strategies, respectively, in period t. According to Eqs. (8) and (9), the percentage of green players increases if the pay-off given by the green strategy (E) is higher than what is expected when the polluting strategy (P) is played. The pay-off depends on the actions of the co-players and hence on the frequencies of the strategies within the population (Sigmund 2010). The more successful individuals will be “mimicked” by others, so that the share of individuals adopting a given strategy changes over time.

4.1 Households

The utility of a household h depends on its material pay-off and strategy (\(h_{s}\)). For the sake of simplicity, we assume that the consumption of each kind of commodity yields the same level of utility (u).Footnote 14 The pay-off of the household is a piece-wise continuous function defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} h_{s,t} = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} h_{E,t} = u - c (\theta - \beta _t), &{} {\text {iff}}\,\,\,\,\beta _t< \theta {\text { and s }}={\text { E}}\\ h_{P,t} = u - \delta (\theta - \beta _t), &{} {\text {iff}}\,\,\,\,\beta _t < \theta {\text { and s}} ={\text { P}}\\ u, &{} {\text {otherwise, with s}} = \{{\text {E, P}}\}. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(10)

where \(0< \delta ,c,u \le 1\). Parameter \(u>0\) is the constant level of utility from consumption, independent of market conditions (not modelled here).Footnote 15 Environment friendly households bear an additional monetary cost (c) proportional to the difference between the environmental standard (\(0\le \theta \le 1\)) and the share of green firms (\(0\le \beta \le 1\)). This additional cost represents the willingness to finance the (start-up) of green production. In other words we include the observations that the more eco-friendly the product is, the higher the price that consumers must pay (Shi et al. 2019).Footnote 16 On the other hand, polluting households incur, as a moral cost, the weight of negative public opinion regarding the possible damage arising from polluting consumption (\(\delta \)). Thus, \(\delta \) is a measure of the level of environmental attitude commonly found in society, which might also be interpreted as a proxy of the willingness to accept the imposition of green policies. In other words, if \(\delta \) is low it can be interpreted as a form of resistance or social unrest against the environmental laws, while if high it might be indicative of higher environmental awareness. Notably, moral motivations have been proved to be an important driver of behaviour, especially when concerning environmental choices (Turaga et al. 2010; Steg 2016).

The share of green households, in equilibrium, depends on the gap between the environmental law \(\theta \) and the actual proportion of green firms (\(\beta ^{*}\)), while in the case of no environmental concerns—i.e. \(\beta \ge \theta \)—the green household simply receives utility from consumption. The interested reader can find the complete analytical discussion, including proofs and propositions, in “Appendix” B.1.

4.2 Firms

Let us assume that the firm’s pay-off is a piece-wise continuous function defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} f_{s,t} = {\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} f_{E,t} = \pi _E + \frac{c(\theta - \beta _t)\alpha }{\beta _t}, &{} {\text {iff}}\,\,\,\,\beta _t< \theta {\text { and s }} ={\text { E}},\\ f_{P,t} = \pi _P - \frac{\gamma (\theta - \beta _t)}{1- \beta _t}, &{} {\text {iff}}\,\,\,\,\beta _t < \theta {\text { and s }}={\text { P}},\\ \Pi _{s}, &{} {\text {otherwise, with s} }=\{{\text {E, P}}\}. \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(11)

where \(0< \pi _{E} < \pi _{P}<\)1 because we assume that the green technology is not already developed to be as efficient as the polluting one and thus the related profits are smaller (Goeschl and Perino 2017).Footnote 17 This distinction is crucial to assess how the energy mix of production, at the country scale, determines the country’s environmental performance.

The coefficient \(\gamma >0\) is a multiplicative factor that measures the monetary cost of the difference \(\theta - \beta _t\) which represents the gap between the actual and the normative share of clean production. The level of profits from production depends on the strategy (\( \pi _{s} \)); they can be interpreted as an average profit proportional to the market share of the belonging sector. A green firmFootnote 18—other than profits—receives a premium-price which is equal to the total amount of extra costs (c), paid by each green household, multiplied by the share of green consumers (\(\alpha \)). This amount decreases as the share of green firms approaches the environmental standards (\(\beta \rightarrow \theta \)). We assume that, in every period, the total amount paid by green consumers is equally shared among green firms. The premium price sustains and boosts the investments in new green start-ups to stimulate investments in green sectors (Bergset and Fichter 2015).

