Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Mitigation Costs in a Globalized World: Climate Policy Analysis with REMIND-R

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Within this paper, we present the novel hybrid model REMIND-R and its application in a climate policy context based on the EU target to avoid a warming of the Earth’s atmosphere by more than 2°C compared to the pre-industrial level. This paper aims to identify necessary long-term changes in the energy system and the magnitude of costs to attain such a climate protection target under different designs of the post-2012 climate policy regime. The regional specification of mitigation costs is analyzed in the context of globalization where regions are linked by global markets for emission permits, goods, and several resources. From simulation experiments with REMIND-R, it turns out that quite different strategies of restructuring the energy system are pursued by the regions. Furthermore, it is demonstrated that the variance of mitigation costs is higher across regions than across policy regimes. First-order impacts, in particular, reduced rents from trade in fossil resources, prevail regardless of the design of the policy regime.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14
Fig. 15
Fig. 16
Fig. 17
Fig. 18

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On http://www.pik-potsdam.de/research/research-domains/sustainable-solutions/remind-code-1, the technical description of REMIND-R and the whole set of input data are available. REMIND-R is programmed in GAMS. The code is available from the authors on request.

  2. We assume a pure rate of time preference of 3% for the simulation experiments presented in later sections.

  3. The assumed values for the substitution elasticities (see Fig. 2) are comparable to the values assumed by [13, p. 49]. Regarding the nesting structure of the energy composite, we tried to replicate the basic structure of energy system services composed of mobile and stationary energy uses. Both are combined by a very low elasticity of substitution.

  4. Most recent data are available on http://www.enerdata.fr/enerdatauk/index.html.

  5. In cases without or with internalized externalities (applies to the climate change externality and technological learning), the pareto-optimal solution computed by REMIND-R corresponds also to a market solution.

  6. Throughout this report, all relevant economic figures (e.g., GDP) are measured in constant international $US 2003 (market exchange rate).

  7. The primary energy consumption of the renewable energy sources wind, solar, and hydro power is put on the same level as the related secondary energy production.

  8. While for the year 2050, the carbon price here is of the same order of magnitude as the carbon prices simulated for the less ambitious 450 ppm CO2 stabilization scenario within the Innovation Modeling Comparison Project (cf. [7, p. 96]), it is significantly higher for the year 2100.

  9. In general, regional GDP losses differ from regional consumption losses. This is due to the effects of international trade.

References

  1. Alcamo, J., Leemans, R., & Kreileman, G. J. J. (1998). Global change scenarios of the 21st century. Results from the IMAGE 2.1 model. London: Pergamon & Elsevier Science.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Barker, T., Köhler, J., Anderson, D., & Pan, H. (2006). Combining energy technology dynamics and macroeconometrics: The E3MG model for climate stabilization scenarios. The Energy Journal, 113–133 (Special Issue 2006).

  3. Bauer, N., Edenhofer, O., & Kypreos, S. (2008). Linking energy system and macroeconomic growth models. Journal of Computational Management Science, 5, 95–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Bosetti, V., Carraro, C., Galeotti, M., Massetti, E., & Tavoni, M. (2006). WITCH: A world induced technical change hybrid model. The Energy Journal, 13–38 (Special Issue 2006).

  5. Crassous, R., Hourcade, J.-C., & Sassi, O. (2006). Endogenous structural change and climate targets. Modeling experiments with Imaclim-R. The Energy Journal, 259–276 (Special Issue 2006).

  6. Edenhofer, O., Bauer, N., & Kriegler, E. (2005). The impact of technological change on climate protection and welfare: Insights from the model MIND. Ecological Economics, 54, 277–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Edenhofer, O., Lessmann, K., Kemfert, C., Grubb, M., & Köhler, J. (2006). Induced technological change: Exploring its implications for the economics of athmospheric stabilization: Synthesis report from innovation modeling comparison project. The Energy Journal, 57–107 (Special Issue 2006).

  8. Edmonds, J., Wise, M., Pitcher, H., Richels, R., Wigley, T., & MacCracken, C. (1997). An integrated assessment of climate change and the accelerated introduction of advanced energy technologies. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change, 1, 311–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. den Elzen, M. G. J, & Lucas, P. L. (2005). The FAIR model: A tool to analyse environmental and costs implication of regimes of future commitments. Environmental Modeling and Assessment, 10, 115–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. den Elzen, M., Lucas, P.-A., & van Vuuren, D. (2005). Abatement costs of post-Kyoto climate regimes. Energy Policy, 33, 2138–2151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Frei, C. W., Haldi, P., & Sarlos, G. (2003). Dynamic formulation of a top-down and bottom-up merging energy policy model. Energy Policy, 31, 1017–1031.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Gerlagh, R., & van der Zwaan, B. (2003). Gross world product and consumption in a global warming model with endogenous technological change. Resource and Energy Economics, 25, 35–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Gerlagh, R., & van der Zwaan, B. (2004). Sensitivity analysis of timing and costs of greenhouse gas emissions reduction. Climatic Change, 65, 39–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Guest, R. S., & McDonald, I. M. (2007). Global GDP shares in the 21st century—An equilibrium approach. Economic Modelling, 24, 859–877.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Hamelinck, C. (2004). Outlook for advanced biofuels. Ph.D. thesis, University of Utrecht, The Netherlands.

