Skip to main content
Log in

Climate Damage on Production or on Growth: What Impact on the Social Cost of Carbon?

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recent articles have investigated with integrated assessment models the possibility that climate damage bears on productivity (TFP) growth and not on production. Here, we compare the impact of these alternative representations of damage on the social cost of carbon (SCC). We ask whether damage on TFP growth leads to higher SCC than damage on production ceteris paribus. To make possible a controlled comparison, we introduce a measure of aggregate damage, or damage strength, based on welfare variations. With a simple climate-economy model, we compare three damage structures: quadratic damage on production, linear damage on growth and quadratic damage on growth. We show that when damage strength is the same, the ranking of SCC between a model with damage on production and a model with damage on TFP growth is not unequivocal. It depends on welfare parameters such as the utility discount rate or the elasticity of marginal social utility of consumption.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. More accurately the social cost of CO2 as it relates to the impact of a ton of CO2 and not a ton of carbon. This is simply a question of changing units (from $ /tCO2 to $ /tC) and not a different concept. We follow here the majority of the literature by using the terminology social cost of carbon.

  2. There are two different types of IAMs. First, the cost-benefit type concerned in this article. Second, a different type of IAMs, sometimes called process-based IAMs, that explicitly represent the drivers and processes of change in global energy and land use systems linked to the broader economy. The IAMs of this second type do not represent damage from climate change, and are used to analyze transformation pathways to achieve a pre-determined level of mitigation effort such as 2 C climate stabilization, in a cost-effectiveness framework. Examples of process-based IAMs include the models used to quantify the shared socioeconomic pathways [41].

  3. Appendix 1 discusses why this allocation does not control for the magnitude of damage.

  4. In particular, [23] have shown that this linear relationship is influenced by prior emissions pathways, and [24] have shown that it is no longer valid for high emissions pathways such as the RCP8.5.

  5. What we call “idealine” is usually called “baseline” in the IAM community, in particular in the context of process-based IAMs studies on mitigation pathways and mitigation costs in a cost-effectiveness framework.

  6. This is the same as saying that mitigation gain are always positive, see Eq. 13.

  7. As explained in the main text, damage on production have a second-order cumulative effect through reduced capital accumulation.

References

  1. Anthoff, D., & Tol, R.S.J. (2013). The uncertainty about the social cost of carbon: a decomposition analysis using FUND. Climatic Change, 117(3), 515–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Anthoff, D., & Tol, R.S.J. (2009). The impact of climate change on the balanced growth equivalent: An application of FUND. Environmental and Resource Economics, 43(3), 351–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Arrow, K.J. (2007). Global climate change: a challenge to policy. The EconomistsVoice, 4(3).

  4. Auffhammer, M., & Schlenker, W. (2013). It’s not just the statistical model. A comment on Seo (2013). Climatic Change, 121(2), 125–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Colacito, R., Hoffmann, B., & Phan, T. (2014). Temperatures and growth: a panel analysis of the US., SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 2546456 Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY.

  6. Committee on Assessing Approaches to Updating the Social Cost of Carbon, Board on Environmental Change and Society, Division of Behavioral and Social Sciences and Education, and National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine (2017). Valuing climate changes: Updating estimation of the social cost of carbon dioxide, Washington, DC:National Academies Press, https://doi.org/10.17226/24651.

  7. Dasgupta, P. (2007). The Stern review’s economics of climate change. National Institute Economic Review, 199, 4–7.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Dell, M., Jones, B.F., & Olken, B.A. (2009). Temperature and income: reconciling new cross-sectional and panel estimates. American Economic Review, 99(2), 198–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Dell, M., Jones, B F., & Olken, B.A. (2012). Temperature shocks and economic growth: evidence from the last half century. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(3), 66–95.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Dell, M., Jones, B.F., & Olken, B.A. (2014). What do we learn from the weather? The new climate-economy literature. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(3), 740–798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Deryugina, T, & Hsiang, S.M. (2014). Does the environment still matter? Daily temperature and income in the united states, Working Paper 20750, National Bureau of Economic Researchx.