The polluting firm faces a cost (\(\frac{\gamma (\theta - \beta _t)}{1- \beta _t}\)) for local damage that depends on: the relation between the actual level of green production (\(\beta _t\)), the abatement target fixed by the government (\(\theta \)), and the number of polluting firms (\(1 - \beta _t\)). Since polluting firms must jointly cover the cost of environmental damage, the total amount is determined by the percentage of polluting firms. We assume that the amount paid by polluting firms might be used by the government to restore the detrimental effects and to finance climate mitigation actions.

Given that the expected pay-off of firms is not linear, depending on households strategy, we develop in Sect. 5 numerical simulations to evaluate all the possible cases. The interested reader can find the complete analytical discussion, including proofs and propositions, in “Appendix” B.2.

5 Results

For the sake of simplicity, we focus on four key dimensions: climatic risk distribution (a), global economic development (\(\Pi _N + \Pi _S\)), cross-country technological inequality (\( \Pi _N / \Pi _S \)),Footnote 19 and consumers’ environmental attitudes (\(\delta \)). For a comparative analysis about the effect of different opportunity costs, see “Appendix” A.2.

Table 1 The setting of the parameters of the numerical simulations

Table 1 reports the setting of the values of all the parameters that characterize the different scenarios. Depending on global economic growth and cross-country inequality, we define four alternative cases. Note that in Game 1 we have 16 alternative sets of pay-offs since that for each of the four IEA cases (inequality/growth) there are other four alternative games depending on the cross-country climatic risk distribution (i.e. \(a_L^N-a_L^S\) or \(a_L^N-a_H^S\) or \(a_H^N-a_L^S\) or \(a_H^N-a_H^S\) ). To this, Game 2 adds other two alternative worlds where consumers might have either low or high environmental attitudes, making a total of 32 scenarios.

Numerical simulations enable reliable outcomes to be generated when many parameters vary at the same time, which would be impossible to assess analytically. This is crucial to clarify the relation between the target ratified in the IEA and the actual level of carbon pollution which depends on the country’s economic structure and its evolutionary path.Footnote 20 Our framework provides reliable scenarios able to capture the interaction between top-down policy decisions and the (micro-level) economic structure. Note that the proposed scenarios capture all the possible cases, thereby producing clear results despite the complex issues at hand. Indeed, any other modification of the parameters will generate outcomes somewhat in between those defined herein. This, together with the analytical discussion provided in the “Appendix”, also ensures robustness of the outcomes.

5.1 Optimal IEA target

Table 2 collects all of the solutions from Game 1, also specifying whether the poorer (\(^S\)) or richer (\(^N\)) country is the bottleneck of the agreement, viz. who proposes the lowest target that will be implemented as the optimal solution of the IEA (i.e. \(\theta ^*\)), according to the SDC-rule (see Sect. 3.1).

Table 2 Optimal bargaining solution from IEA in Game 1 (i.e. \(\theta ^{*}\))

In this respect, an asymmetric influence of climate risks appears to be present: the poor country always establishes the IEA’s target when it faces a low risk (\(a_L^S\)), irrespective of the global conditions and the climate risk in the North. A possible interpretation might lie in the fact that the poor country prefers to boost polluting economic growth when the climate risk is low. Indeed, in the poorest regions, the absolute difference between polluting and green profits and the limited economic losses due to local damage (i.e. \(L_i\)), make the green strategy less convenient once the abatement target is fixed.