  16. Höhne, N., Galleguillos, C., Blok, K., Harnisch, J., & Phylipsen, D. (2003). Evolution of commitments under the UNFCCC: Involving newly industrial economies and developing countries. Research Report, UBA-FB 000412, Umweltbundesamt.

  17. Hourcade, J.-C., Jaccard, M., Bataille, C., & Ghersi, F. (2006). Hybrid modeling: New answers to old challenges. The Energy Journal, 1–12 (Special Issue 2006).

  18. Kahouli-Brahmi, S. (2008). Technological learning in energy-environment-economy modelling: A survey. Energy Policy, 36, 138–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Kainuma, M., Matsuoka, Y., & Morita, T. (2003). Climate policy assessment: Asia-Pacific integrated modeling. Tokyo: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Kouvaritakis, N., Soria, A., & Isoard, S. (2000). Endogenous learning in world post-Kyoto scenarios: Applications of the POLES model under adaptive expectations. International Journal of Global Energy Issues, 14, 222–248.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Kriegler, E., & Bruckner, T. (2004). Sensitivity of emissions corridors for the 21st century. Climatic Change, 66, 345–387.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  22. Kypreos, S., & Bahn, O. (2003). A MERGE model with endogenous technological progress. Environmental Modeling and Assessment, 19, 333–358.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Leimbach, M., & Toth, F. (2003). Economic development and emission control over the long term: The ICLIPS aggregated economic model. Climatic Change, 56, 139–165.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  24. Löschel, A. (2002). Technnological change in economic models of environmental policy: A survey. Ecological Economics, 43, 105–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. McKibbin, W. J., & Wilcoxen, P. J. (1999). The theoretical and empirical structure of the G-cubed model. Economic Modelling, 16, 123–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Manne, A. S., Mendelsohn, M., & Richels, R. (1995). MERGE—A model for evaluating regional and global effects of GHG reduction policies. Energy Policy, 23, 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Manne, A. S., & Rutherford, T. (1994). International trade, capital flows and sectoral analysis: Formulation and solution of intertemporal equilibrium models. In W. W. Cooper, & A. B. Whinston (Eds.), New directions in computational economics (pp. 191–205). Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M. D., & Green, J. R. (1995). Microeconomic theory. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Messner, S., & Schrattenholzer, L. (2000). MESSAGE-MACRO: Linking an energy supply model with a macroeconomic model and solving it interactively. Energy, 25, 267–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Nordhaus, W. D., & Yang, Z. (1996). A regional dynamic general-equilibrium model of alternative climate-change strategies. American Economic Review, 86, 741–765.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Petschel-Held, G., Schellnhuber, H. J., Bruckner, T., Toth, F. L., & Hasselmann, K. (1999). The tolerable windows approach: Theoretical and methodological foundations. Climatic Change, 41, 303–331.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  32. Penn World Tables (2007). Version 6.2. http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/php-site/pwt-index.php.

  33. Riahi, K., Grübler, A., & Nakicenovic, N. (2007). Scenarios of long-term socio-economic and environmental development under climate stabilization. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 74, 887–935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Rogner, H. H. (1997). An assessment of world hydrocarbon resources. Annual Review of Energy and Environment, 22, 217–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Rose, A., & Stevens, B. (1993). The efficiency and equity of marketable permits for CO2 emissions. Resource and Energy Economics, 15, 117–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Sanstad, A. H., & Greening, L. A. (1998). Economic models for climate policy analysis: A critical discussion. Environmental Modeling and Assessment, 3, 3–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Takeshita, T., & Yamaij, K. (2008). Important roles of Fischer-Tropsch synfuels in the global energy future. Energy Policy, 36, 2773–2784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Vaillancourt, K., Loulou, R., & Kanudia, A. (2008). The role of abatement costs in GHG permit allocations: A global stabilization scenario analysis. Environmental Modeling and Assessment, 13, 169–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. World Bank (2005). World development indicators. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  40. Weyant, J. P. (2004). Introduction and overview. Energy Economics, 26, 501–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

For their help in implementing the REMIND model, we are grateful to our colleagues Michael Lüken and Markus Haller. We also thank the German Federal Environmental Agency for the financial support of this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marian Leimbach.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Leimbach, M., Bauer, N., Baumstark, L. et al. Mitigation Costs in a Globalized World: Climate Policy Analysis with REMIND-R. Environ Model Assess 15, 155–173 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-009-9204-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-009-9204-8

Keywords

Navigation