  12. Dietz, S., & Stern, N. (2015). Endogenous growth, convexity of damage and climate risk: how Nordhaus’ framework supports deep cuts in carbon emissions. The Economic Journal, 125(583), 574–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Fankhauser, S., & Tol, R.S.J. (2005). On climate change and economic growth. Resource and Energy Economics, 27(1), 1–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Gillett, N.P., Arora, V.K., Matthews, D., & Allen, M.R. (2013). Constraining the ratio of global warming to cumulative CO2 emissions Using CMIP5 Simulations*. Journal of Climate, 26(18), 6844–6858.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Godard, O. (2009). Time discounting and long-run issues: the controversy raised by the Stern Review of the economics of climate change. OPEC Energy Review, 33(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Goodwin, P., Williams, R.G., & Ridgwell, A. (2015). Sensitivity of climate to cumulative carbon emissions due to compensation of ocean heat and carbon uptake. Nature Geoscience, 8(1), 29–34.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  17. Greenstone, M., Kopits, E., & Wolverton, A. (2013). Developing a social cost of carbon for US regulatory analysis: a methodology and interpretation. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 7(1), 23–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Hope, C. (2013). Critical issues for the calculation of the social cost of CO2: why the estimates from PAGE09 are higher than those from PAGE2002. Climatic Change, 117(3), 531–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Hsiang, S. (2016). Climate econometrics. Annual Review of Resource Economics, 8(1), 43–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Hsiang, S.M., & Jina, A.S. The causal effect of environmental catastrophe on long-run economic growth: evidence from 6,700 Cyclones, Working Paper 20352, National Bureau of Economic Research.

  21. Tol, K.R.R., & Waldhoff, S. (2012). The social cost of carbon, http://www.economics-ejournal.org/special-areas/special-issues/the-social-cost-of-carbon. Special Issue of Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal.

  22. Kopp, R.E., Golub, A., Keohane, N.O., & Onda, C. (2012). The influence of the specification of climate change damages on the social cost of carbon, Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal.

  23. Krasting, J.P., Dunne, J.P., Shevliakova, E., & Stouffer, R.J. (2014). Trajectory sensitivity of the transient climate response to cumulative carbon emissions. Geophysical Research Letters, 41(7), 2520–2527.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  24. Leduc, M., Damon Matthews, H., & De Elía, R. (2015). Quantifying the limits of a linear temperature response to cumulative CO 2 emissions. Journal of Climate, 28(24), 9955–9968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Lucas, R.E., Jr. (1987). Models of business cycles. Oxford: Royaume-Uni, Basic Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Lucas, R.E., Jr. (2003). Macroeconomic priorities. American Economic Review, 93(1), 1–14.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Matthews, H.D., Gillett, N.P., Stott, P.A., & Zickfeld, K. (2009). The proportionality of global warming to cumulative carbon emissions. Nature, 459(7248), 829–832.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  28. Mirrlees, J.A., & Stern, N.H. (1972). Fairly good plans. Journal of Economic Theory, 4(2), 268–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Moore, F.C., & Diaz, D.B. (2015). Temperature impacts on economic growth warrant stringent mitigation policy. Nature Climate Change, 5(2), 127–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Moyer, E.J., Woolley, M.D., Matteson, N.J., Glotter, M.J., & Weisbach, D.A. (2014). Climate impacts on economic growth as drivers of uncertainty in the social cost of carbon. The Journal of Legal Studies, 43 (2), 401–425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Nordhaus, W.D. (1992). An optimal transition path for controlling greenhouse gases. Science, 258(5086), 1315–1319.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  32. Nordhaus, W.D. (1994). Managing the global commons: the economics of climate change. Cambridge: Mass MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Nordhaus, W.D. (2008). A question of balance. London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  34. On Social Cost of Carbon, Interagency Working Group (2010). Social Cost of Carbon for Regulatory Impact Analysis under Executive Order 12866. Technical report, United States Government.