By contrast, when S faces high climate risk (\(a^H_S\)), the outcomes depend on N. If the richer country has low environmental concerns (\(a^L_N\)), it will establish the IEA at a lower level because it faces higher opportunity costs. However, under the same high climatic risk (\( a^H_S = a^H_N = 0.9 \)), S is again the bottleneck because it prefers to pursue economic growth and to put the burden of emission reduction on N. Indeed, given the historical economic inequality (i.e. \(\Pi _N \gg \Pi _S\)), N will curb more carbon emissions, in absolute terms, once the same abatement target in the IEA is established. Notably, extreme climate risks (\(a_H^N-a_H^S\)) do not necessarily lead to drastic mitigation interventions. In the case of high inequality and economic growth (Case 4), the IEA target will prove lower than the other cases. The trade-off between uncertain environmental damage and economic interests, together with the asymmetric historical responsibility, thus generates an impasse, as often observed in real IEAs.Footnote 21

The abatement targets will prove more stringent in the case of higher economic growth (Case 2 and 4) independently of both renewable energy profitability (i.e. higher green profits \(\pi _E\)), and the polluting/green profits gap, suggesting that economic growth brings about more efforts to avoid detrimental environmental effects. Interestingly, in some cases the proposed abatement target is particularly ambitious (\(\theta ^{*} > 0.7\)) although not unrealistic. Indeed, the last report drawn up by the IPCC (2018) suggested that, in order to avoid a temperature rise greater than 1.5 Celsius degree, it is necessary to reach net zero carbon emissions by 2050.

5.2 Evolutionary equilibrium and actual emissions

Table 3 reports the results of Game 2 and the GHG emissions emerging from the evolutionary equilibrium (as described in the green and orange panels in Fig. 1). A detailed explanation of the different regimes and the stability of the equilibria is exposed in “Appendix” B.3. Note that the overall GHG is computed as the sum of country emissions given the share of polluting firms in equilibrium, namely:

$$\begin{aligned} GHG = (1 - \beta ^*_N)\cdot \Pi _N^P + (1 - \beta ^*_S)\cdot \Pi _S^P. \end{aligned}$$
Table 3 Results Game 2

Note that, in the above scenarios, the fraction of green firms in (evolutionary stable) equilibrium (\( \beta ^*\)) does not vary across countries because the value of the parameters (c, u, \(\delta \) and \( \theta \)), that determine \( \beta ^*\) is the same (see Eq. B.2 and B.4 in “Appendix” B.1). However, the fraction of green consumers (\( \alpha ^*\)) that makes firms indifferent is larger in the richer country (i.e. \( \alpha ^*_N > \alpha ^*_S \)) because they are needed more green consumers are required to offset the absolute difference between polluting and green profits. This gap is higher in absolute terms in the North in all four cases.

When \(\theta ^{*}\) is enforced by law in each country, the economic structure will determine the actual outcome. Here, what is crucial is the role played by the consumers’ environmental attitude (\(\delta \)). When it is low (\(\delta _L\)), the actual environmental outcome is always worse than what is agreed in the IEA, irrespective of any free-riding behaviour. In some cases, the IEA is utterly ineffective (\( \beta ^{*}=0 \)) due also to the unfavourable consumers’ environmental attitude. This is a noteworthy result that shows the necessity of bottom-up initiatives for environmental policies to succeed. It also shows another source of failure of IEAs other than free-riding that depends on the actual socio-economic structure.

The only exception is given by the case of extreme climate risks that generate such an environmental target that the pay-off structure of consumers and firms is greatly affected. Interestingly, in these cases our model captures the over-performance observed in the real world, i.e. the country attains a greater abatement in emissions than what was ratified. Thus, when the top-down intervention is particularly strong the individual environmental attitude does not play a significant role. By contrast, when the environmental attitude is high the system converges towards a green-green equilibrium even with weaker targets (\(\theta \)). This confirms previous findings according to which local participation can have the positive impact of accelerating the process of cleaning up production and saving resources for alternative uses, because they allow governments to fix less stringent standards and avoid additional expenditures on restoring environmental damage (Coenen 2009).

