Skip to main content
Log in

On the performance of rule-based contribution schemes under endowment heterogeneity

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Experimental Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We experimentally test different rule-based contribution mechanisms in a repeated 4-player public goods game with endowment heterogeneity and compare them to a VCM, distinguishing between a random and an effort-based allocation of endowments. We find that endowment heterogeneities limit the efficiency gains from these rule-based contribution schemes under random allocation. Under effort-based allocations, substantial efficiency gains relative to a VCM occur. These are largely driven by significant reductions of contributions in VCM, while the rule-based mechanisms generate stable efficiency levels, even though falling short in realizing the maximal efficiency gains. Our results indicate that the procedure of endowment allocation impacts the perception of what constitutes a fair burden sharing.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For the case of homogeneous marginal benefits, the payoff equation simplifies to \(\pi_{i} = e_{i} - q_{i} + bQ\) and correspondingly \(\sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^{n} {b_{j} = nb}\). Throughout the paper, we keep the notation \(b_{i}\) to allow for a more general application of our model. The Electronic Supplementary Material to this paper reports findings from an additional treatment to investigate the robustness of the eqpay rule in a setting with heterogeneous marginal benefits.

  2. Multiples of four are required.

  3. For deriving minimum individual contribution levels, integer numbers are required.

  4. Note that, given a specific binding \(Q^{min}\), voluntary contributions by high-type agents would be smaller in E-eqcont than under R-eqcont, but might be increased through the smaller \(Q^{min}\). As such, no prediction on the ranking for voluntary contributions is possible.

  5. It should be noted, however, that under effort-based allocation, eqcont may be expected to perform better than eqpay if high-type players feel to deserve a higher income than others: the distance in payoff between high- and low-types is constant in the range \(Q^{min} < 40\) in eqcont, while it decreases in eqpay (see Fig. 1). As such, high-type agents under effort-based allocation may block coordinating on positive minimum contribution levels.

  6. We observe the typical downward trends in contributions both under random and effort-based allocation (see also test for time trends in Table 7). Importantly, the gap in cooperative behavior between effort-based and random allocation persists over time.

  7. Considering the distribution of proposals allows gaining insights into possible motivation for this decline: under random allocation, 51% of low-type players’ suggestions correspond to their (potentially) payoff maximizing group contribution level (\(Q = 80\)), while less than 4% suggest a level which maximizes high-type players’ payoffs (\(Q = 40\)). Under effort-based endowment allocation, the rate of low-type players suggestions at \(Q = 80\) drops to 26%, while 13% of suggestions are at \(Q = 40\).

  8. It is noteworthy that players voluntarily go beyond the minimum contribution requirement. Under the equal-contribution rule, this applies particularly to high-type players (1.4), and less to low-types (0.7). Under the equal-payoff rule, this is reversed such that voluntary contributions largely stem from low-types (0.7) rather than high-types (0.1). As such, the equal-contribution rule appears to be seen as requiring disproportionately large contributions from low-types, while the equal-payoff rule may require too much from high-types.

  9. As can be seen from Fig. 4, average payoffs rather tend to decline over time, most notably in the last 5 periods.

  10. This is partly surprising, since even though binding minimum contribution levels on average remain in the range \(Q^{min} < 40\) where the distance in payoffs between both type of players decreases (see Fig. 1) high-type agents under effort-based allocation do not appear to block coordinating on positive minimum contribution levels.

  11. The corresponding Wald Test for the parameters estimated in regression (Table 6, column 5) confirm this finding for low-type players only for the eqpay rule but not for the eqcont rule (p[minQ + effXminQ = 0] = 0.23 and p[minQeq + effXminQeq] < 0.01).

  12. As a robustness check to the interpretation of our results for the equal-payoff rule under effort-based allocation, we carried out an additional treatment E-MPCR-eqpay which introduced heterogeneity with respect to the MPCR in addition to unequal endowments. For a discussion of the results, see the Electronic Supplementary Material to this paper.