  35. On Social Cost of Carbon, Interagency Working Group (2015). Technical Update of the Social Cost of Carbon for Regulatory Impact Analysis Under Executive Order 12866. Technical report, United States Government.

  36. Pindyck, R.S. (2011). Modeling the impact of warming in climate change economics. In Libecap, G., & Steckel, R. (Eds.) The economics of climate change. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  37. Pindyck, R.S (2012). Uncertain outcomes and climate change policy. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 63(3), 289–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Pizer, W., Adler, M., Aldy, J., Anthoff, D., Cropper, M., Gillingham, K., Greenstone, M., Murray, B., Newell, R., Richels, R., Rowell, A., Waldhoff, S., & Wiener, J. (2014). Using andimproving the social cost of carbon. Science, 346(6214), 1189–1190.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  39. Pottier, A., Etienne, E., Perrissin-Fabert, B., & Dumas, P. (2015). The comparative impact of Integrated Assessment Models’ structures on optimal mitigation policies. Environmental Modeling & Assessment, 20(5), 453–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Revesz, R.L., Howard, P.H., Arrow, K., Goulder, L.H., Kopp, R.E., Livermore, M.A., Oppenheimer, M., & Sterner, T. (2014). Global warming: Improve economic models of climate change. Nature, 508(7495), 173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Riahi, K., Vuuren, D.P., Kriegler, E., Edmonds, J, O’Neill, B.C., Fujimori, S., Bauer, N., Calvin, K., Dellink, R., Fricko, O., Lutz, W., Popp, A., Cuaresma, J. C., Samir, K. C., Leimbach, M., Jiang, L., Kram, T., Rao, S., Emmerling, J., Ebi, K., Hasegawa, T., Havlik, P., Humpenöder, F., Da Silva, L.A., Smith, S., Stehfest, E., Bosetti, V., Eom, J., Gernaat, D., Masui, T., Rogelj, J., Strefler, J., Drouet, L., Krey, V., Luderer, G., Harmsen, M., Takahashi, K., Baumstark, L., Doelman, J.C., Kainuma, M., Klimont, Z., Marangoni, G., Lotze-Campen, H, Obersteiner, M., Tabeau, A., & Tavoni, M. (2017). The Shared Socioeconomic Pathways and their energy, land use, and greenhouse gas emissions implications: An overview. Global Environmental Change, 42, 153–168.

  42. Schneider, S.H (1997). Integrated assessment modeling of global climate change: transparent rational tool for policy making or opaque screen hiding value-laden assumptions? Environmental Modeling and Assessment, 2(4), 229–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Stern, N. (1977). Welfare weights and the elasticity of the marginal valuation of income. In Artis, M.J., & Nobay, A.R. (Eds.) Studies in modern economic analysis: proceedings of the AUTE Edinburgh meeting of 1976, Chapter 8. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

  44. Stern, N. (2014). Ethics, equity and the economics of climate change. Paper 1: science and philosophy. Economics and Philosophy, 30(3), 397–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Stern, N. (2014). Ethics, equity and the economics of climate change. Paper 2: economics and politics. Economics and Philosophy, 30(3), 445–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Stern, N.H. (2006). Stern review: The economics of climate change Vol. 30. London: HM treasury.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Strulik, H. (2015). Hyperbolic discounting and endogenous growth. Economics Letters, 126, 131–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Tol, R.S. (2009). The economic effects of climate change. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(2), 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Tol, R.S. (2014). Correction and update: The economic effects of climate change. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(2), 221–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Antonin Pottier.

Appendices

Appendix 1

Moyer et al. [30] and [12] rely on the same representation of the impact of climate change on productivity growth. They start from damage bearing only on production, with a damage function D t that depends quadratically on the temperature T t : D t = 1 − Ω(T t ). Net production (that is including climate damage) Q t is reduced by a factor 1 − D t from Y t , the production that would have occurred given factors on production (technology, capital, labor), had climate change not existed: Q t = Y t (1 − D t ).

From this standard case, the current damage D t are then “allocated” between damage on production and damage on TFP growth, a procedure that originates, to our knowledge, from [22]. The TFP growth rate is reduced by f.D t , when the production, instead of being reduced by 1 − D t is reduced by (1 − D t )/(1 − f D t ), where f is the “share” of damage that impact growth. Speaking of an “allocation” of damage conveys the impression that there is the same “amount” of damage.

However, the damage apply on very different quantities. Damage on TFP growth have a (first-order) cumulative effect on the whole output path, whereas damage on production does not.Footnote 7 Far from keeping aggregate damage constant across the scenarios studied, the allocation introduces more damage when f increases. Thus, it is not surprising that these studies find that the SCC increases when more damage are allocated to damage on growth. To illustrate this, we consider two possible ways to measure aggregate damage: the real production loss and the damage strength used in the main text.

Figure 5 plots the real production loss at 3 C (the percentage of production loss between the baseline and the idealine when the temperature increase reaches 3 C) against the theoretical loss (the value of D t when the temperature increase is 3 C), for several “shares” of damage on growth: 0, 2.5, 5, 10, 15, and 20 (percents). Because temperature increase feedbacks on the economic dynamic and thus on emissions, the date at which 3 C is reached changes slightly when the theoretical loss and the “share” vary.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Real production losses as a function of theoretical production losses, for different “shares” of damage on growth f increasing from 0 to 20 percents

When damage bear only on production, real losses are already higher than the theoretical damage from the damage function (equal theoretical and real damage is represented by the dotted line in Fig. 5). This is due to feedbacks through reduced accumulation of capital. But the difference between real and theoretical losses remains quite small. When the “share” of damage on TFP growth increases, the wedge between the real loss and the theoretical loss increases rapidly. This is of course no surprise, because the damage that reduces long-term growth rates has long-lasting effects. However it has the consequence that damage is much higher at 3 C than what is commonly assumed. This means that the value of reduction of output at 3 C is not kept constant.

Figure 6 plots the damage strength against the theoretical production loss. We can see that theoretical loss and damage strength goes in the same direction. Therefore, when the “share” of damage on TFP growth is kept constant, theoretical loss can be used as a proxy for damage strength. However, when the “share” of damage on TFP growth is changed, the same theoretical loss can lead to highly different damage strengths.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Damage strength as a function of theoretical production losses, for different “shares” of damage on growth f increasing from 0 to 20 percents

Appendix 2

The model is resolved over a 600 years time horizon, by 5 years time steps. It is calibrated in 2005. Table 2 gives the parameters values.

Table 2 Values of model parameters

In addition, four variables follow exogenous trends, as defined below:

g t = g 0 e χt (exogenous trend of TFP growth)

L t = L 0 e γt + L (1 − e γt) (population)

\(\sigma _{t}=\sigma _{0} e^{-g_{\sigma } t e^{-d_{\sigma } t}} \frac {1+e^{-s_{peak} d_{peak}}}{1+e^{s_{peak} (t-d_{peak})}}\) (exogenous evolution in carbon content of production)

\(\theta _{1}(t)=\sigma _{t} \frac {p_{backstop}}{\theta _{2}} \frac {r_{backstop}-1+e^{-g_{backstop}t}}{r_{backstop}}\) (exogenous decrease of abatement costs)

Table 3 gives the values of the parameters used in these four exogenous trends.

Table 3 Values of parameters defining exogenous trends

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Guivarch, C., Pottier, A. Climate Damage on Production or on Growth: What Impact on the Social Cost of Carbon?. Environ Model Assess 23, 117–130 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-017-9572-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-017-9572-4

Keywords

Navigation