Our model also clarifies the double-edge role played by economic growth. On the one hand, when it is higher the abatement target tends to be more stringent. On the other hand, overall GHG emissions are greater even when the share of green firms is relatively high. This underlines the issue of the scale of the economy and suggests that size matters. Thus, the feasibility of low-carbon transition plans might be weaker in the case of sustained economic growth, unless clean production becomes exceptionally profitable (i.e. \(\pi _E > \pi _P \)). This concern finds confirmation in the lack of evidence for alleged GDP-CO\(_2\) decoupling (Aslanidis and Iranzo 2009; Parrique et al. 2019) that might be due to the high cost of dismantling existing structures and to the fact that renewable energies are still not sufficient to cover the increasing global energy demand.

6 Discussion

This study analysed under what conditions international environmental agreements (IEAs) can be effective in terms of fulfilment of the ratified emission abatement targets. To this purpose, we considered two asymmetric countries—with different economic structures and technological development—negotiating emission reductions and then compared their actual environmental performance. It emerged that country-specific socio-economic dynamics are crucial in understanding why the IEAs might (or might not) fail. This claim was supported by the use of an analytical apparatus together with numerical simulations.

From a theoretical point of view, we offered an innovative perspective on which to ground multi-scale analysis. The main contribution with respect to the current literature on IEAs lies in modelling the country-specific economic structure which gives further insights to explain the gap between the promises of agreements and actual results. To the best of our knowledge, this study is the first to propose a two-nested-game approach where the outcomes of two different games are tied in a consistent framework. The proposed methodology might open the door to further developments in this field and shed light on how to bridge the micro- and macro- scales.

Although simplifications are essential, the effects of simplifying assumptions should not be ignored when interpreting the results (Madani 2013). In this respect, we acknowledge that there exist other drivers linked to climate change that might be relevant, such as: population growth, stock of emitted greenhouse gases remaining in the atmosphere, international trade, and time and costs required for conversion from a fossil-based to a zero-carbon economy. Future research might benefit from the inclusion of such factors, although the inclusion of too many variables, in a single tractable model, represents a mathematical and computational challenge.

Several implications may be drawn from our findings. First, contrary to what is assumed in the literature, our model shows that “global solutions”, negotiated at the international level, do not automatically produce the expected effects. Our framework allows a more accurate picture to be defined—including a variety of real-case results that would have been hidden in a standard context—in which even country-specific environmental over-performance (i.e. when carbon emissions are lower than what ratified) might emerge. Moreover, the assumption of free-riding might be misleading when dealing with collective entities and it is not necessary to explain the failure of the IEAs. Rather, at the country scale, environmental performance represents the outcome of a complex system resulting from the interplay of a large population of economic agents (consumers and firms). Indeed, our results suggest that the same IEA target may lead to diverging results depending on the country-specific socio-economic structure without assuming any free-riding behaviour.

Second, alternative combinations of climate risks distribution, economic growth, and cross-country technological inequalities generate non-trivial consequences. The impact of potential climatic economic losses generates asymmetric responses: the poorer countries prefer to fix lower abatement targets, all else kept constant. However, cross-country inequality appears to play a role when the climate risks are extreme. Contrary to what might be expected, the abatement target, ratified in the IEA, is lower because the poor country decides to place the burden on the richer one. This might explain why, during the Kyoto Protocol in 1997, compliance with the treaty was not mandatory for many developing countries (non-Annex I Parties). Moreover, “size matters”. Higher economic growth, albeit translating into higher international abatement targets, results in higher GHG emission, thus confirming the scepticism regarding the possibility of achieving absolute decoupling between GDP and emissions.

Third, our approach highlighted the fact that the relation between justice and environmental targets is crucial to attain a low-carbon transition, as recently acknowledged in the literature (D’Alessandro et al. 2020). Increasing inequality might lead to adverse environmental attitudes (i.e. \(\delta \) low) that might hamper the process of low-carbon transition implemented via energy policies (e.g. as shown by the protests of the “Gilet Jaune” in France). These observations entail that governments should not simply impose environmental standards by law. Rather, top-down policies and bottom-up interventions should be coordinated; otherwise, they might fail if undertaken in isolation.