References

  • Anderson, L. R., Mellor, J. M., & Milyo, J. (2008). Inequality and public good provision: An experimental analysis. Journal of Socio-Economics, 37, 1010–1028.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balafoutas, L., Kocher, M. G., Putterman, L., & Sutter, M. (2013). Equality, equity and incentives: An experiment. European Economic Review, 60, 32–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., & Ockenfels, A. (2000). ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. The American Economic Review, 90, 166–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, E., & Croson, R. (2006). Income and wealth heterogeneity in the voluntary provision of linear public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 935–955.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cappelen, A. W., Hole Drange, A., Sørensen, E. Ø., & Tungodden, B. (2007). The pluralism of fairness ideals: An experimental approach. The American Economic Review, 97, 818–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, K. S., Mestelman, S., Moir, R., & Muller, R. A. (1996). Voluntary contribution to public goods under varying income distributions. Canadian Journal of Economics, 29, 54–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, K. S., Mestelman, S., Moir, R., & Muller, R. A. (1999). Heterogeneity and the voluntary provision of public goods. Experimental Economics, 2, 5–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 817–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherry, T. L. (2001). Mental accounting and other-regarding behavior: Evidence from the lab. Journal of Economic Psychology, 22, 605–615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherry, T. L., Frykblom, P., & Shogren, J. F. (2002). Hardnose the dictator. The American Economic Review, 92, 1218–1221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cherry, T., Kroll, S., & Shogren, J. (2005). The impact of endowment heterogeneity and origin on public good contributions: Evidence from the lab. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 57, 357–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dannenberg, A., Lange, A., & Sturm, B. (2014). Participation and commitment in voluntary coalitions to provide public goods. Economica, 81, 257–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich, N., Oppenheimer, J., & Kurki, A. (2004). Modeling other-regarding preferences and an experimental test. Public Choice, 119, 91–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallier, C., Kesternich, M. & Sturm, B. (2017). Voting for burden sharing rules in public goods games voting for burden sharing rules in public goods games. Environmental and Resource Economics, 67, 535–557.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Georgantzìs, N. & Proestakis, A. (2011). Accounting for real wealth in heterogeneous-endowment public good games. The Working Paper No.10/20, University of Granada.

  • Gill, D. & Prowse, V. (2011). A novel computerized real effort task based on sliders. IZA Working Paper No. 5801.

  • Gill, D., & Prowse, V. (2012). A structural analysis of disappointment aversion in a real effort competition. The American Economic Review, 102, 469–503.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 114–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, F., & El Mouden, C. (2011). Exploring the effects of working for endowments on behaviour in standard economic games. PLoS ONE, 6, 1–6.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kesternich, M., Lange, A., & Sturm, B. (2014). The impact of burden sharing rules on the voluntary provision of public goods. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 105, 107–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kittel, B., Paetzel, F. & Traub, S. (2012). Who cares about equity? A social norm revisited. Working Paper.

  • Konow, J. (1996). A positive theory of economic fairness. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 31, 13–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koukoumelis, A., Levati, M. V., & Weisser, J. (2012). A voluntary contribution experiment with one-way communication and income heterogeneity. Applied Economics, 19, 1549–1552.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ku, H., & Salmon, T. C. (2013). Procedural fairness and the tolerance for income inequality. European Economic Review, 64, 111–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange, A., Löschel, A., Vogt, C., & Ziegler, A. (2010). On the self-interested use of equity in international climate negotiations. European Economic Review, 54, 359–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orzen, H. (2008). Fundraising through competition: Evidence from the lab, experimental economics. CeDEx Discussion Paper No. 2008-11, University of Nottingham.

  • Oxoby, R. J., & Spraggon, J. (2008). Mine and yours: Property rights in dictator games. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 65, 703–713.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinstein, D., & Riener, G. (2012). Decomposing desert and tangibility effects in a charitable giving experiment. Experimental Economics, 15, 229–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reuben, E., & Riedl, A. (2013). Enforcement of contribution norms in public good games with heterogeneous. Games and Economic Behavior, 77, 122–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spraggon, J., & Oxoby, R. J. (2009). An experimental investigation of endowment source heterogeneity in two-person public good games. Economics Letters, 104, 102–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ubeda, P. (2014). The consistency of fairness rules: An experimental study. Journal of Economic Psychology, 41, 88–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Dijk, F., Sonnemans, J., & Van, Winden F. (2002). Social ties in a public good experiment. Journal of Public Economics, 85, 275–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zelmer, J. (2003). Linear public goods experiments: A meta-analysis. Experimental Economics, 6, 299–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Financial support by the German Federal Ministry of Education and Research (FKZ 01UN1016A) is gratefully acknowledged. We thank the MaXLab team for their support in conducting the experiment.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andreas Lange.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 795 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kesternich, M., Lange, A. & Sturm, B. On the performance of rule-based contribution schemes under endowment heterogeneity. Exp Econ 21, 180–204 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9535-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-017-9535-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation